Introduction To Game Theory: Prof. Swagata Bhattacharjee
Introduction To Game Theory: Prof. Swagata Bhattacharjee
Game Theory
PROF. SWAGATA BHATTACHARJEE
Today
Rationalizability and Iterated Dominance
Best Response
Dominated Strategies
A pure strategy of player i is (strictly) dominated if there is a strategy (pure or mixed) such that
A strategy (pure or mixed) of player i (strictly) dominates a pure strategy if for all strategy profiles
of the other players
Delete all of the dominated strategies for each player, because a rational player would never use one of these.
Common knowledge of rationality therefore implies that it is common knowledge that a strategy profile in R1 will
be played.
In other words, essentially the players are interacting in a “reduced” game in which R1 is the set of strategy
profiles.
Iterated Deletion/ Removal of
Strictly Dominated Strategies
(Iterated Dominance)
We can apply the procedure to any normal-form game as follows.
Now, essentially the players are interacting in a “reduced” game in which R1 is the set of strategy profiles.
The next step is to remove any strategies that are dominated in this reduced game and define R2 as the strategy
profiles that remain.
Continue this process to identify smaller and smaller sets of strategy profiles, R3 ,R4, …, until no more strategies
can be deleted.
Let R denote the resulting set of strategy profiles—those that survive this iterated dominance procedure.
The set of strategies R that survive iterated dominance is therefore called the rationalizable strategies.
Example
Any pure strategy that is dominated another
pure strategy?
Example
Any pure strategy that is dominated another
pure strategy?
No!
Any dominated strategy at all?
Example
Any pure strategy that is dominated another
pure strategy?
No!
Any dominated strategy at all?
Yes!
Player 2: X is dominated by the mixed
strategy (0, ½, ½ )
Iterated deletion step 1:
R1 = {{U, M, D} ˟ {Y, Z}}.
Example
Within R1, any dominated strategy?
Yes! U is dominated by D for Player 1.
Iterated deletion step 2:
R2 = {{M, D} ˟ {Y, Z}}.
Example
R2 = {{M, D} ˟ {Y, Z}}.
Within R2, for 2, Y is dominated.
Step 3: R3 = {{M, D} ˟ {Z}}.
“Whatever the other players do, a strategy for player i is dominated by another”
Often, no strategy is dominated. Then, players have to form belief about what the others are going to
do and respond to that: Best response.
To maximize the payoff that you expect to obtain—which we assume is the mark of rational behavior
—you should select the strategy that yields the greatest expected payoff against your belief.
Definition:
Suppose player i has a belief about the strategies played by the other players. Player i’s strategy is a best
response if
for every
Best Response
Definition:
Suppose player i has a belief about the strategies played by the other players. Player i’s strategy is a best
response if
for every
If a strategy is best response to all possible beliefs, then it is the dominant strategy!
There can be more than one best responses. Set of best responses for a given belief is denoted by
Best Response: Example
Suppose Player 1 believes that 2 will use the
strategy (1/3, ½, 1/6)=
If chooses M:
If chooses D:
So,
Best Response: Example
Suppose Player 2 believes that 1 will use the
strategy (½, ¼, ¼ )=
If chooses C:
If chooses R:
So,
Never Best Response and Dominance
Definition:
Suppose player i has a belief about the strategies played by the other players. Player i’s strategy is a best
response if
for every
A strategy is a Never Best Response if it is not a best response to any belief by player i.
Result: A strategy in a finite game is a Never Best Response if and only if it is a Strictly Dominated
strategy.
Example
Suppose that two people decide to form a partnership firm.
The revenue of the firm depends on the amount of effort expended on the job by each person and is given by:
The contract that was signed by the partners stipulates that person 1 receives a fraction t (between 0 and 1) of the
firm’s revenue, and person 2 receives a 1 - t fraction.
Person i ’s utility in this endeavor is the amount of revenue that this person receives, minus the effort cost.
Example
Effort levels (assumed nonnegative) are chosen by the people simultaneously and independently.
(a) Define the normal form of this game (by describing the strategy spaces and payoff functions).
Payoff functions:
Example
(b) Using dominance, compute the strategies that the players rationally select (as a function of t, a1 and a2).
In this game, each player has a strategy that dominates all others. To see
this, observe how player 1’s payoff changes as is varied.
So,
Similarly,
Example
Suppose that you could set t before the players interact. How would you set to maximize the
revenue of the firm?
From (b), we know, for every t, ,
So, revenue =
This is linear in t, so corner solution!
either t=1 or t=0
If so t=1 otherwise t=0
What if the firm wants to maximize revenue minus the effort costs by both the partners?
Next Class
Nash Equilibrium