0% found this document useful (0 votes)
56 views53 pages

Production Slides

Production involves transforming inputs into outputs. The production function mathematically represents the relationship between inputs used and maximum output possible. It defines output as a function of capital and labor inputs. There are short-run and long-run production functions depending on whether all inputs can vary. The law of diminishing marginal returns states that beyond a certain point, adding more of a variable input while holding others fixed will result in lower marginal productivity. Firms aim to operate where marginal revenue product equals marginal cost.

Uploaded by

Julian
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PPT, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
56 views53 pages

Production Slides

Production involves transforming inputs into outputs. The production function mathematically represents the relationship between inputs used and maximum output possible. It defines output as a function of capital and labor inputs. There are short-run and long-run production functions depending on whether all inputs can vary. The law of diminishing marginal returns states that beyond a certain point, adding more of a variable input while holding others fixed will result in lower marginal productivity. Firms aim to operate where marginal revenue product equals marginal cost.

Uploaded by

Julian
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PPT, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 53

PRODUCTION

Production
 The transformation of resources into
products.
 The process whereby inputs are turned
into outputs.
 Economic efficiency of the production
process is the issue under analysis.
 Economic efficiency calls for minimizing
the cost of producing any output level
during a period of time.
The Production Function
 For a profit maximizing firm, the revenues and
the costs are the two important components.
 The costs will be related to the production of
the good or service by using the different
categories of inputs.
 The production function gives a mathematical
representation of the relationship between
1. the output produced and,
2. the inputs used for production.
The Production Function
 Q = f (X1, X2, …, Xk)
where Q = output
X1, …, Xk = inputs used in the production
process
 Q is a measure of output at a specific point in
time.
 The production relationship holds for a given
level of technology.
 Q is the maximum amount that can be produced
with a given level of inputs.
The Production Function
 The production function defines
 the relationship between inputs and the

maximum amount that can be produced


 within a given period of time and

 with a given level of technology.

 Traditionally, the production function is written


for two categories of inputs, capital (K) and
labor (L):
Q = f (K, L)
The Production Function
 The exact mathematical specification of the
production function depends upon the
productivity of the inputs at various levels of
employment.
 The productivity of the inputs depends on the
state of the technology.
 State of the technology is the inherent ability
of inputs to produce output, given the
simultaneous efforts of all other inputs in the
production process.
State of the Technology
 E.g. Labor can be more productive if it
works with modern mechanical and
computer-assisted equipment.
 E.g. Plant or equipment can be more
productive if it is being operated by
highly-skilled and well-trained workers.
Short-run versus Long-run
 A SR production function shows the maximum
quantity of a good or service that can be
produced by a set of inputs, assuming that
the amount of at least one of the inputs
used remains constant.
 A LR production function shows the maximum
quantity of a good or service that can be
produced by a set of inputs, assuming that
the firm is free to vary the amount of all
the inputs being used.
Short-run versus Long-run
 Long-run does not refer to a long
period of time.
 It is that period of time when all factors
of production can be varied.
 When changing the scale of production,
the firm must operate under short-run
conditions until its most-fixed input
becomes variable.
Short-run versus Long-run

 E.g. Assembly of an automobile


production.
 Fixed inputs: land and building,
assembly lines, computerized plant and
equipment.
 Variable inputs: worker-hours,
component parts, energy.
Short-Run Analysis:
Total, Average, and Marginal Product
 Terminology:
Inputs: Factors, Factors of production,
Resources

Output: Quantity (Q), Total Product (TP),


Product
Short-Run Analysis:
Total, Average, and Marginal Product
Recall:
 Q = Total product = f (X, Y)

 Marginal product of X (MPX) = Q / X, holding Y constant

 Average product of X (MPX) = Q / X, holding Y constant

 Marginal product is the change in total product resulting


from a unit change in a variable input.
 Average product is the total product per unit of input used.
Units of Y
Employed Output Quantity (Q)
8 37 60 83 96 107 117 127 128
7 42 64 78 90 101 110 119 120
6 37 52 64 73 82 90 97 104
5 31 47 58 67 75 82 89 95
4 24 39 52 60 67 73 79 85
3 17 29 41 52 58 64 69 73
2 8 18 29 39 47 52 56 52
1 4 8 14 20 27 24 21 17
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8
Units of X Employed
When Y is held constant at the level of 2 units:

Variable Input Total Product Marginal Product Average Product


(X) (Q or TP) (MP) (AP)
0 0
1 8 8 8.00
2 18 10 9.00
3 29 11 9.67
4 39 10 9.75
5 47 8 9.40
6 52 5 8.67
7 56 4 8.00
8 52 -4 6.50
Law of Diminishing Returns
 As additional units of variable input are
combined with a fixed input, at some
point, the additional output (i.e., marginal
product) starts to diminish.
 In the example, the law of diminishing
marginal returns occurs at 3.5 units of
input.
 If input X is not divisible, then we would
have to add the 4th unit to observe the
diminishing marginal returns.
60
50 TP
TP
40
30
20
10
0
0 2 4 6 8 10

diminishing returns begins


15
to take effect
10
AP
5
marginal product
0 becomes negative
0 2 4 6 8 10
-5
MP
Diminishing Marginal Returns
 Examples:
1. Production: sorting refillable glass bottles
Fixed input: machinery and working area
Variable input: people working as sorters

2. Production: development of applications


software
Fixed input: programming language and
hardware
Variable input: software programmers
Three Stages of Production in the Short-Run
60
Stage I Stage II Stage III
50
40
30
20
10
0
0 2 4 6 8 10

15

10

0
0 2 4 6 8 10
-5
Stages of Production
 Stage I:
1. Fixed input grossly underutilized
2. Specialization and teamwork cause AP to increase when
additional X is used.

 Stage II:
1. Specialization and teamwork continue to result in
greater output when additional X is used
2. Fixed input is being properly utilized

 Stage III:
1. Fixed input capacity is reached
2. Additional X causes output to fall
Stages of Production
 At which state should the firm produce?
 What level of variable input should the firm use?

 The firm needs information in order to decide


how many units of variable input to use:
 how many units of output it could sell

 the price of the product


 monetary cost of employing various amounts
of the X input
Total Marginal Total Marginal
Revenue Revenue Labor Labor
Labor Total Avrg Mrgnl Product Product Cost Cost
Unit Product Product Product (TRP) (MRP) (TLC) (MLC)
(X) (TP) (AP) (MP) TP x P MP x P XxW dTLC / dX TRP – TLC MRP – MLC
0 0 0 0 0 0 0
1 10,000 10,000 10,000 20,000 20,000 10,000 10,000 10,000 10,000
2 25,000 12,500 15,000 50,000 30,000 20,000 10,000 30,000 20,000
3 45,000 15,000 20,000 90,000 40,000 30,000 10,000 60,000 30,000
4 60,000 15,000 15,000 120,000 30,000 40,000 10,000 80,000 20,000
5 70,000 14,000 10,000 140,000 20,000 50,000 10,000 90,000 10,000
6 75,000 12,500 5,000 150,000 10,000 60,000 10,000 90,000 0
7 78,000 11,143 3,000 156,000 6,000 70,000 10,000 86,000 -4,000
8 80,000 10,000 2,000 160,000 4,000 80,000 10,000 80,000 -6,000

P = Product price = TL2


W = Cost per unit of labor = TL10,000
 The firm should employ additional units
of X up to the point where
 additional marginal labor cost (MLC) of
adding X is more than made up for by the
additional marginal revenue product (MRP)
brought in by the sale of the increased
output.
 Where MRP = MLC
The Multiple Input Case
 In the more general case, the firm is faced
with the decision regarding the choice of
the optimal combination of inputs.
 For simplicity, we will consider the two-
input case.
 The assumption is that all inputs of the firm
can be divided into two basic categories.
Isoquant Curves
 An isoquant curve represents the various
combinations of two inputs that produce the
same amount of output.
 In the example, the following combinations of
inputs X and Y produce 52 units of output:
º 2,6
º 3,4
º 4,3
º 6,2
º 8,2
Example Isoquant Curve
7
6
5
Units of Y

4 Isoquant; TP = 52 units
3
2
1
0
0 2 4 6 8 10
Units of X
Isoquant Curves
 The slope and the shape of the
isoquant curves depend on the degree
of substitutability between the two
inputs.
 The degree of substitutability is a
measure of the ease with which one
input can be used in place of the other
in producing a given amount of output.
Isoquant Curves

Perfect Perfect Imperfect


Substitution Complementarity Substitution
Optimal Choice and
Substitutability
 Easiest is the perfect complementarity: X and Y
need to be used in a fixed proportion.
 Trivial is the perfect substitutability: X and Y
can be used in any proportion.
 Difficult is the imperfect substitutability: X and
Y need to be used such that the combination is
optimal by taking into account two factors:
 1. Degree of substitutability (how far can X be

substituted for Y?)


 2. Relative prices of X and Y
Marginal Rate of Technical
Substitution
 MRTS is a measure of the degree of substitutability
between two inputs:

MRTS (X for Y) = Y / X

 Numerator shows the amount of Y removed from


the production process and denominator shows the
amount of X needed to be added to the production
process in order to maintain the same amount of
output.
MRTS Along the Isoquant
Curve
 From the example:

Movement
from to MRTS
2,6 3,4 -2 / 1 = -2.0
3,4 4,3 -1 / 1 = -1.0
4,3 6,2 -1 / 2 = -0.5
6,2 8,2 0 / 2 = 0.0
MRTS Along the Isoquant
Curve
 As we move along the isoquant curve, the
absolute value of the MRTS declines.
 This phenomenon is called The Law of
Diminishing MRTS.
 This law implies that increasingly more of
input X is needed to compensate for the loss
of a given amount of input Y to maintain the
same output.
MRTS Along the Isoquant
Curve
 Why would the Law of Diminishing MRTS
hold?
 The answer comes from the marginal
products of the two inputs:
 Recall:
MPX = Q / X
MPX is the change in output relative to
the change in some given input.
 From point 1 to point 2 along the example isoquant, we
move from (2,6) to (3,4). This movement implies two
MPs:
Q
 We first change Y and keep X constant: Y
Q for (2,6) = 52 and Q for (2,4) = 39
Therefore, MPY = -13 / -2 = 6.5

 Then, we change X and keep Y constant at its new level:


Q for (2,4) = 39 and Q for (3,4) = 52
Therefore, MPX = 13 / 1 = 13
 From point 2 to point 3 along the example isoquant, we
move from (3,4) to (4,3). This movement implies two
MPs:

 We first change Y and keep X constant: Q


Q for (3,4) = 52 and Q for (3,3) = 41. Y
Therefore, MPY = -11 / -1 = 11

 Then, we change X and keep Y constant at its new level:


Q for (3,3) = 41 and Q for (4,3) = 52.
Therefore, MPX = 11 / 1 = 11
 Let’s look at the MRTS for points 1 and 2:
From point 1 to point 2:
-MPY . Y = MPX . X
needs to be true in order to maintain the same
level of output.
From this it follows that
ΔY MPX
  MRTS
ΔX MPY
 Therefore, the MRTS along an isoquant curve is equal to
the ratio of the marginal products for the two inputs.
 MRTS diminishes along the isoquant curve because the
relative marginal products change.
 Recall from earlier:
 From point 1 to point 2
MPX / MPY = 13 / 6.5 = 2
 From point 2 to point 3
MPX / MPY = 11 / 11 = 1
 As seen, the MRTS is declining as we
move down on the isoquant curve.
 The reason the Law of Diminishing MRTS
holds is that as we move to the extreme
points along the isoquant curve, the
marginal product of the input being added
(X) declines relative to the marginal
product of the input being reduced (Y).
Optimal Combination of
Multiple Inputs
 The budget limit imposed upon the firm
will be the second factor to consider in
choosing the optimal combination.
 The isocost curve shows the different
combinations of the two inputs that can
be purchased with a given level of
monetary budget:
E = PX.X + PY.Y
 Rearrange the isocost curve equation:

E PX
Y  X
PY PY

 For example, suppose a firm has a budget of


TL1,000 to spend on inputs X and Y. Also,
suppose PX = TL100 and PY = TL200. Then,
TL1,000 = TL100 X + TL200 Y
Combination X Y
A 0 5
B 2 4
C 4 3
D 6 2
E 8 1
F 10 0
These are the possible combinations of X and
Y that lie on the isocost curve of TL1,000.
Y 6 ISOCOST1; E = TL1,000
5
4
3
2
1
0
0 2 4 6 8 10 12
X
Optimal Combination of
Multiple Inputs
 Recall that there are two factors in
determining the optimal input:
1. Degree of substitutability (how far can
X be substituted for Y?):
MRTS = -MPX / MPY
2. Relative prices of X and Y:
Slope of the isocost = PX / PY
 For decision making, we need to combine the
information from the isoquant curve with the
information from the isocost curve:

Y 7
6
optimal combination
5
4
3
2
1
0
0 2 4 6 8 10 12

X
 The optimal combination occurs at the point
where the isoquant curve is tangent to the
isocost curve.
 At the point of tangency, the slopes of the
two curves need to be equal to each other:

MPX PX
 
MPY PY
 Rearranging terms,

MPX MPY

PX PY
 At the best (optimal) combination each
input has the same amount of marginal
product per dollar/lira spent on that
input.
 If the following is true:
MPX MPY

PX PY
then, we can improve our utilization of the
budget by employing more units of X and
fewer units of Y.
 As X , MPX  and as Y , MPY .
 As a result, the equality is reached where

MPX MPY

PX PY
 If the following is true:
MPX MPY

PX PY
then, we can improve our utilization of the
budget by employing more units of Y and
fewer units of X.
 As Y , MPY  and as X , MPX .
 As a result, the equality is reached where

MPX MPY

PX PY
The Long-Run Production
Function
 In the long-run, the firm has enough
time to change the amount of all of its
inputs.
 When the firm changes the amount of
all inputs, the resulting change in the
total product is called the “returns to
scale.”
Units of Y
Employed Output Quantity (Q)
8 37 60 83 96 107 117 127 128
7 42 64 78 90 101 110 119 120
6 37 52 64 73 82 90 97 104
5 31 47 58 67 75 82 89 95
4 24 39 52 60 67 73 79 85
3 17 29 41 52 58 64 69 73
2 8 18 29 39 47 52 56 52
1 4 8 14 20 27 24 21 17
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8
Units of X Employed
Returns to Scale
 Increasing returns to scale are observed when
%  in inputs < %  in Q
 Decreasing returns to scale are observed when
%  in inputs > %  in Q
 Constant returns to scale are observed when
%  in inputs = %  in Q
Returns to Scale and
Output Elasticity
 Output elasticity is the measure of returns to
scale:
% change in Q
EQ 
% change in all inputs

 If EQ > 1, increasing returns to scale (IRTS)


 If EQ < 1, decreasing returns to scale (DRTS)
 If EQ = 1, constant returns to scale (CRTS)
Q Q Q

X,Y X,Y X,Y

IRTS DRTS CRTS

You might also like