0% found this document useful (0 votes)
87 views18 pages

CH 1. Introduction

Download as ppt, pdf, or txt
Download as ppt, pdf, or txt
Download as ppt, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1/ 18

INTRODUCTION TO ECONOMETRICS

Chapter I
WHAT IS ECONOMETRICS?

• Econometrics means “economic measurement”. the scope of


econometrics is much broader, as can be seen from the following
definitions:

• “Consists of the application of mathematical statistics to economic


data to lend empirical support to the models constructed by
mathematical economics and to obtain numerical results” (Gerhard
1968).

• “Econometrics may be defined as the social science in which the tools


of economic theory, mathematics, and statistical inference are
applied to the analysis of economic phenomena” (Goldberger 1964).

• “Econometrics is concerned with the empirical determination of


economic laws” (Theil 1971).
WHY ECONOMETRICS IS A SEPARATE DISCIPLINE?

• the subject deserves to be studied in its own right for the following
reasons:
• Economic theory makes statements or hypotheses that are mostly
qualitative in nature (eg. the law of demand). Economic law alone
does not provide any numerical measure of the relationship.
Providing numerical measure for the intended relationship is the job
of the econometrician.
• The main concern of mathematical economics is to express economic
theory in mathematical form without regard to measurability or
empirical verification of the theory. Econometrics is mainly interested
in the empirical verification of economic theory.
• Eg. Coub-Douglas production function is mathematical function. It can be increasing returns to scale, diminishing returns to scale or constant returns to
scale. In a given production unit, the type of returns to scale can be verified using empirical data making use of econometrics .

• Economic statistics is mainly concerned with collecting, processing,


and presenting economic data in the form of charts and tables. It does
not go any further. The one who goes further to show the precise
relationship among variables is the econometrician.
METHODOLOGY OF ECONOMETRICS

• Broadly speaking, traditional econometric methodology proceeds


along the following lines:

1. Statement of theory or hypothesis.


2. Specification of the mathematical model of the theory
3. Specification of the statistical, or econometric, model
4. Collecting the data
5. Estimation of the parameters of the econometric model
6. Hypothesis testing
7. Forecasting or prediction
8. Using the model for control or policy purposes.

• To illustrate the preceding steps, let us consider the well-known


Keynesian theory of consumption.
1. Statement of Theory or Hypothesis
• Keynes states that on average, consumers increase their consumption as
their income increases, but not as much as the increase in their income
(MPC < 1).

2. Specification of the Mathematical Model of Consumption (single-


equation model)
Y = β 1 + β2X 0 < β2 < 1 (I.3.1)

Y = consumption expenditure and (dependent variable)


X = income, (independent, or explanatory variable)
β1 = the intercept
β2 = the slope coefficient ---- Marginal Propensity to Consume (MPC)

• The slope coefficient β2 measures the MPC.


• Geometrically,
3. Specification of the Econometric Model of Consumption
• The relationships between economic variables are generally inexact. In
addition to income, other variables affect consumption expenditure. For
example, size of family, ages of the members in the family, family religion,
etc., are likely to exert some influence on consumption.

• To allow for the inexact relationships between economic variables, (I.3.1) is


modified as follows:

• Y = β 1 + β2X + u (I.3.2)

• where u, known as the disturbance, or error, term, is a random (stochastic)


variable that has well-defined probabilistic properties. The disturbance term
u may well represent all those factors that affect consumption but are not
taken into account explicitly.
• (I.3.2) is an example of a linear regression model, i.e., it hypothesizes that Y
is linearly related to X, but that the relationship between the two is not exact;
it is subject to individual variation. The econometric model of (I.3.2) can be
depicted as shown in Figure I.2.
4. Obtaining Data
• To obtain the numerical values of β1 and β2, we need data. Look at Table
I.1, which relate to the personal consumption expenditure (PCE) and the
gross domestic product (GDP). The data are in “real” terms.
The data are plotted in Figure I.3
5. Estimation of the Econometric Model
• Regression analysis is the main tool used to obtain the estimates. Using this
technique and the data given in Table I.1, we obtain the following estimates
of β1 and β2, namely, −184.08 and 0.7064. Thus, the estimated consumption
function is:

• Yˆ = −184.08 + 0.7064Xi (I.3.3)

• The estimated regression line is shown in Figure I.3. The regression line fits
the data quite well.

• The slope coefficient (i.e., the MPC) was about 0.70, meaning that an
increase in real income of 1 birr led, on average, to an increase of about 70
cents in real consumption.
6. Hypothesis Testing
• That is to find out whether the estimates obtained in, Eq. (I.3.3) are in
accordance with the expectations of the theory that is being tested. Keynes
expected the MPC to be positive but less than 1. In our example we found the
MPC to be about 0.70.

• But before we accept this finding as confirmation of Keynesian


consumption theory, we must enquire whether this estimate is sufficiently
below unity. In other words, is 0.70 statistically less than 1? If it is, it may
support Keynes’ theory.

• Such confirmation or refutation of economic theories on the basis of sample


evidence is based on a branch of statistical theory known as statistical
inference (hypothesis testing).
• Syntax: test income = 1, test income = 0.70 or test income = 0.
• P-value for t-test = 0.000 …. The probability of the coefficient to be zero = 0
• P-value for t-test = 0.000 …. Also for the probability of the coefficient to be = 1
7. Forecasting or Prediction
• To illustrate, suppose we want to predict the mean consumption
expenditure for 1997. If the GDP value for 1997 was 7269.8 billion birrs
consumption would be:

Yˆ1997 = −184.0779 + 0.7064 (7269.8) = 4951.3 (I.3.4)

• Assume that the actual value of the consumption expenditure reported in


1997 was 4913.5 billion birrs. The estimated model (I.3.3) thus over-
predicted the actual consumption expenditure by about 37.82 billion birrs.
We could say the forecast error is about 37.8 billion birrs, which is about
0.76 (37.82/4913.5) percent of the actual GDP value for 1997. Which is
less than 1%.

• Now suppose the government decides to propose a reduction in the income


tax. What will be the effect of such a policy on income and thereby on
consumption expenditure and ultimately on employment?
8. Use of the Model for Control or Policy Purposes
• Suppose we have the estimated consumption function given in (I.3.3).
• Suppose further the government believes that consumer expenditure of about
4900 will keep the unemployment rate at its current level of about 4.2% . What
level of income will guarantee the target amount of consumption expenditure?
• If the regression results given in (I.3.3) seem reasonable, simple arithmetic will
show that:
• 4900 = −184.0779 + 0.7064X (I.3.6)

• which gives X = 7197, approximately. That is, an income level of about 7197
(billion) birrs, given an MPC of about 0.70, will produce an expenditure of
about 4900 billion birrs.
• As these calculations suggest, an estimated model may be used for control, or
policy purposes. By appropriate fiscal and monetary policy mix, the
government can manipulate the control variable X to produce the desired level
of the target variable Y.
• Figure I.4 summarizes the anatomy of classical econometric modeling.
• Choosing among Competing Models
• When a governmental agency (e.g., CSA) collects economic data, such as
that shown in Table I.1, it does not necessarily have any economic theory in
mind.
• How then does one know that the data really support the Keynesian theory
of consumption? Check whether b1 = 0

• Is it because the Keynesian consumption function (i.e., the regression line)


shown in Figure I.3 is extremely close to the actual data points?
• Is it possible that another consumption model (theory) might equally fit the
data as well? For example, Milton Friedman has developed a model of
consumption, called the permanent income hypothesis. Robert Hall has also
developed a model of consumption, called the life-cycle permanent income
hypothesis. Could one or both of these models also fit the data in Table I.1?
• In short, the question facing a researcher in practice is how to
choose among competing hypotheses or models of a given
phenomenon, such as the consumption–income relationship.

• The eight-step classical econometric methodology discussed above is neutral


in the sense that it can be used to test any of these rival hypotheses.

• Is it possible to develop a methodology that is comprehensive enough to


include competing hypotheses? This is an involved and controversial topic.

You might also like