Basic Training: Shahadat Hossain, PHD Cu Cba University of Chittagong
Basic Training: Shahadat Hossain, PHD Cu Cba University of Chittagong
Contents:
Functional relationship,
Economic model,
Calculus and optimization,
Regression analysis.
Functional Relationships;
Total, Average, and Marginal
In mathematics, an equation of the form
y =f(x)
is read "y is a function of x." This means that the value of y depends on the
value of x in a systematic way and that there is a unique value of y for each
value of x.
Usually the variable on the left-hand side of the equation, in this case, is
called the dependent variable and
60
A= 57/7=8.14
50
30
20
10
0
0 2 4 6 8 10 12
There are important relationships among the three functions that are
true for all total, average, and marginal functions.
First, the value of the average function at any point along that curve
is equal to the slope of a ray drawn from the origin to the total
function at the corresponding point. For example, from previous
table, it is known that the average product of six workers is 6.7.
Thus. the slope of a line (OA) drawn from the origin to point A on the
total product function has a slope of 6.7.
Another key relationship is that the value of the marginal function
is equal to the slope of the line drawn tangent to the total function at
a corresponding point. For example, the slope of the dashed line
CD, which is drawn tangent to the total function at E, is about 4. This
means that the marginal product corresponding to this point (i.e.,
between 2 and 3 units of labor) is 4.
Point F on the total function is called an inflection point. To the left of
point F, the total function is increasing at an increasing rate; to the
right of F, the total function is increasing but at a decreasing rate.
Note that this inflection point, corresponding to about six workers,
occurs at the point where the marginal product function is at a
maximum (i.e., point H in lower part).
If the marginal and average functions intersect, that point of
intersection will be at the minimum or maximum point on the average
function. In the Figure, the intersection occurs at point G, which is the
maximum point of the average product function.
If the marginal function is positive, the total function must be rising.
Note that it does not matter whether the marginal function is
increasing or decreasing, as long as it is positive.
Conversely, if the marginal function is negative, the total function
must be declining. Again, it does not matter if marginal is rising or
falling.
If marginal is negative, the total function will be declining. For the
data in Table and Figure , the marginal product is positive for the first
nine workers. It declines after the sixth worker but remains positive
through the ninth. Note that total product increases until the tenth
worker is added. The marginal product of the tenth worker is –1, and
this negative marginal product is associated with a decline in total
product.
Because the total function increases as long as the marginal
function is positive and decreases when marginal is negative,
it follows that total product is at a maximum when the marginal
function is zero.
In Figure the maximum of the total product function occurs at
nine workers. This point corresponds to the point where the
marginal function intersects the horizontal axis, that is, where
marginal changes from being positive to negative.
Economic Model
In economics, graphs and/or equations are used to explain economic relationships
and phenomena and to predict the effects of changes in such economic parameters
as prices. wage rates and the price of capital.
Although such models are abstractions from reality and may seem unrealistic, they
are useful in studying the way an economic system works. An economic decision
should not be made without having first analyzed its implications by using an
economic model.
An economic model usually consists of several related functions, some restrictions
on one or more of the coefficients of these functions, and equilibrium conditions.
Recall the concepts of supply and demand from introductory economics. As shown in
Figure in next slide the demand curve (DD) slopes downward from left to right and
shows the quantity of output that consumers are willing and able to , buy at each price.
The negative Slope implies that , larger quantity is, demanded at lower prices than at
higher prices. The supply curve (SS) shows the amount that firms will produce and
offer for sale at each price. This curve has a positive slope because firms will supply
a larger quantity at higher prices than at lower prices.
Graphical presentation of Supply and
Demand analysis:
Equilibrium in a market exists when the quantity demanded
equals the quantity supplied.
This is shown graphically as the intersection of the demand and
supply functions in previous Figure .
In this example, P*, and Q*, are the equilibrium price and
quantity, respectively.
In equilibrium there is no incentive for buyers or sellers to
change price or the quantity.
At point [P*, Q*], buyers' demands are met exactly and
suppliers are selling exactly the number of units they desire to
sell at that price.
The preceding example is an economic model depicted
graphically. A simple algebraic model can be used to describe
exactly the same economic phenomenon.
The quantity demanded (Qd) and the quantity supplied (Qs) are both
functions of price. That is,
Qd= f(P) and Qs= f(P)
Suppose that the demand function is
Qd = a +bP where b < 0 ………….. E1 and
the supply function is
Qs = c + dP where d > 0 ……………. E2
The restrictions on the parameters (i.e., b < 0 and d > 0) simply mean
that the demand curve must slope downward (i.e., have a negative
slope) and that the supply curve must slope upward (i.e., have a positive
slope).
By adding an equilibrium condition that the quantity supplied equals the
quantity demanded, that is,
Qd = Qs, ………………..E3
the economic model, consisting of equations E1, E2 and E3, is complete.
The equilibrium price (P,) can be determined. Substituting equations
a+ bP = c + dP
Solving for P, the equilibrium price is
Pe=(c-a)/(b-d)
And the equilibrium quantity Qe is
Qe = a+ b(c-a)/(b-d)
If the values of the parameters a, b, c, and d are known,
the actual values of Pe, and Qe, can easily be calculated.
Example:
Determine the equilibrium price and quantity
from the following demand and supply
function:
Qd= 14-2P
Qs= 2+ 4P
Probability and Probability
Distribution:
Managers are often faced with making decisions that have the potential for
a variety of outcomes.
An outcome is a possible result of some action. For example, flipping a coin
will result in one of two outcomes—heads or tails.
A management decision to introduce a new product could result in a range
of outcomes varying from wide consumer acceptance to no interest
whatsoever.
The quality of any decision will be enhanced by identifying the possible
outcomes of the decision and then estimating the relative chances of each
occurring.
This listing of outcomes and the chance of each occurring is a probability
distribution that can be evaluated using quantitative techniques.
Probability and probability distributions are an important part of the
manager’s tool kit.
Probability:
This means that when the experiment is conducted, one of the outcomes
must occur. It then follows that the probability that an event will not occur is
1 minus the probability that it will occur.
For example, if the probability of a 6 occurring when rolling a die is 1/6, this
implies that the probability of not rolling a six is 1- (1/6)= 5/6
A listing of each outcome of an experiment and its probability defines a
probability distribution.
For example, the probabilities of tossing 0,1,2 or 3 heads in three tosses of a
coin are shown as in the following table. X i is the number of heads observed in
each experiment of three tosses.