Access Deficit Core Submission
Access Deficit Core Submission
Interconnection Pricing
A Submission to the Australian Competition and Consumer
Commission
From an economic perspective, the construction of an access deficit is rather odd. The
CAN is used as an input for a wide variety of telecommunications services including
local and long distance calls, calls to mobiles, and internet access. Economically, there is
no reason to presume that an input that is used to provide a variety of different services
must have its cost recovered from a particular charge. Rather, if one input is used to
facilitate a large variety of retail products then any evaluation of any ‘deficit’ or ‘surplus’
associated with that input needs to be made by considering the entire operations of the
relevant firm. But the access deficit is calculated only with regards to customer access
charges, ignoring any economic profits that might accrue to Telstra from other
telecommunications products. As such, it is not clear that the access deficit has any
economic meaning.
There appear to be two potential arguments are made in favour of an access deficit
contribution (ADC). First, it is sometimes argued that the lack of an ADC will not
allow Telstra to earn a reasonable market rate-of-return on assets. Second, it is
sometimes argued that without an ADC, inefficient entry might occur. That is, entrants
may seek opportunities to make profits where Telstra is constrained to meet their price.
We evaluate each of these arguments. With regard to investment incentives, the nature
and operation of the universal service obligation fund in Australia essentially under-
writes any losses that may result from non-recovery of the ADC and effectively
guarantees Telstra a market rate of return on PSTN assets. The inefficient entry or
‘cream skimming’ argument neglects the fact that most PSTN dependent service
markets (such as long distance and fixed-to-mobile calls) involve competitive provision
and, consequently, entry will be efficient regardless of whether there is an ADC in the
access price or not. This is because in these markets there are no actual or implicit
constraints on Telstra’s ability to meet an entrant’s price. For these reasons, we do not
believe there is sound economic basis for the inclusion of the ADC in access
arrangements for the PSTN.
Finally, even if there was an economic argument for Telstra to receive an ADC,
building this ADC into access prices on the basis of calls or call minutes is an
inefficient means of recovering the costs of the CAN from access seekers. This is
because such pricing will discourage entry and soften price competition in
telecommunications markets. A better approach would be to recover the ADC in a
manner consistent with that of the USO.
Contents Page
1. Background ............................................................................. 3
6.4 An Alternative................................................................... 17
Appendix A ....................................................................................... 21
A.1 The Universal Service Obligation Scheme .................... 21
July, 2001 i
Contents Page
July, 2001 ii
Section 1 Background
1. Background
3
Section 2 What is the ‘Access Deficit’?
In its 1999 and 2000 Undertaking Reports, the ACCC recognised the
access deficit as a reasonable item that Telstra be allowed to recover
as a cost item in PSTN origination and termination. The ‘access
deficit’ was defined as the shortfall between the cost of providing
basic access and the revenues that Telstra is able to secure under the
price control regulations. Telstra’s basic access service is associated
with a customer being able to make and receive calls over the
customer access network (CAN).
4
Section 3 Related Telecommunications Policies
3. Related Telecommunications
Policies
The existence and nature of retail price control policies and USO
funding impact upon the size and rationale for an access deficit.
Appendix A provides a detailed description of these schemes and
considers how they impact upon the logic for an access deficit
contribution.
1
See Section 9 of the Telecommunications (Consumer Protection and Service Standards) Act
1999
2 See further at http://www.aca.gov.au/consumer/ uso/funding/funding.htm
5
Section 4 The Access Deficit as an Economic Construct
The approach to the access deficit adopted by the ACCC treats basic
access as a stand-alone product. It treats basic access as an isolated
product and asks whether the direct revenues from that product
cover its costs. If the stand-alone product revenues do not exceed the
cost then there is a deficit. However, this calculation has no meaning
from an economic perspective. It is irrelevant whether there is a
surplus or a deficit in terms of direct contributions for one input that
is used in combination with other inputs to produce final services.
To see this, suppose that two inputs x and y are combined with each
other to form a final product z. One unit of final product z requires a
consumer to purchase exactly one unit of x and then to purchase one
unit of y. The consumer then puts these two components together to
form a unit of z. Further, the consumer can only form a working unit
of z if they purchase the unit of y from the same manufacturer as the
unit of x. For example, x might represent a razor-handle, y might
represent a blade, and z might represent a finished razor. The
consumer must purchase the razor handle and then purchase the
blade that ‘fits’ that handle. The manufacturer might help facilitate
this dual purchase by bundling the blade with the razor handle.
Assume that consumers only desire the final product z. Having a unit
of x by itself provides no benefit to a consumer. Similarly, having a
unit of y by itself provides no benefit to a consumer. Also assume that
consumers only care what they pay in total for the final product z.
Suppose that it costs $1 to produce a unit of x and $1 to produce a
unit of y. If z is sold at a competitive price then it will sell for $2. But
the seller might ‘break down’ the $2 price of a unit of z in numerous
ways. For example, the seller might sell product x for $1.40 and
product y for $0.60. From the consumers’ perspective they pay $2 for
the final product z. However, if the seller did this, then there would
6
Section 4 The Access Deficit as an Economic Construct
be a ‘product y deficit’ of $0.40 per unit – the ‘revenues’ for y are only
$0.60 per unit while the cost is $1 per unit. Alternatively, the seller
could hold the price of z fixed at $2 but set a price of x of $1.20 and a
price of y of $0.80. If the seller did this, then the ‘product y deficit’
would be $0.20 per unit. In fact, by altering the way they break-down
the $2 price of the final product, the seller could create a ‘product y
deficit’ anywhere between $1 per unit and -$1 per unit. However,
none of these deficit figures would have any economic meaning. They
would not alter consumers’ final product demand, the total sales of
the final product or the profits that are generated in total from the
final product.
7
Section 4 The Access Deficit as an Economic Construct
companies that set low phone prices and these companies will be
more profitable.
A further problem with the access deficit calculation arises due to its
relationship with the Telstra price caps. If these price caps do not
bind then the access deficit is calculated using the maximum access
revenues that Telstra could have received under the price caps rather
than the revenues Telstra actually did receive. While this reduces the
access deficit, it also highlights that the deficit is an arbitrary construct
with little if any economic meaning. If a firm subject to a price cap
sets profit maximising prices that fall under the price cap, then that
price cap is not a binding constraint on the firm. Under standard
economic assumptions that the firm has a well-behaved profit
function and seeks to maximise profits, a non-binding price cap is
redundant. The price cap could be doubled, tripled, or removed
altogether without altering the behaviour of the firm. In this situation,
market conditions other than the price cap are constraining the firm’s
behaviour so that it is not profit maximising for the firm to price ‘up
to’ the cap. In this situation, to define an ‘access deficit’ on the basis
of a non-binding price cap has no economic meaning. The deficit
could be eliminated by simply raising the (non-binding) price cap. As
the cap is not binding, increasing the cap has no effect on any actual
market behaviour. But as the cap rises, the maximum ‘allowed’ line
rental would rise and the deficit would fall. The access deficit could
be arbitrarily raised or lowered by altering the non-binding price cap
without changing any actual behaviour.
8
Section 5 Should Telstra Receive an Access Deficit Contribution?
It has also been argued that failure to have an ADC will lead to an
under-pricing of access to Telstra’s PSTN and hence, excessive entry
in related downstream markets. Thus, there is an investment incentives
argument and a cream skimming argument. The investment incentives
argument states why Telstra should receive an access deficit
contribution. The cream skimming argument is used to justify why
the ADC should come from access seekers to the PSTN.
Unfortunately, there is little elaboration of these arguments in the
Australian debate. Each, when presented, is stated as a contention. In
what follows we evaluate investment incentives and cream skimming
arguments and identify the facts that would have to be established to
give them some validity.
9
Section 5 Should Telstra Receive an Access Deficit Contribution?
In this example, service A is the basic access service. Notice that the
firm makes a loss on this service alone. Service B is a less profitable
related service such as local calls while service C is more profitable.
These figures show the profits on each segment if the provider is a
monopolist. However, suppose that the firm is exposed to
competition. As services B and C are profitable, entry could occur in
those related services if access to service A was mandated. If such
competition was strong, the firm would be left with service A alone
and an overall loss.
3
This example comes from Mark Armstrong and Chris Doyle, “Social Obligations
and Access Pricing: Telecommunications and Railways in the U.K,” in Gabel,
David and Weiman, David F., eds. Opening networks to competition: The regulation and
pricing of access. Topics in Regulatory Economics and Policy Series, Boston; Dordrecht and
London: Kluwer Academic, 1998, pages 159-79.
10
Section 5 Should Telstra Receive an Access Deficit Contribution?
As such, the existence of the USO rules out the dire scenario of
Telstra being made bankrupt and indeed any real possibility of entry
causing serious losses for Telstra. Indeed, the USO fund guarantees
that if Telstra were to only be a provider of basic access, it would earn
a market return on that service.
The existence of the USO fund means that Telstra’s fixed costs
associated with providing access will always be covered. What,
however, does this mean for its incentives to invest in the CAN?
Recall, that it has been argued that Telstra would have little if any
incentive to invest in the CAN if it did not receive an access deficit
contribution. However, Telstra’s universal service obligations require
such investments and compensate Telstra for them through the USO
fund. Indeed, as that fund is cost-based, if anything it may provide
too much rather than too little incentive to maintain and expand the
CAN. This is because Telstra is effectively reimbursed for such
expenses; subject, of course, to its use of best available technologies.
Consequently, the existence of the USO fund and the basis upon
which it is said to operate mean that the investment incentives
argument is unlikely to provide an appropriate justification for an
access deficit contribution. For this to be established would require
11
Section 5 Should Telstra Receive an Access Deficit Contribution?
proof that the USO fund was not performing its stated functions and
that this was leading to competitive forces that are not allowing
Telstra to cover its fixed costs (including any access deficit).
To see this argument, suppose that in, say, long distance markets,
Telstra has a cost of C per subscriber and generates gross value of U
per subscriber. Suppose also that the price of Telstra’s services is P
per subscriber. In this situation, Telstra’s customers receive U – P.5
5
This example is based on one from Mark Armstrong, “The Theory of Access
Pricing and Interconnection,” M. Cave, S. Majumdar and I. Volgelsang (eds.),
Handbook of Telecommunications Economics, Amsterdam: North-Holland, 2002.
12
Section 5 Should Telstra Receive an Access Deficit Contribution?
This raises a critical question: why does the provider’s long distance
price differ from marginal cost? The above argument is predicated on
the assumption that long distance prices are regulated and fixed. In
other words, it assumes that Telstra cannot lower its price below P in
the presence of competition. However, in Australia, long distance
prices are deregulated and indeed, subject to considerable
competition. In this situation, the argument that there is a long
distance distortion that needs to be ‘cured’ by the use of an ADC
does not hold.
To see this, suppose that Telstra has a retail price for long distance
above a + c (where a is a given ADC). In this case, Telstra will receive
a contribution of a per unit from providing access. If, however,
Telstra lowers its price in response to entry, it will be able to charge
up to P = a + c + [U – u]. In this case, it will earn a profit of a + c +
[U – u] – C. This will not be profitable for the incumbent if a ≥ a + c
– C + [U – u] or C ≥ c + [U – u]. Hence, regardless of the choice of
ADC, a, entry will be socially efficient. As such, no ADC is required
to generate efficient entry conditions.
6
This argument basically states that the access price should be driven by an ECPR
logic.
13
Section 5 Should Telstra Receive an Access Deficit Contribution?
5.3 Conclusion
7
Armstrong, op.cit.
14
Section 5 Should Telstra Receive an Access Deficit Contribution?
15
Section 6 Methods of Recovering any “Access Deficit”
8 “Price Elasticities for Local Telephone Calls,” Econometrica, 51 (5), 1983, pp.1699-
1730.
16
Section 6 Methods of Recovering any “Access Deficit”
The ACCC has also considered allocating the ADC on the basis of
call ends and call minutes. In its initial undertaking reports, the ACCC
was concerned that by using call ends this would result “in a greater
amount of the access deficit being allocated to the declared PSTN
services than when call minutes [are] used to allocate the access
deficit.” (ACCC, July 2000, p.25) This is because average call times
were lower on declared services as opposed to the PSTN in general.
It appears that because of a lack of information upon which to
evaluate this distribution the ACCC chose a 50 percent weighting of
call ends to call minutes (July, 2000, p.38).
Both the Telstra and ACCC methods of allocating the access deficit
among access seekers and the provider are based on call volumes
(although weights on ends and minutes vary). The difficulty with this
approach is that when pricing its services, the marginal cost of an
additional call and call minute are increased above Telstra’s costs of
supplying PSTN services.
This has two effects. First, access seekers face a different marginal
cost than does Telstra. This is because the access deficit, as we argued
earlier, is a fixed cost of operating a PSTN network for Telstra.
Hence, it does not factor into their pricing as it would into the pricing
of entrants. As such, entrant’s prices are likely to be too high.
6.4 An Alternative
17
Section 6 Methods of Recovering any “Access Deficit”
9
This is the recommendation of the Centre for Research in Network Economics
and Communications at the University of Auckland in their paper “Estimating the
Cost of the KSO,” 1st June 2001 and also of the Productivity Commission in their
draft report.
18
Section 6 Conclusion: Answers to the ACCC’s Questions
19
Section 6 Conclusion: Answers to the ACCC’s Questions
The answer is that it should not be spread over calls or minutes. Both
are distortionary and likely lead to consumer harm. Instead, a fixed
charge similar to the USO obligations should be imposed on
downstream telecommunications providers.
20
Section 0 Appendix A
Appendix A
10
For further details see Productivity Commission, Telecommunications Competition
Regulation, Final Report, December 2001 at Chapter 18
11
See further at http://www.aca.gov.au/consumer/uso/index.htm
21
Section 0 Appendix A
The formula for calculating the overall size of the NUSC is the
amount by which the costs attributable to the provision services to
net cost areas (avoidable costs) exceed the revenues earned from the
provision of the services (revenues foregone). This formula was originally
contained in the relevant USO legislation. A model for calculating the
NUSC in accordance with the legislation was developed by Bellcore
International in 1996.15 The TCPSS Act (the current USO legislation)
was amended under the Telecommunications (Consumer Protection and
Service Standards) Amendment Act (No. 2) 2000 (commencing July 2000).
Under the amendments the avoidable costs minus revenues foregone
formula has been removed from the Act and no alternative
methodology is prescribed. The ACA Advice to the Minister on New
USO arrangements (prepared prior to passage of the legislation) notes
that:
22
Section 0 Appendix A
16
Australian Communications Authority, Advice to the Minister New USO
Arrangements, September 2000 at p. 6
17
Australian Communications Authority (July 2000), op. cit., at p. 7
18 Australian Communications Authority (October 2002), op. cit., at p. 71.
19
Australian Communications Authority, Estimate of Net Universal Service Costs for
1998/99 and 1999/2000, January 2000
23
Section 0 Appendix A
Methodology
Small exchange areas are costed at the full exchange level. NBUAs
and BUAs are costed separately but on a regional basis. Customers
receiving radio or satellite services and payphone services are costed
individually.
20
Bellcore International, Net Loss Area Specifications, Net Universal Service Cost
Consultancy Agreement Phase 2, Deliverable #1, November 1996 at p. 1
21
Bellcore International (1996), op. cit.,, at p. 1
22
Bellcore International (1996), op. cit., at p. 3
23
Australian Communications Authority (January 2000), op. cit.
24
Section 0 Appendix A
24
Bellcore International (1996), op. cit
25
Australian Communications Authority (January 2000), op. cit
26
Australian Communications Authority (January 2000), op. cit.
27
This determination only applied to the 1997/98 but the same methodology has
been used for future NUSC assessments.
28
Australian Communications Authority (May 1999), op. cit.
29
Ibid.
25
Section 0 Appendix A
Technology Costs
30
Australian Communications Authority, Net Universal Service Cost Assessment for
1997-98, October 1999
31
Australian Communications Authority (October 1999), op. cit., at p. 52
32
ibid., p. 67
33
ibid.
34 ibid., p.12.
26
Section 0 Appendix A
Depreciation Rates
Operating Expenses
35 ibid., p.14.
36 ibid., p.14.
37
ibid., p.14.
38
ibid., p.92.
39 ibid., p.92.
40
ibid., p.5.
41
ibid., p.101.
27
Section 0 Appendix A
The least-cost technology is the one with the lowest annual costs after
taking into account capital costs (WACC and depreciation) and
operating costs. This approach is favoured to an approach whereby
42
ibid., p.101.
43
ibid., p.46.
44
ibid., p.46.
45
ibid., p.46. The levelisation formula can be found at page 49.
46
Australian Communications Authority (May 1999), op. cit.
28
Section 0 Appendix A
the least-cost technology is that with the least cost in year one or with
the lowest NPV. 47
47
Australian Communications Authority (October 1999), op. cit., pp. 105-106
48
ibid.
49 Australian Communications Authority, Estimate of Net Universal Service Costs for
29
Section 0 Appendix A
50
Australian Communications Authority (September 2000), op. cit., at p. 52
51 Australian Communications Authority (October 2002), op. cit., at p. 71.
52
Department for Communications, Information Technology and the Arts,
Explanatory Statement to the Telecommunications Universal Service Obligation (Eligible
Revenues) Regulations 1998, 1998
30
Section 0 Appendix A
Participating Carriers
Eligible Revenues
31
Section 0 Appendix A
56
Australian Competition and Consumer Commission, Review of Price Control
Arrangements, Final Report, February 2001., at p. 6. The history of regulation of
Telstra’s retail prices can be found at page 7.
57 Sub-clase 9(a)
58
Sub-clause 9(b)
59
Sub-clause 9(c)
60
Sub-clause 13(1)
61
Sub-clause 13(2)
62
Sub-clauses 13(4) to 13(7)
32
Section 0 Appendix A
63
Clause 19
64
ACCC (February 2001), op. cit., at p. vii
65
ACCC (February 2001), op. cit., at p. 32
66
ACCC (February 2001), op. cit., at p. ix
67
ACCC (February 2001), op. cit., at p. 36
68
ACCC (February 2001), op. cit., at pp. 37-39
33