We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PPT, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 27
I.
Risk Structure of Interest rates
II. Term Structure of
Interest rates 1.DEFAULT RISK 2. LIQUIDITY 3. INFORMATION COSTS is the cost of acquiring information. 4. TAXATION Borrowers differ in their ability to repay in full the principle and interest required by a loan agreement.
Measuring the default risk
The default risk premium on a bond is the difference between its yield and the yield on a default risk free instrument of comparable maturity, and it measures the default risk. Investors care about liquidity, they are willing to accept a lower interest rate on more liquid investments than on less liquid – illiquid – investments, all other things being equal. The activity of an investor who devotes resources – time and money – to acquire information on an asset reduces the expected return on that financial asset. The cost of using those recourses thus is included in the borrowing cost charged by lender, just as the cost of labor is included in the price of sweater. If two assets have equal default risk and liquidity, investors prefer to hold the asset with lower information cost If returns on all instruments were taxed identically, the differences among instruments in terms of default risk, liquidity and information cost would be the only sources of variation in the risk structure The risk structure of interest rates (the relationship among interest rates on bonds with the same maturity) is explained by three factors: default risk, liquidity, and the income tax treatment of the bond’s interest payments. As a bond’s default risk increases, the risk premium on that bond (the spread between its interest rate and the interest rate on a default-free Treasury bond) rises. The greater liquidity of Treasury bonds also explains why their interest rates are lower than interest rates on less liquid bonds. If a bond has a favorable tax treatment, as do municipal bonds, whose interest payments are exempt from federal income taxes, its interest rate will be lower. Expectations theory Segmented Market Theory The Liquidity Premium Theory The interest rate on a long term bond will equal an average of short term interest rates that people expect to occur over the life of the long-term bond. For example, if people expect that short-term interest rates will be 10% on average over the coming five years, the expectations theory predicts that the interest rate on bonds with five years to maturity will be 10% too. If short- term interest rates were expected to rise even higher after this five-year period so that the average short-term interest rate over the coming 20 years is 11%, then the interest rate on 20-year bonds would equal 11% and would be higher than the interest rate on five-year of the term structure sees markets for different maturity bonds are completely separate and segmented. The interest rate for each bond with a different maturity is then determined by the supply of and demand for that bond with no effect from expected returns on other bonds with other maturities The key assumption in the segmented markets theory is that bonds of different maturities are not substitutes at all, so the expected return from holding a bond of one maturity has no effect on the demand for a bond of another maturity. This theory of the term structure is at the opposite extreme to the expectations theory, which assumes that bonds of different maturities are perfect The liquidity premium theory is the most widely accepted theory of the term structure of interest rates because it explains the major empirical facts about the term structure so well.
It combines the features of both the
expectation theory and the segmented markets theory by asserting that a long- term interest rate will be the sum of liquidity (term) premium and the average of the short-term interest rates that are expected to occur over the life of the bond. of the term structure states that the interest rate on a long-term bond will equal an average of short-term interest rates expected to occur over the life of the long term bond plus a liquidity premium (also referred to as term premium) that responds to supply and demand conditions for that bond. Main assumption of the theory: is that bonds of different maturities are substitutes, which means that the expected return on one bond does influence the expected return on maturity on a bond with of a different maturity, but it allows investors to prefer one bond maturity over another. It assumes that investors have a preference for bonds of one maturity over another, a particular bond maturity (preferred habitat) in which they prefer to invest. Because they prefer bonds of one maturity over another they will be willing to buy bonds that do not have the preferred maturity only if they earn a somewhat higher expected return. Because investors are likely to prefer the habitat of short-term bonds over that of longer-term bonds, they are willing to hold long-term bonds only if they have higher expected returns. Suppose that the one-year interest rate over the next five years is expected to be 5, 6, 7, 8, and 9%, while investors’ preferences for holding short-term bonds means that the liquidity premiums for one- to five-year bonds are 0, 0.25, 0.5, 0.75, and 1.0%, respectively. Equation 3 then indicates that the interest rate on the two-year bond would be: The liquidity premium and preferred habitat theories are the most widely accepted theories of the term structure of interest rates because they explain the major empirical facts about the term structure so well. They combine the features of both the expectations theory and the segmented markets theory by asserting that a long-term interest rate will be the sum of a liquidity (term) premium and the average of the short-term interest rates that are expected to occur over the life of the bond. The liquidity premium and preferred habitat theories explain the following facts: (1) Interest rates on bonds of different maturities tend to move together over time, (2)yield curves usually slope upward, and (3) when short-term interest rates are low, yield curves are more likely to have a steep upward slope, whereas when short-term interest rates are high, yield curves are more likely to be inverted. 1. Bonds with the same maturity will have different interest rates because of three factors: default risk, liquidity, and tax considerations. The greater a bond’s default risk, the higher its interest rate relative to other bonds; the greater a bond’s liquidity, the lower its interest rate; and bonds with tax-exempt status will have lower interest rates than they otherwise would. The relationship among interest rates on bonds with the same maturity that arise because of these three factors is known as the risk structure of interest rates. 2. Four theories of the term structure provide explanations of how interest rates on bonds with different terms to maturity are related. The expectations theory views long- term interest rates as equaling the average of future short-term interest rates expected to occur over the life of the bond; by contrast, the segmented markets theory treats the determination of interest rates for each bond’s maturity as the outcome of supply and demand in that market only. Neither of these theories by itself can explain the fact that interest rates on bonds of different maturities move together over time and that yield curves usually slope upward. 3. The liquidity premium and preferred habitat theories combine the features of the other two theories, and by so doing are able to explain the facts just mentioned. They view long-term interest rates as equaling the average of future short-term interest rates expected to occur over the life of the bond plus a liquidity premium. These theories allow us to infer the market’s expectations about the movement of future short-term interest rates from the yield curve. A steeply upwardsloping curve indicates that future short-term rates are expected to rise, a mildly upward-sloping curve indicates that short-term rates are expected to stay the same, a flat curve indicates that short-term rates are expected to decline slightly, and an inverted yield curve indicates that a substantial decline in short-term rates is expected in the future.