The document discusses indifference curve analysis in economics. It explains that:
1) A budget line shows the combinations of two goods that can be purchased given prices and income, shifting with changes in income or prices.
2) Indifference curves reflect consumer preferences, showing combinations providing equal satisfaction. They slope downward and are convex, with a diminishing willingness to substitute one good for another.
3) Equilibrium occurs where the highest indifference curve is tangent to the budget line, maximizing utility subject to the budget constraint.
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PPTX, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0 ratings0% found this document useful (0 votes)
44 views23 pages
Economics Lecture 5: Indifference Curve Analysis
The document discusses indifference curve analysis in economics. It explains that:
1) A budget line shows the combinations of two goods that can be purchased given prices and income, shifting with changes in income or prices.
2) Indifference curves reflect consumer preferences, showing combinations providing equal satisfaction. They slope downward and are convex, with a diminishing willingness to substitute one good for another.
3) Equilibrium occurs where the highest indifference curve is tangent to the budget line, maximizing utility subject to the budget constraint.
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PPTX, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 23
Economics Lecture 5
INDIFFERENCE CURVE ANALYSIS
The Budget line :What is Attainable
• A budget line (or more technically, the
budget constraint) is a schedule or curve that shows various combinations of two products a consumer can purchase with a specific money income. The Budget Line: Whole-Unit Combinations of A and B Attainable with an Income of $12 Units of A Units of B (Price = $1.50) (Price = $1) Total Expenditure 8 0 $12 (=$12+$0) 6 3 $12 (=$9+$3) 4 6 $12 (=$6+$6) 2 9 $12 (=$3+$9) 0 12 $12 (=$0+$12) A consumers budget line. The budget line shows all the combinations of any two products that can be purchased, given the prices of the products and the consumers money income. The Budget line :What is Attainable • The budget line has two other significant characteristics: • Income changes The location of the budget line varies with the money income. An increase in money income shifts the budget line to the right. A decrease in money income shifts it to the left. • Price changes A change in product prices also shifts the budget line. A decline in the prices of both products- the equivalent of an increase in real income – shifts the curve to the right. Conversely , an increase in the prices of products shifts the curve to the left. • But these situation have some exceptions if price of one product changes while price of another product and money income remain constant. Indifference Curve: What is Preferred
• Budget lines reflect “objective” market data,
specifically income and prices. They reveal combinations of products A and B that can be purchased, given current money income and prices. • Indifference curves, on the other hand, reflect “subjective” information about consumer preferences for A and B. Indifference Curve: What is Preferred (Cont’d) • An indifference curve shows all the combinations of two products A and B that will yield the same total satisfaction or total utility to a consumer. Table 2 and Figure 2 present a hypothetical indifference curve for products A and B. The consumer’s subjective preferences are such that he or she will realize the same total utility from each combination of A and B shown in the table or on the curve. So the consumer will be indifferent (will not care) as to which combination is actually obtained. • Indifference curves have several important characteristics. An Indifference Schedule (Whole Units)
Combination Units of A Units of B
j 12 2 k 6 4 l 4 6 m 3 8 Indifference Curves Are Downsloping • An indifference curve slopes downward because more of one product means less of the other if total utility is to remain unchanged. Suppose the consumer moves from one combination of A and B to another, say, from j to k in figure 2. In so doing, the consumer obtains more of product B, increasing his or her total utility. But because total utility is the same everywhere on the curve, the consumer must give up some of the other product, A, to reduce total utility by a precisely offsetting amount. Thus “more of B” necessitates “less of A”, and the quantities of A and B are inversely related. A curve that reflects inversely related variables is downward- sloping. Indifference Curves Are Convex to the Origin
• An Indifference Curve is convex (bowed inward) to the origin
of the graph. Its slope diminishes or becomes flatter as we move down the curve from j to k to l and so on. Technically the slope of an Indifference Curve at each point measures the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) of the combination of two goods represented by that point. The slope or MRS shows the rate at which the consumer who possesses the combination will substitute one good for the other (say, B for A) to remain equally satisfied. The diminishing slope of the Indifference Curve means that the willingness to substitute B for A diminishes as more of B is obtained. Indifference Curves Are Convex to the Origin Contd… • The rationale for this convexity-that is, for a diminishing MRS-is that a consumer’s subjective willingness to substitute B for A (or A for B) will depend on the amounts of B and A he or she has to begin with. ConsiderTable2 and Figure 2 again, beginning at point j. Here, in relative terms ,the consumer has a substantial amount of A and very little of B. Within this combination, a unit of B is very valuable (that is, its marginal utility is high), while a unit of A is less valuable ( its marginal utility is low). The consumer will then be willing to give up a substantial amount of A to get , say,2 more units of B. in this case, the consumer is willing to forgo 6 units of A to get 2 more units of B; the MRS if 6/2 or 3, for the jk segment of the curve. Indifference Curves Are Convex to the Origin Contd… But at point k the consumer has less A and more B. Here A is somewhat more valuable and B less valuable, ‘at the margin’. In a move from point k to point l, the consumer is willing to give up only 2 units of A to get 2 more units of B, so the MRS is only 2/2, or 1 .Having still less of A and more of B at point l, the consumer is willing to give up only 1 unit of A in return for 2 more units of B and the MRS falls to ½ between l and m . Indifference Curves Are Convex to the Origin Contd… • In general, as the amount of B increases the marginal utility of additional units of B decreases. Similarly as the quantity of A decreases, its marginal utility increases . In Figure 2 we see that in moving down the curve, the consumer will be willing to give up smaller and smaller amounts of A to offset acquiring each additional unit of B. The result is a curve with a diminishing slope, a curve that is convex to the origin. MRS declines as one moves southeast along the indifference curve. The Indifference Map • An indifference map is a set of indifference curves . Curves further from the origin indicate higher levels of total utility. Thus any combination of product A and B represented by a point on I4 has greater total utility than any combination of A and B represented by a point on I3, I2 or I1. • (Look at slide below) The Indifference Map Equilibrium at Tangency The consumer’s equilibrium position. The consumer’s equilibrium position is represented by point X, where the black budget line is tangent to indifference curve I3. The consumer buys 4 units of A at $1.5 per unit and 6 of B at $1 per unit with a $12 money income. Points Z and Y represent attainable combinations of A and B but yield less total utility, as is evidenced by the fact that they are on lower indifference curves. Point W would entail more utility than X, but it requires a greater income than the $12 represented by the budget line. (Look at slide below) Equilibrium at Tangency Equilibrium at Tangency Contd… • In previous slide, the consumers equilibrium position is at point X, where the budget line is tangent to I3. • Here Y will not be the equilibrium position. Because Y is on a lower indifference curve, I2. By moving ‘down’ the budget line – by shifting dollars from purchases of A to purchases of B – the consumer can attain an indifference curve further from the origin and thereby increase the total utility derived from the same income . • Same situation for point Z also. Point Z is on a lower indifference curve , I1. By moving up the budget line- by reallocating dollars from B to A – the consumer can get on higher indifference curve I3 and increase total utility. Equilibrium at Tangency Equilibrium at Tangency Contd… •• Now come to the point W on indifference curve I4. It is true that W would yield a greater total utility than X, Point W is beyond (outside) the budget line and that’s why not attainable by the consumer. Point X represents the optimal attainable combination of products A and B . Note that according to the definition of tangency , the slope of the highest attainable indifference curve equals the slope of the budget line . Because the slope of the indifference curve reflects the MRS and the slope of the budget line is PB/PA, the consumers optimal or equilibrium position is the point where MRS = The Measurement of Utility • There is an important difference between the marginal utility theory of • consumer demand and the indifference curve theory. The marginal-utility theory assumes that utility is numerically measurable, that is , that the consumer can say how much extra utility he or she derives from each extra unit of A or B. The consumer needs that information to realize the utility – maximizing (equilibrium) position, as indicated by
• The indifference curve approach imposes a less stringent requirement on
the consumer. He or she need only specify whether a particular combination of A and B will yield more than, less than, or the same amount of utility as some other combination of A and B will yield. The consumer need only say, for example, that 6 of A and 7 of B will yield more (or less) satisfaction than will 4 of A and 9 of B. indifference curve theory does not require that the consumer specify how much more (or less) satisfaction will be realized. The Measurement of Utility Contd. • When we compare the equilibrium situations in the two theories, we find that in the indifference curve analysis the MRS equals PB /PA at equilibrium; however, in the marginal-utility approach the ratio of marginal utilities equals PB /PA . We therefore deduce that at equilibrium the MRS is equivalent in the marginal-utility approach to the ratio of the marginal utilities of the last purchased units of the two products.