Heuristics are mental shortcuts or rules of thumb that help people make decisions and draw inferences quickly when facing complex problems or limited information. Amos Tversky and Daniel Kahneman identified three common heuristics through their research:
1. Representativeness heuristic - Making judgments based on how representative something seems of a category without regard to base rates. This can lead to errors like the base rate fallacy.
2. Availability heuristic - Judging frequency or likelihood based on how easily examples can be recalled. This can cause overestimating dramatic but rare events.
3. Anchoring and adjustment heuristic - Making judgments by starting from an initial anchor value and adjusting upward or downward. This is used
Heuristics are mental shortcuts or rules of thumb that help people make decisions and draw inferences quickly when facing complex problems or limited information. Amos Tversky and Daniel Kahneman identified three common heuristics through their research:
1. Representativeness heuristic - Making judgments based on how representative something seems of a category without regard to base rates. This can lead to errors like the base rate fallacy.
2. Availability heuristic - Judging frequency or likelihood based on how easily examples can be recalled. This can cause overestimating dramatic but rare events.
3. Anchoring and adjustment heuristic - Making judgments by starting from an initial anchor value and adjusting upward or downward. This is used
Heuristics are mental shortcuts or rules of thumb that help people make decisions and draw inferences quickly when facing complex problems or limited information. Amos Tversky and Daniel Kahneman identified three common heuristics through their research:
1. Representativeness heuristic - Making judgments based on how representative something seems of a category without regard to base rates. This can lead to errors like the base rate fallacy.
2. Availability heuristic - Judging frequency or likelihood based on how easily examples can be recalled. This can cause overestimating dramatic but rare events.
3. Anchoring and adjustment heuristic - Making judgments by starting from an initial anchor value and adjusting upward or downward. This is used
Heuristics are mental shortcuts or rules of thumb that help people make decisions and draw inferences quickly when facing complex problems or limited information. Amos Tversky and Daniel Kahneman identified three common heuristics through their research:
1. Representativeness heuristic - Making judgments based on how representative something seems of a category without regard to base rates. This can lead to errors like the base rate fallacy.
2. Availability heuristic - Judging frequency or likelihood based on how easily examples can be recalled. This can cause overestimating dramatic but rare events.
3. Anchoring and adjustment heuristic - Making judgments by starting from an initial anchor value and adjusting upward or downward. This is used
Download as PPTX, PDF, TXT or read online from Scribd
Download as pptx, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 15
HEURISTICS
• heuristics—simple rules for making complex decisions or drawing inferences in a rapid and efficient manner.
• Amos Tversky and Daniel Kahneman have carried out series of
experiments to demonstrate that human beings use mental short-cuts to make sense of the world under conditions of uncertainty. They proved that individuals do not think rationally while making judgments. They make systematic errors and biases in their inferences. They argued that human beings use heuristics because they cannot manage information. This is known as information overload. Human cognitive system can process limited amount of information at a given point of time. When the information is more than it could be processed, we fail to process all information. This is called as information overload. • We use smart tactics under conditions of information overload and manage this information. These tactics are known as heuristics. Heuristics are simple rules of thumb or mental shortcuts that help us to make complex decisions and drawing inferences in speedy and efficient way. They reduces our mental efforts. Tversky and Kahneman have demonstrated the use of three heuristics. • They are : • 1. Representativeness Heuristics, • 2. Availability Heuristics, and • 3. Anchoring and Adjustment Heuristics. • Heuristics are rules of thumb or mental shortcuts that people use to make decisions and draw inferences rapidly and with reduced efforts when the cognitive system is overloaded with information. • In representativeness heuristic, a judgement is made about a person, event or object based on how similar or representative it is thought to be of a category or prototype. • Suppose that you have just met your next-door neighbor for the first time. While chatting with her, you notice that she is dressed conservatively, is neat in her personal habits, has a very large library in her home, and seems to be very gentle and a little shy. Later you realize that she never mentioned what she does for a living. Is she a business manager, a physician, a waitress, an artist, a dancer, or a librarian? One quick way of making a guess is to compare her with a prototype—a list of attributes commonly possessed by members of each of these occupations.
• If you made your judgment about your neighbor’s
• occupation in this manner, you used the representativeness heuristic. In other words, • you made your judgment on the basis of a relatively simple rule: The more an individual seems to resemble or match a given group, the more likely she or he is to belong • to that group. • Why did we make this error? It happened because we used something called as ‘representativeness heuristics’. When likelihood of an event is judged on the basis of the extent that it represents the essential features of the parent population or of its generating process is called as representativeness heuristics. When an individual is similar to a typical member of a given group, then he/she is judged to be more likely a member of that group. The heuristic is useful in inductive reasoning. • The use of this heuristic can systematically lead to make errors in judgements. One such example is ‘base rate fallacy’. In an experiment by Tversky and Kahneman, subjects were told that a profile of Jack is picked up from 100 profiles in which 30 are engineers and 70 are lawyers. Jack is 30 yr old man. He is married and had no children. He is man of high ability and high motivation and promises to be quite successful in his field. He is liked by his colleagues. What is more likely occupation of Jack? Many responded Engineer. While doing so they ignored very important information regarding base rate. The base rate of engineers is 30% and so the probability of Jack being an engineer can not be more than .30. This is called as base rate fallacy. Subjects ignored base rates because they focused on representativeness. Hence, representativeness heuristics can also lead to errors. AVAILABILITY HEURISTIC • . Now consider another, non-self-related question: Are you safer driving in a huge • SUV or in a smaller, lighter car? Many people would answer, “In the big SUV,” think • ing that if you are in an accident, you are less likely to get hurt in a big vehicle com • pared to a small one. While that might seem to be correct, actual data indicate that • death rates (number of deaths per 1 million vehicles on the road) are higher for SUVs • than smaller cars (e.g., Gladwell, 2004). • This example, and many similar judgment errors, illustrates the operation of the • availability heuristic, another cognitive “rule of thumb” suggesting that the easier • it is to bring information to mind, the greater its impact on subsequent judgments or • decisions. Use of this heuristic makes good sense much of the time. After all, the fact • that we can bring some types of information to mind quite readily suggests that it may • indeed be frequent or important, so it should influence our judgments and decisions. • But relying on availability in making social judgments can also lead to errors. Specifi • cally, it can lead us to overestimate the likelihood of events that are dramatic but rare, • because they are easy to bring to mind • he availability heuristic is a phenomenon in which people predict the frequency of an event, or a proportion within a population, based on how easily an example can be brought to mind. • There are situations in which people assess the frequency of a class or the probability of an event by the ease with which instances or occurrences can be brought to mind. E.g., one may assess the risk of heart attack among middle-aged people by recalling such occurrences among one's acquaintances. Availability is a useful clue for assessing frequency or probability ANCHORING AND ADJUSTMENT • When people attempt to sell something—whether it’s a house or a car, through an ad in a newspaper or online—they typically set the “asking” price higher than they really expect to get. Likewise, buyers often bid less initially than they expect to ultimately pay. This is mostly because buyers and sellers want to give themselves some room for bargaining. Often the selling price is the starting point for discussion; the buyer offers less, the seller counters, and the process continues until an agreement is reached. When a seller sets a starting price, this is an important advantage related to another heuristic that strongly influences our thinking: anchoring and adjustment. • This heuristic involves the tendency to deal with uncertainty in many situations by using something we do know as a starting point (the “anchor”) and then making adjustments to it. • The seller’s asking price provides such a starting point, to which buyers try to make adjustments in order to lower the price they pay. Lowering the price makes buyers feel they are getting a very good deal in comparison to the original asking price. • This too is how “sale pricing” and highly visible “reductions” work in retail stores—the original starting point sets the anchor so shoppers feel like they are then getting a bargain in comparison SOURCES OF ERROR IN SOCIAL COGINITION