Indifference Curve Analysis
Indifference Curve Analysis
•
• Second: The second order condition is that indifference curve must be convex to the
origin at the point of tangency
Consumer Equilibrium
• Assumptions:
•
• The following assumptions are made to determine the consumer’s equilibrium position.
•
• (i) Rationality: The consumer is rational. He wants to obtain maximum satisfaction given his
income and prices.
•
• (ii) Utility is ordinal: It is assumed that the consumer can rank his preference according to
the satisfaction of each combination of goods.
•
• (iii) Consistency of choice: It is also assumed that the consumer is consistent in the choice
of goods.
•
• (iv) Perfect competition: There is perfect competition in the market from where the
consumer is purchasing the goods.
•
• (v) Total utility: The total utility of the consumer depends on the quantities of the good
consumed.
Consumer Equilibrium
Consumer Equilibrium
• In the diagram 3.11, there are three indifference curves IC1,
IC2 and IC3. The price line PT is tangent to the indifference curve
IC2 at point C. The consumer gets the maximum satisfaction or
is in equilibrium at point C by purchasing OE units of good Y
and OH units of good X with the given money income.
• The consumer cannot be in equilibrium at any other point on
indifference curves. For instance, point R and S lie on lower
indifference curve IC1 but yield less satisfaction. As regards
point U on indifference curve IC3, the consumer no doubt gets
higher satisfaction but that is outside the budget line and hence
not achievable to the consumer. The consumer’s equilibrium
position is only at point C where the price line is tangent to the
highest attainable indifference curve IC2 from below.
Consumer Equilibrium
• 2) Slope of the Price Line to be Equal to the Slope of Indifference Curve:
• The second condition for the consumer to be in equilibrium and get the
maximum possible satisfaction is only at a point where the price line is a
tangent to the highest possible indifference curve from below. In fig. 3.11, the
price line PT is touching the highest possible indifferent curve IC2 at point C.
The point C shows the combination of the two commodities which the
consumer is maximized when he buys OH units of good X and OE units of
good Y.
• Geometrically, at tangency point C, the consumer’s substitution ratio is equal
to price ratio Px / Py. It implies that at point C, what the consumer is willing to
pay i.e., his personal exchange rate between X and Y (MRSxy) is equal to
what he actually pays i.e., the market exchange rate. So the equilibrium
condition being Px / Py being satisfied at the point C is:
• Price of X / Price of Y = MRS of X for Y
• The equilibrium conditions given above states that the rate at which the
individual is willing to substitute commodity X for commodity Y must equal the
ratio at which he can substitute X for Y in the market at a given price.
Consumer Equilibrium
• Explanation:
• The consumer’s consumption decision is explained by
combining the budget line and the indifference map. The
consumer’s equilibrium position is only at a point where
the price line is tangent to the highest attainable
indifference curve from below.
• (1) Budget Line Should be Tangent to the Indifference
Curve:
• The consumer’s equilibrium in explained by combining the
budget line and the indifference map
Consumer Equilibrium
• (3) Indifference Curve Should be Convex to the Origin:
• The third condition for the stable consumer equilibrium is that the
indifference curve must be convex to the origin at the point of
equilibrium. In other words, we can say that the MRS of X for Y
must be diminishing at the point of equilibrium. It may be noticed
that in fig. 3.11, the indifference curve IC 2 is convex to the origin
at point C. So at point C, all three conditions for the stable-
consumer’s equilibrium are satisfied.
• Summing up, the consumer is in equilibrium at point C where
the budget line PT is tangent to the indifference IC 2. The market
basket OH of good X and OE of good Y yields the greatest
satisfaction because it is on the highest attainable indifference
curve. At point C:
• MRSxy = Px / Py
Consumer surplus and producer surplus
• Consumer surplus
• Consumer surplus is derived whenever the price a
consumer actually pays is less than they are prepared to
pay. A demand curve indicates what price consumers are
prepared to pay for a hypothetical quantity of a good,
based on their expectation of private benefit.
• For example, at price P, the total private benefit in terms
of utility derived by consumers from consuming quantity,
Q is shown as the area ABQC in the diagram.
• Consumer surplus = willingness to pay – actual pay
• CS= total utility- no.of units purchased.price
Consumer surplus and producer surplus
Consumer surplus and producer surplus
• Producer surplus
• Producer surplus is the additional private benefit to
producers, in terms of profit, gained when the price they
receive in the market is more than the minimum they
would be prepared to supply for. In other words they
received a reward that more than covers their costs of
production.
• The producer surplus derived by all firms in the market is
the area from the supply curve to the price line, EPB.
Consumer surplus and producer surplus
Consumer surplus and producer surplus
• Economic welfare
• Economic welfare is the total benefit available to society
from an economic transaction or situation.
• Economic welfare is also called community surplus.
Welfare is represented by the area ABE in the diagram
below, which is made up of the area for consumer surplus,
ABP plus the area for producer surplus, PBE.
• In market analysis economic welfare at equilibrium can be
calculated by adding consumer and producer surplus.
• Welfare analysis considers whether economic decisions
by individuals, organisations, and the government
increase or decrease economic welfare.
Consumer surplus and producer surplus