Credit Risk Modelling : The Basics
By: A V Vedpuriswar
October 4, 2009
Introduction to Credit Risk Modelling
Credit risk modeling helps to estimate how much credit is 'at risk'
due to a default or changes in credit risk factors.
By doing so, it enables managers to price the credit risks they face
more effectively.
It also helps them to calculate how much capital they need to set
aside to protect against such risks.
2
Market Risk vs Credit Risk Modelling
Compared to market risk modeling, credit risk modeling is a relatively new science.
Credit risk models are not a simple extension of market risk models.
Credit risk is more contextual.
The time horizon is usually longer for credit risk.
Legal issues are more important in case of credit risk.
The upside is limited while the downside is huge.
If the counterparty defaults, while the contract has negative value, the solvent party
typically cannot walk away from the contract.
But if the defaulting party goes bankrupt, while the contract has a positive value,
only a fraction of the funds owed will be received.
3
Data
There are serious data limitations.
Market data is plentiful.
But bankruptcy data are rare.
4
Liquidity
Market prices are readily available for instruments that give rise to
market risk.
However, most credit instruments don't have easily observed market
prices.
There is less liquidity in the price quotes for credit instruments, such as
bank loans, compared to interest rate instruments or equities.
This lack of liquidity makes it very difficult to price credit risk for a
particular obligor in a mark-to-market approach.
To overcome this lack of liquidity, credit risk models must sometimes
use alternative types of data (historical loss data).
5
Distribution of losses
Market risk is often modeled by assuming that returns follow a normal
distribution though sometimes it does not hold good.
The normal distribution, however, is completely inappropriate for
estimating credit risk.
Returns in the global credit markets are heavily skewed to the downside
and are therefore distinctly non-normal.
Banks' exposures are asymmetric in nature.
There is limited upside but large downside.
The distribution exhibits a fat tail.
6
Correlation & Diversification
Diversification is the main tool for reducing credit risk.
For most obligors, hedges are not available in the market.
But there are limits to diversification.
A loan portfolio might look well diversified by its large number of
obligors.
But there might still be concentration risk caused by a large single
industry/country exposure.
Also correlations can dramatically shoot up in a crisis.
7
Expected, unexpected and stress losses
8
Expected Loss
The expected loss (EL) is the amount that an institution expects to
lose on a credit exposure over a given time horizon.
EL = PD x LGD x EAD
If we ignore correlation between the LGD variable, the EAD
variable and the default event, the expected loss for a portfolio is the
sum of the individual expected losses.
How should we deal with expected losses?
In the normal course of business, a financial institution should set
aside an amount equal to the expected loss as a provision.
Expected loss can be built into the pricing of loan products.
9
Unexpected loss
Unexpected loss is the amount by which potential credit losses might
exceed the expected loss.
Traditionally, unexpected loss is the standard deviation of the portfolio
credit losses.
But this is not a good risk measure for fat-tail distributions, which are
typical for credit risk.
To minimize the effect of unexpected losses, institutions are required
to set aside a minimum amount of regulatory capital.
Apart from holding regulatory capital, however, many sophisticated
banks also estimate the necessary economic capital to sustain these
unexpected losses.
10
Stress Losses
Stress losses are those that occur in the tail region of the portfolio
loss distribution.
They occur as a result of exceptional or low probability events (a
0.1% or 1 in 1,000 probability in the distribution below).
While these events may be exceptional, they are also plausible and
their impact is severe.
11
Measuring Credit loss
In simple terms, a credit loss can be described as a decrease in the
value of a portfolio over a specified period of time.
So we must estimate both current value and the future value of the
portfolio at the end of a given time horizon.
There are two conceptual approaches for measuring credit loss:
– default mode paradigm
– mark-to-market paradigm
12
Default mode paradigm
A credit loss is considered to have occurred only if a borrower defaults
within the modeled time horizon.
This approach is sometimes referred to as the two-state model.
The obligor either does or does not default.
If no default occurs, the credit loss is obviously zero.
If default occurs, exposure at default and loss given default must be
estimated.
13
Mark-to-market (MTM) paradigm
Here , a credit loss occurs if:
– the borrower defaults
– the borrower's credit quality deteriorates (credit migration)
The mark-to-market paradigm is therefore a multi-state paradigm.
The mark-to-market paradigm recognizes that there can be an economic
impact even if the borrower does not default.
A true mark-to-market approach would take market-implied values in
different non-defaulting states.
However, because of data and liquidity issues some banks use internal
prices based on loss experiences.
14
Mark-to-market paradigm approaches
There are two well-known approaches in the mark-to-market
paradigm :
– the discounted contractual cash flow approach
– the risk-neutral valuation approach
15
Discounted Contractual Cashflow Approach
In the discounted contractual cash flow approach, the current value of a non-
defaulted loan is measured as the present value of its future cash flows.
The cash flows are discounted using credit spreads which are equal to market-
determined spreads for obligations of the same grade.
If external market rates cannot be applied, spreads implied by internal default
history can be used.
The future value of a non-defaulted loan is dependent on the risk rating at the end
of the time horizon and the credit spreads for that rating.
Therefore, changes in the value of the loan are the result of credit migration or
changes in market credit spreads.
In the event of a default, the future value is determined by the recovery rate, as in
the default mode paradigm.
16
Risk-Neutral Valuation Approach
This approach is derived from derivatives pricing theory.
Prices are an expectation of the discounted future cash flows in a risk-neutral market.
These default probabilities are therefore called risk-neutral default probabilities and are derived
from the asset values in a risk-neutral option pricing approach.
Each cash flow in the risk-neutral approach depends on there being no default.
For example, if a payment is contractually due on a certain date, the lender receives the payment
only if the borrower has not defaulted by this date.
If the borrower defaults before this date, the lender receives nothing.
If the borrower defaults on this date, the value of the payment to the lender is determined by the
recovery rate (1 - LGD rate).
The value of a loan is equal to the sum of the present values of these cash flows.
17
Structural and Reduced Form Models
18
Structural Models
Probability of default is determined by the difference between the
current value of the firm's assets and liabilities, and also by the
volatility of the assets.
Structural models are based on variables that can be observed over
time in the market.
Asset values are inferred from equity prices.
Structural models are difficult to use if capital structure is
complicated and asset prices are not easily observable.
19
Reduced Form Models
Reduced form models do not attempt to explain default events.
Instead, they concentrate directly on default probability.
Default events are assumed to occur unexpectedly due to one or more
exogenous events (observable and unobservable ), independent of the
borrower's asset value.
Observable risk factors include changes in macroeconomic factors such
as GDP, interest rates ,exchange rates ,inflation.
Unobservable risk factors can be specific to a firm, industry or country.
Correlations among PDs for different borrowers are considered to arise
from the dependence of different borrowers on the behavior of the
underlying background factors.
20
Reduced Form Models
Default in the reduced form approach is assumed to follow a Poisson distribution.
A Poisson distribution describes the number of events of some phenomenon (in this
case, defaults) taking place during a specific period of time.
It is characterized by a rate parameter (t), which is the expected number of arrivals
that occur per unit of time.
In a Poisson process, arrivals occur one at a time rather than simultaneously.
And any event occurring after time t is independent of an event occurring before time
t.
It is therefore relevant for credit risk modeling –
– There is a large number of obligors.
– The probability of default by any one obligor is relatively small.
– It is assumed that the number of defaults in one period is independent of the number of defaults in the
following period.
21
Credit Risk Models
Merton
Moody's KMV
Credit Metrics
Credit Risk+
24
Merton and KMV models
25
The Merton Model
This model assumes that the firm has made one single issue of zero
coupon debt and equity.
Let V be value of the firm’s assets, D value of debt.
When debt matures, debt holders will receive the full value of their
debt, D provided V > D.
If V < D, debt holders will receive only a part of the sums due and
equity holders will receive nothing.
Value received by debt holders at time T = D – max {D-VT, 0}
26
The payoff has two components
Examine : D – max {D-VT, 0}
D is the pay off from investing in a default risk free instrument.
On the other hand, - max {D-VT, 0} is the pay off from a short
position in a put option on the firm’s assets with a strike price of D
and a maturity date of T
Thus risky debt ☰ long default risk free bond + short put option
with strike price D
27
Value of the put
Value of the put completely determines the price differential
between risky and riskless debt.
A higher value of the put increases the price difference between
risky and riskless bonds.
As volatility of firm value increases, the spread on the risky debt
increases and the value of the put increases.
28
Value of equity
Let E be the value of the firm’s equity.
Let E be the volatility of the firm’s equity.
Claim of equity = VT – D if VT ≥ D
= 0 otherwise
The pay off is the same as that of a long call with strike price D.
29
Valuing the put option
Assume the firm value follows a lognormal distribution with
constant volatility, .
Let the risk free rate, r be also constant .
The value of the put, P at time, t is given by:
P = e-r(T-t) D N (-d + T-t) – V t N(-d)
d = [1/ T-t] [ln (V t /D) + (r+ ½ 2 (T-t)]
30
Problem
The current value of the firm is $60 million and the value of the
zero coupon bond to be redeemed in 3 years is $50 million. The
annual interest rate is 5% while the volatility of the firm value is
10%. Using the Merton Model, calculate the value of the firm’s
equity.
32
Solution
Formula is: St = V x N(d) – Fe-r(T-t) x N (d-T-t)
d = [1/ T-t] [ln (V t /D) + (r+ ½ 2) (T-t)]
V = value of firm
F = face value of zero coupon debt
= firm value volatility
r = interest rate
33
Solution
S = 60 x N (d) – (50)e-(.05)(3) x N (d-(.1)3)
d = [.1823 +( .05+.01/2)(3)]/.17321
= .3473/ .17321 = 2.005
S = 60 N (2.005) – (50) (.8607) N (2.005 - .17321)
= 60 N (2.005) – (43.035) N (1.8318)
= (60) (.9775) – (43.035) (.9665)
= $17.057 million
34
Problem
In the earlier problem, calculate the value of the firm’s
debt.
35
Solution
Dt = Fe-r(T-t) – pt
= 50e-.05(3) – pt
= 43.035 – pt
Based on put call parity
pt = Ct + Fe-r(T-t) – V
Or pt = 17.057 + 43.035 – 60 = .092
Dt = 43.035 - .092 = $42.943 million
Alternatively, value of debt
= Firm value – Equity value = 60 – 17.057
= $42.943 million
36
Complex capital structures
In real life, capital structures may be more complex.
There may be multiple debt issues differing in
– maturity,
– size of coupons
– seniority.
Equity then becomes a compound option on firm value.
Each promised debt payment gives the equity holders the right to
proceed to the next payment.
If the payment is not made, the firm is in default.
After last but one payment is made, Merton model applies.
37
KMV Model
Default tends to occur when the market value of the firm’s assets
drops below a critical point that typically lies
– Below the book value of all liabilities
– But above the book value of short term liabilities
The model identifies the default point d used in the computations.
38
KMV Model
The KMV model assumes that there are only two debt issues.
The first matures before the chosen horizon and the other matures
after that horizon.
The distance to default can be calculated as:
lnV0 l nD (r v2 / 2)T
v T
39
KMV Model
The distance to default is a proxy measure for the probability of
default.
As the distance to default decreases, the company becomes more
likely to default.
As the distance to default increases, the company becomes less
likely to default.
The KMV model, unlike the Merton Model does not use a normal
distribution.
Instead, it assumes a proprietary algorithm based on historical
default rates.
40
KMV Model
Using the KMV model involves the following steps:
– Identification of the default point, D.
– Identification of the firm value V and volatility
– Identification of the number of standard deviation moves that
would result in firm value falling below D.
– Use KMV database to identify proportion of firms with distance-
to-default, δ who actually defaulted in a year.
– This is the expected default frequency.
– KMV takes D as the sum of the face value of the all short term
liabilities (maturity < 1 year) and 50% of the face value of longer
term liabilities.
41
Problem
Consider the following figures for a company. What is the
probability of default?
– Book value of all liabilities : $2.4 billion
– Estimated default point, D : $1.9 billion
– Market value of equity : $11.3 billion
– Market value of firm : $13.8 billion
– Volatility of firm value : 20%
42
Solution
Distance to default (in terms of value) = 13.8 – 1.9
= $11.9 billion
Standard deviation = (.20) (13.8)
= $2.76 billion
Distance to default (in terms of standard deviation)
= 4.31
We now refer to the default database.
If 5 out of 100 firms with distance to default = 4.31 actually defaulted,
probability of default = .05
43
Problem
Given the following figures, compute the distance to default:
– Book value of liabilities : $5.95 billion
– Estimated default point : $4.15 billion
– Market value of equity : $ 12.4 billion
– Market value of firm: $18.4 billion
– Volatility of firm value : 24%
44
Solution
Distance to default (in terms of value) = 18.4 – 4.15 = $14.25 billion
Standard deviation = (.24) (18.4) = $4.416 billion
Distance to default (in terms of standard deviation) = 3.23
45