CH 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets
CH 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets
CH 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 8e. 1 of 28
MARKET EFFICIENCY
Efficiency is the property of a resource allocation of maximizing the total surplus [= consumer surplus and producer surplus] received by all members of society.
In addition to market efficiency, a social planner might also care about equity – the fairness of the distribution of well-being among the various buyers and sellers.
Chapter 9: The Analysis of Competitive Markets
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 8e. 2 of 28
Consumer and Producer Surplus in the Market
Equilibrium
•Price •A
•D
•Supply
Chapter 9: The Analysis of Competitive Markets
•Consumer
•surplus
•Equilibrium •E
•price
•Producer
•surplus
•Demand
•B
•C
•0 •Equilibrium •Quantity
•quantity
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 8e. 3 of 28
•Copyright©2003 Southwestern/Thomson Learning
9.1 EVALUATING THE GAINS AND LOSSES
FROM GOVERNMENT POLICIES—
CONSUMER AND PRODUCER SURPLUS
Review of Consumer and Producer Surplus
Figure 9.1
Chapter 9: The Analysis of Competitive Markets
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 8e. 4 of 28
9.1 EVALUATING THE GAINS AND LOSSES
FROM GOVERNMENT POLICIES—
CONSUMER AND PRODUCER SURPLUS
Review of Consumer and Producer Surplus
Figure 9.1
Consumer and Producer Surplus
Chapter 9: The Analysis of Competitive Markets
(continued)
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 8e. 5 of 28
Efficiency in the market equilibrium
surplus.
•Market failure Situation in which an
unregulated competitive market is
inefficient because prices fail to provide
proper signals to consumers and
producers.
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 8e. 6 of 28
Evaluating the impacts of government
intervention
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 8e. 7 of 28
9.1 EVALUATING THE GAINS AND LOSSES
FROM GOVERNMENT POLICIES—
CONSUMER AND PRODUCER SURPLUS
Application of Consumer and Producer Surplus
● welfare effects Gains and losses to consumers and
producers.
Chapter 9: The Analysis of Competitive Markets
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 8e. 8 of 28
9.2 THE EFFICIENCY OF A COMPETITIVE MARKET
Figure 9.5
Welfare Loss When Price is Held
Above Market-Clearing Level
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 8e. 9 of 28
PRICE CEILING: MATHEMATICAL
IMPLICATION
Supply and demand equations for government housing are
given below.
Supply: QS = 16,000 + 0.4P
Demand: QD = 32,000 - 0.4P
Now assume that, government has set a price ceiling of
15000 Taka by considering the social need of the
product/service. What will be the impacts of this
intervention. Do you support this type of intervention by
government? Why or why not?
PRICE FLOOR OR MINIMUM
PRICE
A price minimum is a
regulation that makes
it illegal to trade at a
price lower than a
specified level.
If the price minimum <
the equilibrium price,
no effect
If the price minimum >
the equilibrium price,
powerful effects
Example is minimum
wage rule.
9.3 MINIMUM PRICES
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 8e. 12 of 28
9.4 PRICE SUPPORTS AND PRODUCTION QUOTAS
Price Supports
● price support Price set by government above free market level and
maintained by governmental purchases of excess supply.
Prince Supports
Chapter 9: The Analysis of Competitive Markets
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 8e. 13 of 28
PRICE SUPPORT: MATHEMATICAL
EXAMPLE
1981 Supply of rice: QS = 1800 + 240P
1981 Demand for rice: QD = 3550 - 266P
Price Quotas
Figure 9.11
Supply Restrictions
To maintain a price Ps above the
market-clearing price P0, the
Chapter 9: The Analysis of Competitive Markets
ΔCS = −A − B
ΔPS = A − C + Payments for not producing (or at least B + C + D)
COST OF THE GOVERNMENT = -B –C –D
ΔWelfare = -A –B + A –C +B+C+D – B – C -D = -B -C
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 8e. 15 of 28
9.5 IMPORT QUOTAS AND TARIFFS
● import quota Limit on the quantity of a good that can be
imported.
● tariff Tax on an imported good.
Figure 9.14
Chapter 9: The Analysis of Competitive Markets
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 8e. 16 of 28
9.5 IMPORT QUOTAS AND TARIFFS
Figure 9.15
to P*.
This can be achieved by a quota, or
by a tariff T = P* − Pw.
Trapezoid A is again the gain to
domestic producers.
The loss to consumers is A + B + C
+ D.
If a tariff is used, the government
gains D, the revenue from the tariff.
The net domestic loss is B + C.
If a quota is used instead, rectangle
D becomes part of the profits of
foreign producers, and the net
domestic loss is B + C + D.
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 8e. 17 of 28
Find the DWL under Tariff and Import Quota.
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 8e. 18 of 28
TARIFF VS IMPORT QUOTA: WHICH ONE IS GOOD
FOR A HOME COUNTRY?
TARIFF:
Change of CS = -A-B-C-D
Change of PS = A
Govt. revenue (tariff) = C
IMPORT QUOTA
Welfare loss = -B- D -C
Welfare Loss
= -A-B-C-D+A +C
= -B -D
Chapter 9: The Analysis of Competitive Markets
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 8e. 19 of 28
7. Suppose the government wants to limit imports of a certain good. Is it preferable to use
Changes in domestic consumer and producer surpluses are the same under import quotas and
Chapter 9: The Analysis of Competitive Markets
tariffs. There will be a loss in (domestic) total surplus in either case. However, with a tariff, the
government can collect revenue equal to the tariff times the quantity of imports and these revenues
can be redistributed in the domestic economy to offset the domestic deadweight loss by, for
example, reducing taxes. Thus, there is less of a loss to the domestic society as a whole. With the
import quota, foreign producers can capture the difference between the domestic and world price
times the quantity of imports. Therefore, with an import quota, there is a loss to the domestic
society as a whole. If the national government is trying to increase welfare, it should use a tariff.
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 8e. 20 of 28
IMPACT OF TAX
Who really pays these
taxes?
Income tax (Direct tax) -
deducted from your pay,
GST (Indirect tax) - added
to the price of most things
you buy
Direct tax reduces the buying
power of the individuals and
thus shifts the demand curve
to the left.
INCIDENCE OF INDIRECT
TAX
Figure shows the effects of this tax.
With no tax: Equil. price = $3.00 a
packet
With tax on sellers of $1.50 a packet
Indirect tax amount equals the
vertical distance between two supply
curves
The market price paid by buyers
rises to $4.00 a packet and the
quantity bought decreases.
The price received by the sellers
falls to $2.50 a packet.
Let’s see the change in consumer
and producer surplus ,Govt.
Revenue, and DWL;
9.6 THE IMPACT OF A TAX OR SUBSIDY
● specific tax Tax of a certain amount of money per unit sold.
Figure 9.17
Incidence of a Tax
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 8e. 23 of 28
INEFFICIENCY CREATED BY INDIRECT
TAX
Tax revenue takes part of the total surplus.
The decreased quantity creates a deadweight loss
MATHEMATICAL EXAMPLE ON
INDIRECT TAX
Demand equation is Q = 9 –P
Supply equation is Q = -1 + P
Government has imposed an indirect tax of 2 Taka on the
product. Find the new equilibrium, change in consumer
and producer surplus and amount of government revenue
and DWL.
First convert the Supply equation to: P =1 + Q
And Demand equation to: P = 9 -Q .
EXERCISE 2.
A Tax on Buyers
AA taxtax on on
buyers
buyers shifts
shifts Effects of a $1.50 per
the
the DD curve
curve unit tax on buyers
down P
down byby the
the
amount
amount of
of the
the S1
PB = $11.00
tax.
tax. Tax
$10.00
The
The price
price buyers
buyers PS = $9.50
pay
pay rises,
rises, thethe
price
price sellers
sellers
receive falls, D1
receive falls,
equilibrium
equilibrium Q Q D2
falls.
falls. Q
430 500