LIPSEY - CHRYSTAL - FIGTEXT10Visit Us at Management - Umakant.info
LIPSEY - CHRYSTAL - FIGTEXT10Visit Us at Management - Umakant.info
LIPSEY - CHRYSTAL - FIGTEXT10Visit Us at Management - Umakant.info
FIGURE TEXT
Table 10.1: Total average and marginal
revenue
The demand curves D’ and D’’ both have marginal revenue curves
that intersect the marginal cost curve at output q0.
But because the demand curves are different, q0 is sold at:
p0 when the demand curve is D’
and at p1 when the demand curve is D’’.
Thus under monopoly there is no unique relation between price and
the quantity sold.
Figure 10.6: The deadweight loss of
monopoly
When the market is monopolized and price rises to pm, the surplus
area 2 is lost because the output is not produced.
However the monopolist gains area 6 from consumers.
Area 6 is known to be greater than 2 because pm maximizes the
monopolist profits.
Thus although the monopolist gains, society losses areas 1 and 2.
Areas 1 and 2 are the deadweight loss resulting from monopoly and
account for its allocative inefficiency.
Figure 10.7: A price-discriminating
monopolist
Initially the monopolist produces output qm which it sell at pm where MC = MR
instead of the competitive output qc where MC equals demand (which is
consumers’ marginal utility).
The deadweight loss is the sum of the three areas labelled 1, 2, and 3.
A second group of consumers is then isolated from the first (the first group
continue to buy qm at pm).
This new group who would buy nothing at the original price of pm, will buy an
amount that would increase total output to qd at a price of pd.
The monopoly firm’s profits now rise by the area 2, which is the difference
between its cost curve and the price pd that is charged to the new group who
buy the amount between qm and qd.
Consumers’ surplus rises by the area labelled 1 and total deadweight loss
falls to the area labelled 3.
Figure 10.8: Conflicting forces affecting
cartels (i) the market