We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PPT, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 26
The Theory of Rational
Expectations This is the most widely used theory to describe the formation of business and consumer expectations.
Economists regularly viewed expectations as formed
from past experience only. Expectations of inflation, for example, were typically viewed as being an average of past inflation rates. This view of expectation formation, called adaptive expectations, suggests that changes in expectations will occur slowly over time. Cont. • So if inflation had formerly been steady at a 5% rate, expectations of future inflation would be 5% too. If inflation rose to a steady rate of 10%, expectations of future inflation would rise toward 10%, but slowly: In the first year, expected inflation might rise only to 6%; in the second year, to 7%; and so on. Cont. • Adaptive expectations have been faulted on the grounds that people use more information than just past data on a single variable to form their expectations of that variable. • Their expectations of inflation will also be affected by their predictions of future monetary policy as well as by current and past monetary policy. In addition, people often change their expectations quickly in the light of new information. Cont. • John Muth (1961) developed an alternative theory of expectations, called rational expectations, which can be stated as Expectations will be identical to optimal forecasts (the best guess of the future) using all available information. Cont. • However, the forecast does not have to be perfectly accurate to be rational—it need only be the best possible given the available information; that is, it has to be correct on average. • Even though a rational expectation equals the optimal forecast using all available information, a prediction based on it may not always be perfectly accurate. Cont. • What if an item of information relevant to predicting is unavailable or ignored? • If one has no way of ascertaining new information, his expectation is still rational, because the new information is not available to him for incorporation into his optimal forecast. • However, if he did not bother or ignored the new information, his expectation is no longer rational. Cont. • Accordingly, there are two reasons why an expectation may fail to be rational: 1. People might be aware of all available information but find it takes too much effort to make their expectation the best guess possible. 2. People might be unaware of some available relevant information, so their best guess of the future will not be accurate. Cont. • Nonetheless, it is important to recognize that if an additional factor is important but information about it is not available, an expectation that does not take account of it can still be rational. Cont. • the theory of rational expectations:. If X stands for the variable that is being forecast, Xe for the expectation of this variable, and Xof for the optimal forecast of X using all available information, Xe = Xof The Rational Behind the Theory • Why do people try to make their expectations match their best possible guess of the future using all available information? The simplest explanation is that it is costly for people not to do so. • For Example, an appliance manufacturer knows that interest-rate movements are important to the sales of appliances. If the firm makes poor forecasts of interest rates, it will earn less profit, because it might produce either too many appliances or too few. Cont. • There are strong incentives for the firm to acquire all available information to help it forecast interest rates and use the information to make the best possible guess of future interest rate movements. Cont. • In financial markets, people with better forecasts of the future get rich. The application of the theory of rational expectations to financial markets is called the efficient market hypothesis or the theory of efficient capital markets) Implications of the Theory
• Rational expectations theory leads to two
commonsense implications for the forming of expectations that are important in the analysis of the aggregate economy: 1. If there is a change in the way a variable moves, the way in which expectations of this variable are formed will change as well. Cont. • Suppose that interest rates move in such a way that they tend to return to a “normal” level in the future. If today’s interest rate is high relative to the normal level, an optimal forecast of the interest rate in the future is that it will decline to the normal level. Rational expectations theory would imply that when today’s interest rate is high, the expectation is that it will fall in the future. Cont. • Suppose now that the way in which the interest rate moves changes so that when the interest rate is high, it stays high. In this case, when today’s interest rate is high, the optimal forecast of the future interest rate, and hence the rational expectation, is that it will stay high. Expectations of the future interest rate will no longer indicate that the interest rate will fall. Cont. 2. The forecast errors of expectations will on average be zero and cannot be predicted ahead of time. The forecast error of an expectation is X - X e, the difference between the realization of a variable X and the expectation of the variable; that is, if the interest rate on a particular day is 4% and the expectation is 3.5%, the forecast error is 0.5%. Cont. • Suppose that in violation of the rational expectations tenet, the forecast error is not, on average, equal to zero; instead, it equals 0.5%. The forecast error is now predictable ahead of time because the person will soon notice that interest rate, on average, 0.5% higher and can improve his forecast by increasing it by 0.5%. • Rational expectations theory implies that forecast errors of expectations cannot be predicted. The Efficient Market Hypothesis:
• The efficient market hypothesis is based on
the assumption that prices of securities in financial markets fully reflect all available information. • Re = Rof (expected return is the optimal forecast of return using all available information) Cont. • Re = R* • The expected return on a security Re equals the equilibrium return R*, which equates the quantity of the security demanded to the quantity supplied. • We can derive an equation to describe pricing behavior in an efficient market by using the equilibrium condition to replace Re with R* in the rational expectations equation. In this way, we obtain: Rof = R* Cont. • This equation tells that current prices in a financial market will be set so that the optimal forecast of a security’s return using all available information equals the security’s equilibrium return. • According to Financial economists: In an efficient market, a security’s price fully reflects all available information. Rationale Behind the Hypothesis • Suppose that the equilibrium return on a security— say, Exxon common stock—is 10% at an annual rate, and its current price Pt is lower than the optimal forecast of tomorrow’s price Pt+1 so that the optimal forecast of the return at an annual rate is 50%, which is greater than the equilibrium return of 10%. • We are now able to predict that, on average, Exxon’s return would be abnormally high. This situation is called an unexploited profit opportunity. Cont. because Rof is greater than R*, you would buy more, which would in turn drive up its current price Pt relative to the expected future price P t+1, thereby lowering Rof. When the current price had risen sufficiently so that Rof equals R* and the efficient markets condition is satisfied, the buying of Exxon will stop, and the unexploited profit opportunity will have disappeared. Cont. • Similarly, a security for which the optimal forecast of the return is 5% and the equilibrium return is 10% (Rof is smaller than R*) would be a poor investment, because, on average, it earns less than the equilibrium return. In such a case, you would sell the security and drive down its current price relative to the expected future price until Rof rose to the level of R* and the efficient markets condition is again satisfied. Cont. Cont. • In an efficient market, all unexploited profit opportunities will be eliminated. • A very important factor in this reasoning is that not everyone in a financial market must be well informed about a security or have rational expectations for its price to be driven to the point at which the efficient markets condition holds. Cont. • Financial markets are structured so that many participants can play. As long as a few keep their eyes open for unexploited profit opportunities, they will eliminate the profit opportunities that appear, because in so doing, they make a profit.
Why Most Investors Fail and Why You Don’T Have To: Simple, Tax-Efficient Strategies That Control Risk, Eliminate Confusion, and Turn the Odds of Success in Your Favor