Consumer Preferences and The Concept of Utility
Consumer Preferences and The Concept of Utility
Chapter Three
Motivation
Why study consumer choice? Study of how consumers with limited resources choose goods and services Helps derive the demand curve for any good or service Businesses care about consumer demand curves Government can use this to determine how to help and whom to help buy certain goods and services
Chapter Three 3
Consumer Preferences
Consumer Preferences tell us how the consumer would rank (that is, compare the desirability of) any two combinations or allotments of goods, assuming these allotments were available to the consumer at no cost.
These allotments of goods are referred to as baskets or bundles. These baskets are assumed to be available for consumption at a particular time, place and under particular physical circumstances.
Chapter Three
Consumer Preferences
Preferences are complete if the consumer can rank any two baskets of goods (A preferred to B; B preferred to A; or indifferent between A and B) Preferences are transitive if a consumer who prefers basket A to basket B, and basket B to basket C also prefers basket A to basket C
A B; B C == > A C
Chapter Three 5
Consumer Preferences
Preferences are monotonic if a basket with more of at least one good and no less of any good is preferred to the original basket.
Chapter Three
Types of Ranking
Students take an exam. After the exam, the students are ranked according to their performance. An ordinal ranking lists the students in order of their performance (i.e., Harry did best, Joe did second best, Betty did third best, and so on). A cardinal ranking gives the mark of the exam, based on an absolute marking standard (i.e., Harry got 80, Joe got 75, Betty got 74 and so on). Alternatively, if the exam were graded on a curve, the marks would be an ordinal ranking.
Chapter Three
a function that measures the level of satisfaction a consumer receives from any basket of goods and services.
assigns a number to each basket so that more preferred baskets get a higher number than less preferred baskets. U = u(y)
Chapter Three 8
Chapter Three
Marginal Utility
Marginal Utility of a good y additional utility that the consumer gets from consuming a little more of y i.e. the rate at which total utility changes as the level of consumption of good y rises
MUy = U/y
slope of the utility function with respect to y
Chapter Three 10
Chapter Three
11
Chapter Three
12
Marginal Utility
The marginal utility of a good, x, is the additional utility that the consumer gets from consuming a little more of x when the consumption of all the other goods in the consumers basket remain constant. U(x, y) = x + y U/x (y held constant) = MUx U/y (x held constant) = MUy
Chapter Three
13
Marginal Utility
Example of U(H) and MUH
MUH 6 2 -2 -6 -10
14
Marginal Utility
U(H) = 10H H2
MUH = 10 2H
15
Chapter Three
Marginal Utility
Example of U(H) and MUH
The point at which he should stop consuming hotdogs is the point at which MUH = 0 This gives H = 5. That is the point where Total Utility is flat. You can see that the utility is diminishing.
Chapter Three 16
Indifference Curves
An Indifference Curve or Indifference Set: is the set of all baskets for which the consumer is indifferent
Chapter Three
18
Indifference Curves
1) Monotonicity => indifference curves have negative slope and indifference curves are not thick
2)
Indifference Curves
Chapter Three
20
Indifference Curves
Suppose that B preferred to A. but..by definition of IC, B indifferent to C A indifferent to C => B indifferent to C by transitivity. And thus a contradiction.
Chapter Three
21
Indifference Curves
U = xy2
Check that underlying preferences are complete, transitive, and monotonic.
MU x y
for U 144
x 8 4 3 1
MU y 2 xy
Chapter Three
Indifference Curves
Indifference Curve for U =
14 12 10 8 y 6 4 2 0 0 1 2 3 4 X 5 6 7 8 9
xy2
Chapter Three
23
If the more of good x you have, the more you are willing to give up to get a little of good y or the indifference curves get flatter as we move out along the horizontal axis and steeper as we move up along the vertical axis
Chapter Three
25
Positive marginal utility implies the indifference curve has a negative slope (implies monotonicity)
Diminishing marginal utility implies the indifference curves are convex to the origin (implies averages preferred to extremes)
26
Chapter Three
Implications of this substitution: Indifference curves are negatively-sloped, bowed out from the origin, preference direction is up and right Indifference curves do not intersect the axes
Chapter Three
27
Indifference Curves
Averages preferred to extremes => indifference curves are bowed toward the origin (convex to the origin).
Chapter Three
28
Indifference Curves
Do the indifference intersect the axes? curves
Chapter Three
29
Example: U = Ax2+By2; MUx=2Ax; MUy=2By (where: A and B positive) MRSx,y = MUx/MUy = 2Ax/2By = Ax/By
Marginal utilities are positive (for positive x and y) Marginal utility of x increases in x;
Marginal utility of y increases in y
Chapter Three 30
Indifference Curves
Example: U= (xy).5;MUx=y.5/2x.5; MUy=x.5/2y.5
A. Is more better for both goods? Yes, since marginal utilities are positive for both. B. Are the marginal utility for x and y diminishing? Yes. (For example, as x increases, for y constant, MUx falls.) C. What is the marginal rate of substitution of x for y? MRSx,y = MUx/MUy = y/x
Chapter Three 31
Indifference Curves
y
Example: Graphing Indifference Curves
Preference direction
IC2
IC1
x
Chapter Three 32
MUX = Ax-1y
y-1 Ax MUY =
MRSx,y =
(y)/(x)
Standard case
Chapter Three 33
Preference Direction
IC2
IC1
x
Chapter Three 34
MRSx,y = A/B so that 1 unit of x is equal to B/A units of y everywhere (constant MRS).
35
Chapter Three
Slope = -A/B
IC1
IC2
Chapter Three
IC3 x
36
Chapter Three
37
IC2 IC1
0
Chapter Three
x
38
Chapter Three
0
Chapter Three
x
40