Lecture 9 - Merger Control II
Lecture 9 - Merger Control II
Lecture 9 - Merger Control II
(*except in exceptional circumstances – merger with potential or recent entrant, important innovators,
maverick, etc.)
Non- Horizontal Concentrations: Indicators
As the merging parties are not competitors on the same market,
cannot use combined market shares or the before-and-after
change in the HHI as indicators.
Creation or
A B C
strengthening of a
dominant position 33% 33+33=66%
D E F Elimination of
important competitive
66% 25+8=33%
force
e.g. fierce rivals (Heinz),
maverick firm
Horizontal Non-Coordinated Effects: Factors
EU Horizontal Guidelines [para 26] “A number of factors,
which taken separately are not necessarily decisive, may
influence whether significant non-coordinated effects are
likely to result from a merger. Not all of these factors need
to be present for such effects to be likely. Nor should this be
considered an exhaustive list.”
[paras 27-38]:
Merging firms have large market shares.
Merging firms are close competitors.
Customers have limited possibilities of switching
supplier.
Competitors are unlikely to increase supply if price
is increased.
Merged entity able to hinder expansion by
competitors.
Merger eliminates an importance competitive force.
Factor 1) Large Market Shares
EU Horizontal Guidelines, para 27: although only “first indications of market power and
increases in market power, they are normally important factors in the assessment.”
Never the sole consideration:
M.4564 Bridgestone/Bandag [2007] M.5747 Iberia/ British Airways [2010]
Bridgestone + Bandag = EEA leader for supplying Iberia and BA would have 70-80% market share on
pre-cure tread for tyre retreading, with 55-65% in some London-Spain routes…
Norway and 60-70% in the Netherlands…
… but unconditional clearance due to constraints
… but not particularly close imposed by smaller rivals, potential for competitor
competitors, in most markets expansion and entry, and pre-existing cooperation
Bridgestone’s pre-merger as part of One World alliance.
share was <5%, they supplied
different customer groups
(independent repairers v
franchisees), and had strong
competitors.
Factor 2) Closeness of Competition
Product/service differentiation within the same market may mean merging
firms are especially close rivals.
Para 243: Diversion ratios between two were based on small survey and produced results
inconsistent with elsewhere in decision.
Para 249: “Although it may indeed be established that Three and O2 are relatively close
competitors in some of the segments of a concentrated market comprising four mobile
network operators, that factor alone is not sufficient to prove, in the present case, the
elimination of the important competitive constraints which the parties to the concentration
exerted upon each other and cannot suffice to establish a significant impediment to effective
competition; if that were not the case, any concentration resulting in a reduction from four to
three operators would as a matter of principle be prohibited”.
Factor 3) Limited Customer Switching
M.986 Agfa Gevaert/DuPont [1998] Commission cleared with commitments the acquisition
by AG of DP’s negative plate production business
(used primarily in newspaper, book, and commercial
printing). 50-60% market share (nearest rival 20%),
competitors with limited capacity and/or lack of
distribution capabilities.
Commission stated that “tele.ring, as a maverick, has a much greater influence on the competitive
process in this market than its market share would suggest.”
Commitments for divestiture of parts of TR’s network and capacity to 3, which lacked its own
country-wide coverage.
Factor 6) Elimination of an Important Competitive Force
M.7612 Hutchison 3G UK/Telefónica UK [2016]
Commission prohibited 3 (4th largest operator by subscribers) from
acquiring O2 (2nd) for a number of reasons, including elimination of a
competitive force. Would be biggest firm (30-40%) but not dominant.
“Three is the latest network operator to have entered the market and
has been the driver of competition since its entry, for example by
changing the industry trend of restricting data usage and data price
increases. Its recent and current market behaviour shows that it is the
most aggressive and innovative player. Namely, it offers the most
competitive prices in the direct channel, and offered 4G at no extra
cost, forcing the industry to abandon strategies to sell 4G at a
premium. It also offered such popular propositions as free
international roaming… Absent the transaction Three is likely to
continue to compete strongly.”
[paras 20-21 Summary Notice]
Factor 6) Elimination of an Important Competitive Force
T-399/16 CK Telecoms v Commission [2020]:The General Court
annulled the Commission decision.
Para 90: “Article 2(3) of Regulation No 139/2004 must be interpreted as
allowing the Commission to prohibit, in certain circumstances, on
oligopolistic markets concentrations which, although not giving rise to the
creation or strengthening of an individual or collective dominant position,
are liable to affect the competitive conditions on the market to an extent
equivalent to that attributable to such positions, by conferring on the
merged entity the power to enable it to determine, by itself, the parameters
of competition and, in particular, to become a price maker instead of
remaining a price taker.”
Para 172: “Such an interpretation of the concept of ‘important competitive force’, developed in the contested decision, would
introduce, if it were to be regarded as an autonomous legal criterion, a concept additional and alternative to the concept of
‘important competitive constraint’ set out in recital 25 of Regulation No 139/2004. That would lower the standard of
proof required to prove a significant impediment to effective competition, according to whether the Commission classifies the
foreseeable effects of a concentration as ‘non-coordinated effects’ or as ‘coordinated effects’”
Para 173: “The approach taken by the Commission in the contested decision amounts in practice to confusing three
concepts, namely the concept of a ‘significant impediment to effective competition’, which is the legal criterion referred to in
Article 2(3) of Regulation No 139/2004, the concept of ‘elimination of [an] important competitive [constraint]’, referred to in
recital 25 of that regulation, and the concept of elimination of an ‘important competitive force’, used in the contested decision
and based on the Guidelines. By confusing those concepts, the Commission considerably broadens the scope of
Article 2(3) of Regulation No 139/2004, since any elimination of an important competitive force would amount to the
elimination of an important competitive constraint which, in turn, would justify a finding of a significant impediment
to effective competition.”
Para 174: It follows that the Commission made an error of law and an error of assessment, in recital 326 of the contested
decision, in finding that an ‘important competitive force’ does not need to stand out from its competitors in terms of
impact on competition, particularly in so far as such a position would allow it to treat as an ‘important competitive force’ any
undertaking in an oligopolistic market exerting competitive pressure.”
III. 4(b) Non-Horizontal
Concentrations: Non-
Coordinated Effects
Non-Horizontal Concentrations: Non-Coordinated
Theories of Harm
Vertical Concentrations – different levels of supply chain:
Input Foreclosure – excluding rivals through limiting access to inputs.
Customer Foreclosure – excluding rivals through limiting access to
infrastructure/retailers/distributors and thus consumers.
Conglomerate Concentrations – neither horizontal nor vertical:
Foreclosure of rivals through tying/bundling complementary products.
All Same test: 1) Ability to foreclose; 2) Incentive to foreclose; 3)
Overall impact on competition.
Both covered in the Commission’s Guidelines on Non-Horizontal
Mergers [2008] and CMA’s Merger Assessment Guidelines [2010] –
again, apply the guidelines!
Vertical Non-Coordinated Theory of Harm I:
Input Foreclosure
Access of downstream
More Expensive
Input
Input rivals to upstream inputs
denied, restricted or
degraded
Consumers
Vertical Non-Coordinated Theory of Harm II: Customer
Foreclosure
Producer Producer Producer
A B C
Access of
upstream rivals
to downstream
outlets
More Expensive
Distributor Distributor restricted
↑£↑
Consumers
Vertical Non-Coordinated Effects
Question 1: Ability to Foreclose?
Essentially, extent of market power in upstream supplier / downstream
outlet market:
Significance of:
input for downstream product (critical component, significant cost
factor)?
outlet and size of customer base for upstream product?
Alternative suppliers and outlets? Costs of switching?
Rival suppliers/outlets less efficient, more expensive, less preferred,
capacity-constrained, diseconomies of scale?
Vertical Non-Coordinated Effects
Question 2: Incentive to Foreclose?
Would it be profitable for the merged entity to foreclose?
Would the losses in upstream input sales / not stocking upstream rivals
in downstream outlet outweigh the profits from foreclosure of rivals?
Will the merged entity capture all of the customers from excluded
rivals?
Capacity constraints:
Input: is the downstream entity unable to expand production to use
input and take customers from rivals?
Outlet: is the upstream entity unable to expand production to
attract customers of rivals?
Would the conduct undertaken be in breach of competition law?
Vertical Non-Coordinated Effects
Question 3: Overall Likely Impact on Effective Competition
Negative Effects Mitigating or Positive Effects
Merged entity forecloses rivals and LEAVE UNTIL PART 4(d):
increases own prices. countervailing buyer power, upstream
entry, efficiencies?
Merged entity increases rivals’ costs
Possible efficiencies from vertical
and consumer prices.
integration:
Elimination of double-marginalisation
Increased barriers to entry – potential
– lower consumer prices?
competitors lack access to inputs Better coordination of upstream and
/outlets (or have higher operating downstream operations, lower costs.
costs) so need to enter both upstream Align incentives: investments in new
and downstream markets at same products, processes, marketing.
time.
e.g. Vertical Non-Coordinated Effects
M.4854 TomTom/Tele Atlas [2008]
Ability to foreclose access to input:
TA market power (50% share).
Digital maps as critical component
of satnav devices.
No incentive to foreclose access to
input:
Low switching costs to Navteq.
Garmin, main TomTom rival, already in 8-year supply contract with TA so
unable to raise map prices.
Substantial loss of upstream licensing profits would not be compensated
by increased downstream sales.
e.g. Vertical Non-Coordinated BST
Sufficient
Customers?
Consideration of both input and
customer foreclosure is common.
M.4389 - WLR/BST [2007] (CD): WLR
(airbag producer) acquires BST (airbag fabric
producer). WLR
1. Input foreclosure for other airbag
producers? No ability (main customers are
strong, have own in-house fabric production)
or incentive (much more fabric produced by
BST than WLR can use). Sufficient
Inputs?
2. Customer foreclosure for other fabric producers? No ability as plenty of other
customers (WLR only had 15-25% of EU demand for fabrics) and its fabric rivals
were thus diversified.
Conglomerate Non-Coordinated Theory of Harm
Market 1 Market 2
merger
Highly desired Less desired
Rival product
product product
A B C
Barriers Barriers
to Entry 33% 33% 33% to Entry
↑£↑ ↑£↑ ↑£↑
2) “Monitoring Deviations”
3) “Deterrent Mechanisms”
4) “Reaction of Outsiders” [leave until
4(d) – CBP, Entry]
1) Reaching Terms of Coordination
Whether the nature of the market makes coordination reasonably
possible (see generally slide 39 oligopoly parallelism), e.g.,:
Fewer firms - M.1016 Price Waterhouse/Coopers & Lybrand [1999]:
“collective dominance involving more than three or four suppliers is unlikely
simply because of the complexity of interrelationships involved, and the
consequent temptation to deviate; such a situation is unstable and untenable
in the long term.”
Simple, homogenous product - M.1383 Exxon/Mobil [2004]: petrol.
Similar cost structures - M.4141 Linde/BOC [2006]: similar shares and
levels of vertical integration on various gas-production markets.
Stable Demand - M.4706 Superior Essex/Invex [2007]: infrequent and
valuable large orders from buyers made coordination in wire production
unlikely.
Elimination of a Maverick – M.7758 Hutchison 3G Italy/WIND/JV [2016].
2) Ability to Monitor - Transparency
Incentives to stick with and not undercut coordinated position
depends upon sufficient transparency for firms to monitor
deviations.
Transparency aided by, e.g.:
Fewer firms (not always - M.1383 Exxon/Mobil [2004]: 7 firms in Lux.).
Public prices / public trading.
Simple pricing and lack of discounting (reason for CJEU rejecting
coordinated effects in Bertelsmann [2008]).
Simple product (not met with bus production tenders in M.2201
Man/Autwärter [2002]).
Absence of confidential commercial negotiations.
Stable cost conditions.
Use of “most-favoured nation” or “meeting competition” clauses.
Participation in joint ventures - M.4141 Linde/BOC [2006].
3) Ability to Deter and Punish Deviations
Incentives to stick with coordinated position also depend upon a
credible, rapid, and certain mechanism for punishing deviations.
Could be, e.g.:
Simple cessation of profitable coordination
Retaliatory price war (but requires excess output capacity)
o Could be on other markets - M.1628 TotalFina/Elf [2001]: possible
aggressive reaction on different stretches of motorway.
Exclusion from profitable cooperation opportunities:
o M.3333 Sony/BMG [no 2] [2007]: exclusion from compilation
albums, but unlikely to be credible through loss of sales.
o M.4141 Linde/BOC [2006]: blocking strategic decisions and
hindering profitability of joint ventures between coordinating firms.
Poorer access to essential inputs/networks/IP held by a rival.
Non-Horizontal Concentrations and Coordinated Effects?
1) Reaching Terms of Coordination
Non-coordinated foreclosure of rivals reduces number of firms to lower levels.
Vertical integration may increase symmetry and decrease uncertainty between
firms (same internal decision-making, cost structures).
2) Monitoring Deviations
Non-coordinated foreclosure of rivals makes monitoring of fewer firms easier.
Contact with upstream/downstream part of vertically integrated entity as focal
point for monitoring.
3) Deterrent Mechanisms
Vertically integrated firm could use input/customer foreclosure to discipline firms
not following the coordinated price as a crucial supplier/buyer.
Rival conglomerate firms with multi-market contact could discipline (e.g. price
wars) those who break coordination on other markets.
V. 4(d) Mitigating Factors
Factors Making a SIEC Less Likely
Long-term
↑↑£££↑↑
Divert purchases?
contract to Will smaller
entice Retailer retailer also
entrant? Retailer A B benefit from A’s
strength?
Horizontal Guidelines: [para 64] “Countervailing buyer power [is]… the
bargaining strength that the buyer has vis-à-vis the seller in commercial
negotiations due to its size, its commercial significance to the seller and its
ability to switch to alternative suppliers.”
Countervailing Buyer Power: How?
Ability to undermine - or threaten to undermine - post-merger exercises
of market power through, e.g.,…
Switching to rival suppliers at low Reducing non-essential
cost. purchases.
Sponsoring new market entry or Aggressive competition in
rival expansion through giving a markets where the
long-term purchasing contract. producer/buyer directly compete.
Vertically integrating upstream to Pressurising the supplier through,
take over production. e.g., delaying purchases, time-
Reducing purchases of products limiting contracts.
on other markets where merged Delisting their products or giving
entity lacks market power. less favourable positions in store.
Countervailing Buyer Power: Incentives and Effect?
Not just the ability but incentive to exercise buyer power
[Horizontal Guidelines Para 66]:
Reluctance to exercise if rival buyers will also benefit.
Risk that buyers will just pass cost increases onto final customers.
More likely to constrain if final customers are very price sensitive or
retail market is competitive.
Commission will not accept CBP claims if they only shield
certain buyers from post-merger market power, with others
still paying higher prices [Horizontal Guidelines Para 67].
A particular risk if it is possible for the merged entity to engage in price
discrimination.
Countervailing Buyer Power
e.g. M.1225 Enso/Stora [1998] 50-70%
E/S would dominate market for liquid packaging
board, but buying market dominated by TP. Enso Stora
Commission found relationship of mutual
dependence.
Although switching very long and costly, TP buys
V 60-80%
50% of E+S output so they cannot lose its
custom.
TP also likely to sponsor entry or vertically
integrate due to expertise.
CBP suggested correct to
Two smaller purchasers also buy enough to
clear with commitments.
exercise considerable power over E/S, which will
not want to depend entirely on TP.
Countervailing Buyer Power
e.g. M.5658 Unilever/Sara Lee Body Care[2010]
Commission concerned largely about non-
coordinated effects in female deodorant
market, finding price increases likely.
Parties: major retailers have influence
through negotiating worse product placement,
V
delisting, or launching private labels.
Rejected: retailers would have little
incentive to not pass on price increases,
consumers don’t like private labels, no
Lack of CBP suggested need
business sense to stop “must-stock” brands. to secure commitments.
Impact of Entry on Post-Merger Market Power
Three aspects:
1. Likelihood of entry:
a. Extent of barriers to entry.
b. Existence and incentives of potential
competitors.
2. Timeliness: case-by-case, but usually within 2 years.
3. Sufficiency: substantial enough to deter and defeat
post-merger anticompetitive effects.
Entry
E.g. M.833 The Coca-Cola Company/Carlsberg A/S [1997]
Creation of FFJV for bottling and distributing their
various carbonated soft drinks brands in Nordic
countries, particularly giving joint control over 50% of
upstream brands and downstream bottling in Denmark.
Major barriers to entry: brand recognition, access to
distribution opportunities (e.g. network, shelf space),
pre-existing commercial relations, advertising sunk
costs. Evidence of little previous entry except by major
international brands.
Clearance conditional on divestiture of 2 products.
Entry
E.g. M.5830 Olympic/Aegean Airlines (I) [2011]
Proposal for investors in A and O to jointly control both airlines together.
Commission prohibited the concentration: 90-100% on Greek domestic
flight routes, 30-40% of international flights out of Athens, very close
competitors, elimination of potential competition on Athens-Corfu route.
Entry unlikely: need base at Athens airport (expensive, congested),
recognised brand image, significant sunk cost, need access to connecting
traffic and Greek travel agents.