Temi Di Discussione

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 34

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.

com/abstract=2057864
Temi di Discussione
(Working Papers)
Measuring the underground economy with the currency demand
approach: a reinterpretation of the methodology,
with an application to Italy
by Guerino Ardizzi, Carmelo Petraglia,
Massimiliano Piacenza and Gilberto Turati
N
u
m
b
e
r
864
A
p
r
i
l

2
0
1
2
Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2057864
Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2057864
Temi di discussione
(Working papers)
Measuring the underground economy with the currency demand
approach: a reinterpretation of the methodology,
with an application to Italy
by Guerino Ardizzi, Carmelo Petraglia,
Massimiliano Piacenza and Gilberto Turati
Number 864 - April 2012
The purpose of the Temi di discussione series is to promote the circulation of working
papers prepared within the Bank of Italy or presented in Bank seminars by outside
economists with the aim of stimulating comments and suggestions.
The views expressed in the articles are those of the authors and do not involve the
responsibility of the Bank.
Editorial Board: Silvia Magri, Massimo Sbracia, Luisa Carpinelli, Emanuela Ciapanna,
Francesco DAmuri, Alessandro Notarpietro, Pietro Rizza, Concetta Rondinelli,
Tiziano Ropele, Andrea Silvestrini, Giordano Zevi.
Editorial Assistants: Roberto Marano, Nicoletta Olivanti.
MEASURING THE UNDERGROUND ECONOMY WITH THE CURRENCY
DEMAND APPROACH: A REINTERPRETATION OF THE METHODOLOGY,
WITH AN APPLICATION TO ITALY
by Guerino Ardizzi*, Carmelo Petraglia**, Massimiliano Piacenza*** and Gilberto Turati***

Abstract
We contribute to the debate on how to assess the size of the underground or shadow
economy with a reinterpretation of the traditional Currency Demand Approach (CDA) la
Tanzi. We introduce three main innovations. First, we take as dependent variable in the
money demand equation a direct measure of the value of cash transactions: the flow of cash
withdrawn from current accounts relative to total non-cash payments. This avoids use of the
Fisher equation and so overcomes two severe criticisms of the traditional CDA. Second,
instead of the tax burden, usually taken as the main motive for non-compliance, we include
among the covariates two direct indicators of detected tax evasion. Finally, we also control
for the role of illegal economic activity, such as drug dealing and prostitution, which
jointly with the shadow economy contributes to the larger aggregate of the unobserved
economy and represents a significant component of total cash payments. We then propose an
application of this modified CDA to a panel of 91 Italian provinces for the years 2005-
2008.


JEL Classification: E26, E41, H26, K42, O17.
Keywords: underground economy, Currency Demand Approach, cash transactions, tax evasion,
illegal production.

Contents
1. Introduction.......................................................................................................................... 5
2. Reinterpreting the Currency Demand Approach ................................................................. 7
3. An application of the "modified CDA" ............................................................................... 9
3.1 Defining the demand for cash payments ...................................................................... 9
3.2 Defining the determinants of cash payments.............................................................. 13
3.3 Estimating the demand for cash payments ................................................................. 16
3.4 Assessing the unobserved economy ........................................................................... 19
4. Conclusions........................................................................................................................ 21
References .............................................................................................................................. 22
Appendix. The data ................................................................................................................ 25



_______________________________________
* Bank of Italy, Market and Payment System Oversight Department.
** University of Basilicata, Di.T.Ec.
*** University of Torino, Department of Economics and Statistics.

5
1. Introduction
1

The Currency Demand Approach (CDA) is the most widely used of the so-called indirect
macroeconomic approaches to estimating the underground or shadow economy. Originally
suggested by Cagan (1958), the CDA was subsequently refined and applied by Tanzi (1980,
1983) to the U.S. economy and has been commonly used in the literature (among the more
recent contributions, see Ferwerda et al., 2010). The CDA measures the size of the shadow
economy in two stages: 1) the econometric estimation of an aggregate money demand
equation, with a specific component related to cash transactions in the underground sector; 2)
the computation of the value of these shadow transactions via the quantity theory of money.
The key assumptions for the first-stage estimation are that shadow transactions are settled in
cash to avoid traceability, and that the main motive for underground economic activity is
avoiding a high tax burden. The CDA involves estimating the aggregate demand for cash,
including among the regressors both the standard explanatory variables of the preference for
liquidity (such as the interest rate on deposits) and specific variables identifying the
determinants of the shadow economy (such as the level of the tax burden). The demand for
cash associated with shadow transactions is then computed as the difference between the
estimated demand for cash in the full model and the demand obtained by setting to zero all
the determinants of the underground economy (i.e. the demand for cash motivated only by
regular transactions).
More precisely, in the Tanzi (1980, 1983) application of the CDA to the U.S. economy, the
dependent variable in the money demand equation is the ratio of cash to money supply. This
ratio is regressed on three variables identifying the determinants of money demand for
regular transactions (the share of national income consisting in wages paid in cash, the
interest rate on savings deposits, and per capita income), plus the average tax rate on
personal income, posited as the sole determinant of shadow transactions. Since a basic
assumption of the CDA is that a heavier tax burden prompts more tax evasion, increasing the

1
We wish to thank Fabio Bagliano, Domenico Depalo, Michael Pickhardt, Alessandro Santoro, Paolo
Sestito, Jordi Sard, Brigitte Unger, Roberta Zizza, and all seminar participants at the 52
nd
Annual Conference
of the Italian Economic Association (Roma Tre University, 2011), the 2011 Conference on Shadow Economy, Tax
Evasion and Money Laundering (Mnster University, Germany) and the Lunch Seminar held at the Bank of
Italy (Roma, 2011), for their helpful comments. The usual disclaimers apply.


6
demand for cash, the expected sign on the income tax rate is positive. First-stage estimation
of the money demand equation confirms this view. In the second stage, the estimate of the
ratio of the underground economy to GDP is obtained by exploiting the Fisher equation. In
particular, Tanzi defines a base year in which the contribution of the underground economy
to GDP is assumed to be zero, and computes the velocity of money as the ratio of the official
GDP to the stock of liquid assets. Assuming then that this velocity is the same for the regular
economy and the shadow sector, the size of the shadow economy is obtained by multiplying
V by the estimated excess demand for cash.
Schneider and Enste (2000, 2002) identify and discuss many substantial drawbacks of the
CDA, pointing to three main criticisms of its basic assumptions
2
: i) no underground economy
transactions in the base year; ii) equal velocity of money in the official and the irregular
economy; iii) no determinant of the shadow economy except the excessive tax burden. Our
aim here is to contribute to the debate on measuring the underground economy with a
proposed revision of the CDA that overcomes all three drawbacks. Our modified CDA
makes three main innovations: first, our dependent variable in the money demand equation is
a direct measure of cash transactions (the flow of cash withdrawn from current bank and
postal accounts relative to total non-cash payments), which obviates the need for the Fisher
equation; second, rather than the level of the tax burden, we include among the covariates
two direct measures of detected tax evasion, thus overcoming a serious problem of potential
misspecification of the model due to the inability to consider all the relevant determinants;
and third, we also control for the influence of illegal economic activity (such as drug dealing
and prostitution), which together with the shadow economy contributes to the larger
aggregate of the unobserved economy and represents a significant component of total cash
payments (OECD, 2002). We then propose an original application of this modified CDA to
Italy, where the underground economy is considerably larger than in many other Western
countries.
The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 discusses our innovations to
the CDA and shows how they overcome most of the drawbacks highlighted by Schneider and
Enste (2000, 2002). Section 3 applies our modified CDA to Italy, discussing model
specification and empirical results. Section 4 sets out some brief concluding remarks.

2
Ahumada et al. (2007) and Breusch (2005) point to critiques specifically related to econometric issues, partly
addressed by Pickhardt and Sard (2010) within the standard CDA approach.

7
2. Reinterpreting the Currency Demand Approach
We start from the criticisms advanced by Schneider and Enste (2000, 2002) of most of the
assumptions of the traditional CDA. We focus here on three debatable assumptions: (1) the
absence of any transactions in the underground economy in the base year, which is
unrealistic; (2) the equality in money velocity in the official and the irregular economy, which
places a hardly justifiable restriction on the estimation method; and (3) an excessive tax
burden as the sole determinant of the shadow economy, which is also quite restrictive, since
other factors such as market regulation (especially the regulation of labour markets), trust
in political institutions, and the citizens tax morale can substantially affect the decision to
engage in underground economic activity.
To address these criticisms, we make three innovations to the traditional CDA la Tanzi.
First, instead of using the stock of liquid assets as the dependent variable in the money
demand equation, we take a direct measure of cash transactions: the flow of cash withdrawn
from current (bank and postal) accounts with respect to total payments settled by
instruments other than cash. This is a substantial modification of the model, dispensing with
the need for the quantity theory of money and the Fisher equation. In this way, we overcome
the first weakness, i.e. the need for an arbitrary base year for calculating the velocity of
money, and the second, namely the assumption of equal velocity of money in the official
economy and the shadow sector. Notice that the cash withdrawal variable also helps to deal
with the problematic measurement of the stock of liquid assets in each country following the
introduction of the euro, which can severely limit the application of the traditional CDA.
Second, in order to reply to critique (3), direct measures of detected tax evasion are
included among the factors positively correlated with the amount of (irregular) transactions
settled in cash. In this way, we escape the need to identify a set of variables that can
adequately capture all the relevant determinants of the shadow economy, apart from the tax
burden which is the crucial variable in the classic Tanzi approach and excludes any other
factors in noncompliance (e.g., Ferwerda et al., 2010; Schneider, 2010). We look directly at the
final outcome of this process so as to circumvent the problem of incomplete specification of
the model and investigate the relationship between the number of detected cases of tax
evasion and the use of cash in transactions.

8
Finally, with reference again to criticism (3) and the issue of model misspecification, we
argue that shadow economy is only one component of the total amount of cash payments.
Indeed, according to the OECD (2002) classification, the activities that contribute most to
the so-called unobserved (cash-settled) economy in developed countries include not only
underground but also illegal production: the former is defined as those activities that are
productive and legal but are deliberately concealed from the public authorities to avoid
payment of taxes or complying with regulations, while the latter mainly refers to the
production of goods and services whose production, sale or mere possession is forbidden by
law. Hence, in order to avoid potential distortions in the estimation of the underground
component of unobserved economy (as emphasized by Zizza, 2002), the CDA methodology we
propose also controls for the presence of illegal production. We consider, in particular, two
criminal activities drug dealing and prostitution that represent illegal transactions
typically settled in cash and that are universally considered as the most important activities
within the illegal economy.
3
Notice that the choices of the individuals operating in the two
sectors of the unobserved economy (underground and illegal) stem from different motivations
and incentive mechanisms, including the role of deterrence. The two components also differ
significantly in their effect on the public finances and their implications for law enforcement,
since one can identify potentially recoverable revenues (through tax audits) only for the
shadow economy, whereas in the case of illegal production the goal is to suppress the criminal
activity outright through police work and imprisonment. Despite these significant
differences, the literature rarely investigates the disaggregation of total unobserved economy
into underground and illegal production, mainly because delineating the boundaries of the
analysis is quite difficult and reliable information is lacking.
4
Here we exploit crime indicators
related to drug dealing and prostitution to make a more precise estimate of the excess demand

3
See the classification originally proposed by Lippert and Walker (1997), supplemented by Schneider and Enste
(2000, 2002) and Schneider (2010), and the discussion in OECD (2002), chapter 9.
4
For a comprehensive survey of the estimates of the unobserved economy in different countries with a
discussion of the contribution of the two components, see Thomas (1992). See also Rogoff (1998) for an
interesting analysis of the problem of large banknotes in circulation and the relationship between currency
velocity, tax levels and crime rates in OECD countries. A recent application that takes into account the role of
illegal production and relies on the traditional CDA is Ferwerda et al. (2010), which in order to reply to criticism
(3) raised by Schneider and Enste (2000, 2002) propose some changes to the Tanzi approach, by including in the
model several proxies alternative to the income tax rate for the determinants of the shadow economy. However,
the results are judged unsatisfactory, since none of the proxies significantly explains the underground economy
as measured by excess demand for cash. The authors conclude that other variables more closely related to the
decision to operate in the shadow sector still need to be found.

9
for cash transactions due to tax evasion, by isolating the illegal component of the unobserved
economy; this represents our third innovation with respect to the traditional CDA.
5
This will
also provide additional insights with respect to the official figures provided by the Italian
National Institute of Statistics (Istat) since unlike tax evasion illegal activities are not
included in the national accounts estimates.
3. An application of the modified CDA
3.1. Defining the demand for cash payments
In this section of the paper we provide a first application of the modified CDA to a
balanced panel of 91 Italian provinces observed from 2005 to 2008. We first need to discuss
the definition of the demand for cash payments, then its determinants. As to demand, we
depart from the standard CDA and exploit information on the flow of cash rather than the
stock of liquid assets. Hence, we base our assessment of the size of the shadow economy on a
direct measure of the value of transactions at provincial level. In particular, our dependent
variable in the estimated equation of the demand for cash payments (CASH) is the ratio of
the value of cash withdrawn from current accounts to the value of total payments settled by
instruments other than cash. This represents a measure of the demand for untraced payments
per euro of traceable payments (i.e., bank transfers, cheques, credit cards).
The transactions theory of money demand counts liquid assets as such (e.g., M1), not the
concept of payment. The latter necessarily implies a cash flow and precise technical and
organizational procedures by which the flow circulates. Even with reliable statistics, however,
stock indicators can be highly inaccurate for three reasons: a) quantifying the level of
national currency used outside national borders is problematic, and this is particularly true in
the euro area since the cash changeover in 2002; b) a certain amount of money can be held for
purposes other than transactions (traditional theories posit, for instance, the speculative
motive); and c) the velocity of money is assumed to be constant with respect to several GDP
components, including the informal sector, without taking into account such factors as trade
in intermediate goods and services. Hence, there may be compensatory phenomena within the
same stock of banknotes in circulation, both between different motives for holding cash

5
Ardizzi et al. (2011) survey studies on the assessment of underground economy in Italy using the CDA, which
include Bovi and Castellucci (2001), Zizza (2002), Schneider and Enste (2000, 2002), and Chiarini and Marzano
(2004).

10
reserves, and between the formal and the informal sector. This is confirmed by the recent
trend in currency-to-GDP ratios in the G10 and Eurosystem countries: the ratio has remained
stable or even risen since 2004 in the countries that should have been most affected by the
replacement of banknotes with digital money. Similar considerations hold for other stock-
based indicators of currency demand, such as M1 (currency and sight deposits). Notice that
while an increase in a stock-based monetary aggregate is a signal of greater liquidity
preference, it is not informative about the motives, which may include portfolio re balancing,
the adjustment of liquidity buffers, the need to hide transactions (either for tax evasion or
illegal activity). The European Central Bank has noted that, on the occasion of the cash
changeover, the stock of euro banknotes in circulation increased (even compared to M1 or
M2) more than the previous circulation of national currencies would have suggested (ECB,
2008). According to the ECB, this is reasonable, in particular, in an environment of low
interest rates and low inflation expectations, not to mention that an estimate of up to 20
percent of the banknotes outstanding are outside the euro area. As a consequence, it is
difficult if not impossible to estimate the component of cash held to settle payments within
the underground economy from data on stocks. This is why researchers need to select
monetary indicators more directly related to the transaction motive.
To clarify this issue, Figure 1 shows the divergence in recent trends of the currency-to-
GDP and the currency-to-M1 ratios as compared to their respective flows in Italy: stocks rise
while flows decline. The increasing trend of stocks is explained by the ECB clarification cited
above. The decreasing trend of flows is consistent with the spread of electronic payment
instruments in commercial transactions, which allow some substitution between alternative
instruments in the formal economy. Furthermore, the common trend of the two flow-based
indicators confirms the greater consistency of these indicators with the transaction motive for
cash demand. The combined evidence of such a substitution effect of cash flows and the
growing trend of the stock of banknotes suggests a slowdown in the overall velocity of
circulation of legal money for liquidity needs that are not purely transactional. All these
considerations lend force to the criticisms of the traditional CDA based on the quantity
theory of money.



11
Figure 1. Monetary aggregates in Italy: stocks vs. flows
.

Sources: Based on Bank of Italy and Istat data


The direct link between flow-based indicators of currency demand and the transaction
motive for holding cash is also underscored by micro-data on cash purchases collected by the
Bank of Italy in its Survey of Household Income and Wealth. Table 1 illustrates the
correlation matrix of two different (macro) currency ratios (based on cash withdrawals
divided by other payment transactions) and the percentage ratio of cash purchases to total
expenditures declared by the survey sample households in the period 2006-2008 (nearly the
same period considered in this study). The correlation coefficients are positive and significant
in all cases. As one would expect, the ATM cash withdrawals to POS card transactions
ratio shows a higher correlation with the Cash expenditure share by Italian households
than does the ratio of Total cash withdrawals value flows to total non-cash payments. In
other words, the closer the monetary indicator is to the point of sale, the stronger the

12
correlation with household cash expenditures.
6
Nevertheless, the broader indicator of cash use
Total cash withdrawals value flows to total non-cash payments better accounts for the
behaviour of all the economic agents (private firms and the public sector as well as
households), which makes it more appropriate for our purposes.

Table 1. Pearson, Spearman and Kendall tau-b correlation coefficients for different cash
usage indicators
a
Cash use indicator
Total cash withdrawals
value flows over total non-cash
payments
b

ATM cash withdrawals
over POS card transactions
c

Cash expenditure share
by Italian households
d


Pearson correlation
Total cash withdrawals
value flows over total non-cash
payments 1
ATM cash withdrawals over
POS card transactions 0.663 1
Cash expenditure share by
Italian households 0.717

0.848

1

Spearman correlation
Total cash withdrawals
value flows over total non-cash
payments 1
ATM cash withdrawals over
POS card transactions 0.695 1
Cash expenditure share by
Italian households 0.690

0.793

1

Kendall tau-b correlation
Total cash withdrawals
value flows over total non-cash
payments 1
ATM cash withdrawals over
POS card transactions 0.490 1
Cash expenditure share by
Italian households 0.490

0.590

1
a
Each correlation index is based on data for the 20 Italian regions. All correlation indexes are statistically significant at 1%.

b
Bank of Italy, banking statistics 2006-2008 (average annual value).
c
Bank of Italy, banking statistics 2009.
d
Bank of Italy, Survey on Household Income and Wealth, 2006-2008 (average annual value).




6
Exhaustive data on ATM cash withdrawals and POS transactions at regional level are available from 2009.
Nevertheless, the stability of payment behaviours over time makes the correlation analysis consistent even
where the data on cash expenditures cover a different period.

13
3.2. Defining the determinants of cash payments
In line with the discussion in Section 2, we classify the determinants of CASH into three
groups, identifying three components of the demand for cash payments: structural,
underground (or tax evasion), and illegal (or crime). A description of the variables affecting
each of the three components is provided below. The Appendix reports descriptive statistics
for all covariates and information on data sources (see Tables A1 and A2).
3.2.1. The structural component of the demand for cash payments
Drawing on the literature (e.g., Goodhart and Krueger, 2001), we identify four
conventional determinants of the structural demand for cash payments: the level of
economic development, the degree of spatial diffusion of banking, the payment technology
and the interest rate. Economic development is measured as per capita GDP at the
provincial level (YPC). As several authors suggest (e.g., Schneider and Enste, 2000;
Schneider, 2010), the expected sign of this variable is negative: the higher the standard of
living, the lower the relative use of cash and the greater the demand for alternative payment
instruments. Income is closely correlated with education (both general education and
financial literacy), and more education usually leads to less use of cash, since more educated
individuals have greater trust in alternative payment instruments (World Bank, 2005;
Ferwerda et al., 2010).
We use the per capita number of current accounts (BANK) as a proxy for the diffusion of
banking, thus controlling for the structural impact of the degree of bank branch diffusion on
the demand for cash payments. The expected sign of the BANK coefficient is negative, in
that where there are more current accounts there is less need to withdraw cash from ATMs to
make payments.
A number of studies (e.g., Drehmann and Goodhart, 2000; Goodhart and Krueger, 2001;
Schneider, 2009) emphasize the importance of the payment technology, with special reference
to electronic payment instruments. In our model, the structural determinants of CASH
include the variable ELECTRO, the value of transactions settled by electronic payments in
proportion to provincial GDP. Since a higher share of electronic transactions (via POS and
internet banking) implies fewer cash transactions, the expected sign of ELECTRO is
negative.

14
The interest rate on current deposits (INT) is the fourth determinant of the structural
component of CASH. Based on standard economic theory, it is expected to have a negative
effect on the demand for money, insofar as a higher interest rate increases the opportunity
cost of holding cash instead of interest-bearing assets. However, our model deals with cash
flows rather than stocks of liquid assets, which implies an ambiguous effect of the interest
rate.
7
Higher interest rates might even have a positive impact on flows, for instance, by
fostering the raising of cash outside the banking channel. However, given the standard
speculative motive, we cannot exclude the possibility that a higher interest rate on bank
deposits may also diminish the propensity to withdraw cash as an alternative to other
payment instruments. Thus, the expected sign of the INT coefficient is ambiguous.
3.2.2. The underground component
We revise the traditional CDA by using measures of detected tax evasion in lieu of the
standard proxies for the tax burden, such as the average income tax rate. Data on detected
tax evasion are retrieved from a dataset on law enforcement inspections carried out by the
Italian finance police (Guardia di Finanza). This information is particularly relevant for two
reasons. First, many factors in addition to the tax and social security burden are likely to
influence the decision to evade the surveillance of the tax authorities (market regulation,
citizens tax morale, the efficiency of government, etc.), and each of these factors would need
its own proxy.
8
Second, there are no available data on the actual tax rate at the provincial
level in Italy, and the calculation of some measures of the tax burden at that level is not
simple, since taxes are levied by different levels of government.
To overcome these problems, we selected two variables that provide a direct measure of
the diffusion of the economic activities not fully known to the tax authorities at the
provincial level. EVAS1 is the number of targeted tax audits
9
in a given province divided by
its sample mean (this is a measure of tax evasion intensity at the provincial level) and then

7
Studies on the role of innovative payment systems in the cash demand of Italian households (e.g., Ardizzi and
Tresoldi, 2003; Lippi and Secchi, 2008; Alvarez and Lippi, 2009) have found that progress in transaction
technology can actually reduce (or even eliminate) the impact of the interest rate on buyers demand for cash.
8
For a discussion of these other determinants of the decision to operate in the shadow economy see, among
others, Friedman et al. (2000), Schneider and Enste (2000, 2002), Feld and Frey (2007), Dreher et al. (2009),
Torgler and Schneider (2009), and Dreher and Schneider (2010).
9
These audits are targeted in the sense that they imply inspections of firms based on information of fraud within
a particular operation (e.g., payment of salaries) and/or related to a single item of the tax base (e.g., income
taxes or social security contributions).

15
weighted by a GDP concentration index.
10
This latter standardization allows us to compare
provinces characterized by large differences in level of economic development, and so to avoid
automatically attaching higher levels of tax evasion to provinces with an above-average
number of audits. The second variable (EVAS2) takes account of irregularities detected by
the finance police in inspections of retailers. It is modeled as the ratio of the number of
positive audits on cash registers and tax receipts to the number of existing POS terminals in
the province.
11
The standardization for the number of POS terminals is necessary because of
the very great inter-provincial variability in their number, which is likely to affect the
opportunity for evasion (which will be lower where the number of terminals is higher). Both
EVAS1 and EVAS2 are included in our model, in that the former refers to inspections that
may relate to any assumed fiscal irregularity (evasion of income and indirect taxes or social
security contributions) in any type of business, whereas the latter certainly detects only tax
frauds in sales by retailers (VAT and income tax evasion). Thus, EVAS1 and EVAS2 are
expected to jointly provide a more comprehensive evaluation of the underground component
of the demand for cash payments.
3.2.3. The illegal component
A further innovation with respect to the standard CDA is an index of the crime rate, in
order to separate the illegal component of unobserved (cash-settled) economy from shadow
economic activity.
12
Our CRIME indicator is defined as the ratio of drug and prostitution
offenses to the total number of crimes reported in the province. Like the tax evasion
variables, this indicator has been weighted by a GDP concentration index. The selection of
the variables used to estimate the size of the illegal economy needs a brief explanation. Our
choice of drug- and prostitution-related offenses is motivated by the focus on criminal
activities that in line with the OECD (2002) definition of the illegal economy imply an
exchange between a seller and a buyer relying on a mutual agreement and a voluntary cash
payment. Accordingly we excluded crimes that depend on violence (burglary, extortion, etc.)

10
The GDP concentration index is defined as the ratio of provincial GDP to its sample mean.
11
Here positive means audits that detected some evasion. The ratio is weighted for the GDP concentration
index, for the same reasons discussed above.
12
To the best of our knowledge, the only previous attempt to account for the presence of criminal activities in
Italy is Zizza (2002), where the indicator is the share of thefts and robberies in the total number of reported
crimes. However, as we argue below, this indicator is not adequate to capture the excess demand for cash
payments due to illegal activity.

16
and therefore imply payments that do not follow an agreement (as between thief and
victim.
13
We also excluded those offences with possible ambiguous effects on the volume of
cash withdrawals. This is the case of thefts, for instance, which might diminish our CASH
variable because in areas where robbery is more common people may find it too dangerous to
hold cash. In essence, our choice is consistent with the model to be estimated, which exploits
information on cash withdrawals from current accounts due to a voluntary transactional
motive.
3.3. Estimating the demand for cash payments
Equation [1] provides the complete model of the demand for cash payments to be
estimated, which comprises the structural demand reflecting the ordinary preference for
liquidity augmented by the components relating to the underground economy and illegal
economic activity:
it it it it
it it it it it
CRIME EVAS EVAS
INT ELECTRO BANK YPC CASH
c + + + +
+ + + + =
7 6 5
4 3 2 1 0
2 1

[1]
We depart from the existing CDA literature on Italy, which has so far dealt with country-
level data, and apply model [1] to a balanced panel of the 91 Italian provinces (out of 103) for
which complete information was available for all the variables included in Equation [1]. The
observation period is 2005 to 2008.
Given the panel structure of the database, we use a random-effects Tobit model to
account for unobservable residual heterogeneity across provinces (Wooldridge, 2002). Unlike
the standard panel regression with individual random effects, this model can accommodate
the particular distribution of the dependent variable, which is censored and has a
concentrated mass of positive values very close to zero.
14
In particular, we specify the error

13
We do not consider money laundering, since this is a crime that follows from other predicate offenses and
amplifies the impact of organized crime on both the regular and the irregular economies in a cumulative way.
The definition of the crime implies that the proceeds of the predicate crime must be laundered through some
legal channel (e.g., bank transactions) in order to lower the chances of the criminals being caught. After this,
the laundered funds can be reinvested in legitimate activities.
14
The sample mean of CASH is 0.11 (median = 0.10), with a minimum of 0.01 and a maximum of 0.24; 75% of
the observations show values below 0.14. Before considering the censored nature of CASH and adopting the
Tobit specification, we estimated our model by both LSDV and GLS panel tecniques. The Hausman test did not
reject the GLS model. Indeed, Cameron and Trivedi (2005) argue that one of the weaknesses of the LSDV model
is the high degree of inaccuracy of the estimates when the within-panel variability is dominated by between-panel

17
structure of Equation [1] as it = ui + e it, where u denotes individual effects and e the standard
disturbance term.
15

After obtaining the parameter estimates of the model, we adapt and apply the procedure
originally proposed by Tanzi (1983) to gauge the size of the underground economy. The size of
total (shadow plus illegal) unobserved transactions is given by the excess demand for cash
payments the portion not explained by structural factors. This excess demand is obtained
as the difference between the fitted values of CASH from the full model [1], and the predicted
values from a restricted version of Equation [1] setting EVAS1 = EVAS2 = CRIME = 0. To
evaluate the size of the two components of the unobserved economy separately, we then
proceed in a similar manner, alternately imposing the restrictions EVAS1 = EVAS2 = 0 and
CRIME = 0, and calculating the excess demand for cash payments due to tax evasion
(underground economy) and criminal activities (illegal economy), respectively. Given our
definition of CASH, the estimates so obtained are expressed in relation to total payments
settled by instruments other than cash. To get measures that are comparable with previous
studies, we then rescale our estimates of the shadow and illegal economy and express the
results in terms of provincial GDP.

variability. Looking at Table A2 in the Appendix, it is clear that this is the case for all variables of our model
(except INT). In light of this, we decided to adopt a random-effects Tobit specification.
15
We also tested a model including time effects in addition to provincial individual effects. However, apart from
the year 2007, for which the estimated coefficient was negative and significant, no other time effect was
statistically significant; and the estimates of the other coefficients in equation [1] and the assessment of both the
dynamics and the geographical variations of the underground economy were practically unaffected.

18
Table 2. Estimated demand for cash payments (random-
effects Tobit model Italian provinces, 2005-2008)
a

Regressors
b
MODEL A MODEL B
YPC -0.030*** -0.026***

(0.003) (0.004)
BANK -0.037*** -0.061***

(0.011) (0.013)
ELECTRO -0.005*** -0.005***
(0.001) (0.001)
INT -0.011*** -0.010***
(0.002) (0.002)
EVAS1 0.006*** 0.006***

(0.002) (0.002)
EVAS2
0.027*** 0.010*

(0.005) (0.006)
CRIME - 0.286***
(0.063)
Constant 0.220*** 0.222***
(0.006) (0.006)
Observations 364 364
Log-likelihood 959.08 963.96
Wald statistic (_
2
) 1969.51*** 2563.29***
ou 0.022*** 0.023***
(0.001) (0.001)
o
e
0.012*** 0.012***
(0.000) (0.000)
0.772 0.784
(0.019) (0.017)
a
Dependent variable: CASH; MODEL A: equation [1] without crime
indicator (o7 = 0); MODEL B: equation [1] including crime indicator.
b
Standard errors in parentheses; *** statistically significant at 1%; **
statistically significant at 5%; * statistically significant at 10%.

Table 2 reports the estimation results. The first column shows the estimates for a reduced
version of Equation [1], taking account only of underground production as a component of
the unobserved economy (MODEL A). The second column reports results for a complete model
considering both tax evasion and criminal activity (MODEL B). All the estimated coefficients
have the expected sign, and all except one are statistically significant at the 1% level.
Moreover, the LR test (H0: MODEL A = MODEL B) confirms the importance of controlling for

19
the presence of illegal activity in assessing the extent of the underground economy: the
inclusion of CRIME significantly improves the models fit (_
2
(1) = 9.76, p-value = 0.002) and
also reduces the magnitude of the coefficient associated to EVAS2 from 0.027 to 0.010, thus
lowering the total impact of tax evasion on the demand for cash and, possibly, the estimated
size of the shadow economy.
16
Finally, for both specifications the coefficient which
measures the proportion of total residual variance explained by individual effects (u) in
relation to the proportion explained by noise (e) is close to 0.80, underscoring the
importance of using panel techniques to control for unobserved heterogeneity due to
province-specific idiosyncratic random shocks.
3.4. Assessing the unobserved economy
The size of the total unobserved economy for each province in each year has been
estimated by the most comprehensive specification of Equation [1] (MODEL B), which allows
us to obtain separate measures for the underground and the illegal economy. Before
computing average values (reported in Table 3), we discarded 26 outliers identified using the
Hadi (1992, 1994) method.

Table 3. Size of unobserved economy as % of GDP (Italian provinces, 2005-2008)
a


Underground
economy
Illegal economy
Total unobserved
economy
2005 14.5% 10.2% 24.7%
2006 15.0% 9.6% 24.6%
2007 18.0% 11.3% 29.3%
2008 18.5% 12.6% 31.1%
Average 2005-2008 16.5% 10.9% 27.4%
a
26 outliers were dropped using the Hadi (1992, 1994) method.

Several interesting results emerge from Table 3. First, the estimated size of the
unobserved economy due to tax evasion (16.5% of GDP over the entire period 2005-2008) is

16
Results are robust to an alternative crime indicator defined as the ratio of drug and prostitution offences in a
province divided by its sample mean value (weighted by a GDP concentration index).

20
very close to the official figures provided by Istat (2010), while Schneider and Enste (2000,
2002) report much higher values (above 25% from the mid-1990s to 2000). As suggested by
Zizza (2002), this discrepancy is likely to reflect the role of criminal activities. Indeed, the
ratio of the illegal economys value added to GDP in 2007 is in line with the only available
estimates provided by Eurispes (2008) for that year (about 11% of GDP). The estimates of
MODEL A where the crime indicator is not included confirm that neglecting the illegal
component leads to an overestimation of underground output: MODEL A implies a larger
estimate of the underground economy than MODEL B (21.4% on average in 2005-2008), not far
from the estimates presented by Schneider (2010) but lower than the sum of the shadow
economy and illegal output estimated in MODEL B (27.4%).
17
Hence, ignoring crime as a
component of total cash payments may cause two possible measurement errors: confusing tax
evasion with illegal economic activity and underestimating the total size of the unobserved
economy.
As to temporal dynamics, both components increase between 2005 and 2008. The increase
is sharper for tax evasion (4 percentage points) than for the criminal economy (2.4 percentage
points), and there is a jump between 2006 and 2007 (3 and 1.7 percentage points
respectively). This may be due at least in part to the onset of the cyclical downturn in 2007 in
Italy as in the rest of the euro area consequent to the world financial crisis, with an abrupt
slowdown in consumption and investment and a marked deterioration in firms confidence
(Bank of Italy, 2007). The negative expectations of citizens and firms may have led to
increased concealment of taxable income, greater resort to the underground labour market,
and possibly even a movement into the illegal economy.
18
It is worth noticing that the
upward revision in the estimated size of the unobserved economy, as we include illegal
activities, does not mechanically translate in the final estimate of GDP. Indeed the latter
results from an extensive and balanced process combining different inputs coming from both

17
The average incidence of the underground economy estimated by Schneider (2010) in the years 2005-2007 was
23.3% of GDP. However, since the estimates for the more recent years were derived from a combination of the
MIMIC method with the CDA, in this case the comparison is more difficult than for the values computed up to
2000 and presented in Schneider and Enste (2000, 2002). For additional details, see Schneider (2010).
18
Note that these cyclical changes are likely to involve variations in the velocity of money, which presumably
fell in the official economy and increased in the irregular sectors. This further supports the adoption of an
estimation approach such as our modified CDA that overcomes the constraint of money velocity being
constant over time and the same in the regular and the unobserved economy.

21
the demand and the supply side of the economy, with our estimate of illegal activity
potentially providing a further ingredient.
4. Conclusions
This paper takes its place in the debate on the size of the underground economy with a
reinterpretation of the standard currency demand approach la Tanzi, which aims at
overcoming the drawbacks criticized by Schneider and Enste (2000, 2002). Our contributions
can be summarized as follows. First, we introduce a direct measure of the value of cash
transactions as the dependent variable in the money demand equation. In particular, instead
of the traditional money stock variable we use the flow of cash withdrawn from current
accounts as a ratio to total non-cash payments. This innovation enables us to dispense with
the Fisher equation and its unrealistic assumptions of zero underground production in the
base year and equal velocity of money in the official and the irregular economy. Second,
instead of taking tax burden as the key determinant of the decision to operate in the
underground economy, we capture the excess demand for cash payments due to tax evasion
by exploiting direct information on detected non-compliance, thus overcoming the problem of
finding suitable proxies for all the relevant causes. Third, we also control for the role of illegal
economic activity (in our case, drug dealing and prostitution), which jointly with the
shadow economy contributes to the larger aggregate of the unobserved economy and
accounts for a significant portion of total cash payments.
We apply this modified CDA to original data on monetary variables, tax evasion and
reported illegal activities for the Italian provinces over the period 2005-2008. Our results
estimate the shadow economy at an average of 16.5% of GDP, which is consistent with the
recent estimates available from official statistical sources relying on microeconomic methods
but lower than the values for Italy in the international literature (e.g. Schneider and Enste,
2000, 2002 and Schneider, 2010). We show that this discrepancy is likely to be due to the
omission of illegal activities in the application of the standard CDA. This indicates that if one
ignores illegal economic activity one may not only mistakenly attribute to the shadow
economy a part of the cash payments due to criminal transactions but also underestimate the
total incidence of the unobserved economy (namely underground plus illegal economic
activity). It is worth noticing that the upward revision in the estimated size of the

22
unobserved economy, as we include illegal activities, does not mechanically translate in the
final estimate of GDP. Indeed the latter results from an extensive and balanced process
combining different inputs coming from both the demand and the supply side of the
economy, with our estimate of illegal activity potentially providing a further ingredient.


References
Ahumada, H., Alvaredo, F. and Canavese, A. (2007), The Monetary Method and the Size of
the Shadow Economy: A Critical Assessment, Review of Income and Wealth, 53(2), 363-
371.
Alvarez, F. and Lippi, F. (2009), Financial Innovation and the Transactions Demand for
Cash, Econometrica, 77(2), 363-402.
Ardizzi, G., Petraglia, C., Piacenza, M. and Turati, G. (2011), Leconomia sommersa fra
evasione e crimine: una rivisitazione del Currency Demand Approach con una
applicazione al contesto italiano, Econpubblica Working Paper n. 155.
Ardizzi, G. and Tresoldi, C. (2003), Spunti di riflessione sulluso del contante nei pagamenti,
Banca Impresa Societ, 2, 153-188.
Bank of Italy (2007), Relazione Annuale, Rome.
Bank of Italy (various years), Survey on Household Income and Wealth, Rome.
Bovi, M. and Castellucci, L. (2001), Cosa sappiamo delleconomia sommersa in Italia al di l
dei luoghi comuni? Alcune proposizioni empiricamente fondate, Economia Pubblica, 6,
77-119.
Breusch, T. (2005), Fragility of Tanzis Method of Estimating the Underground Economy,
Working Paper, School of Economics, Australian National University: Canberra.
Cagan, P. (1958), The Demand for Currency Relative to Total Money Supply, Journal of
Political Economy, 66, 303-328.
Cameron, A.C., and Trivedi, P.K. (2005), Microeconometrics: Methods and Applications,
Cambridge University Press, New York.
Chiarini, B. and Marzano, E. (2004), Dimensione e dinamica delleconomia sommersa: un
approfondimento del currency demand approach, Politica Economica, 3, 303-334.
Dreher, A. and Schneider, F. (2010), Corruption and the Shadow Economy: An Empirical
Analysis, 144(2), Public Choice, 215-238.

23
Dreher, A., Kotsogiannis, C. and McCorriston, S. (2009), How Do Institutions Affect
Corruption and the Shadow Economy?, International Tax and Public Finance, 16(4),
773-796.
Drehmann, M. and Goodhart, C.A.E. (2000), Is Cash Becoming Technologically Outmoded? Or
Does it Remain Necessary to Facilitate Bad Behaviour? An Empirical Investigation into the
Determinants of Cash Holdings, Financial Markets Group Research Centre, Discussion
Paper 358, LSE.
Eurispes (2008), Rapporto Italia 2008, Istituto di Studi Politici Economici e Sociali, Rome.
European Central Bank (2008), Economic Bulletin, special edition, May.
Feld, L. and Frey, B.S. (2007), Tax Compliance as the Result of a Psychological Tax
Contract: The Role of Incentives and Responsive Regulation, Law and Policy, 29(1), 102-
120.
Ferwerda, J., Deleanu, I. and Unger, B. (2010), Revaluating the Tanzi-Model to Estimate the
Underground Economy, Tjalling C. Koopmans Research Institute, Discussion Paper 10-04,
Utrecht School of Economics, February.
Friedman, E., Johnson, S., Kaufmann, D. and Zoido-Lobatn, P. (2000), Dodging the
Grabbing Hand: The Determinants of Unofficial Activity in 69 Countries, 76(3), Journal
of Public Economics, 459-493.
Goodhart, C. and Krueger, M. (2001), The Impact of Technology on Cash Usage, Financial
Markets Group Research Centre, Discussion Paper 374, LSE.
Hadi, A.S. (1992), Identifying Multiple Outliers in Multivariate Data, Journal of the Royal
Statistical Society, Series B, 54, 761-771.
Hadi, A.S. (1994), A Modification of a Method for the Detection of Outliers in Multivariate
Samples, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series B, 56, 393-396.
Istat (2010), La misura delleconomia sommersa secondo le statistiche ufficiali. Anni 2000-
2008, Conti Nazionali Statistiche in Breve, Istituto Nazionale di Statistica, Rome.
Lippert, O. and Walker, M. (1997), The Underground Economy: Global Evidences of its Size and
Impact, Vancouver: The Frazer Institute.
Lippi., F. and Secchi, A. (2008), Technological Change and the Demand for Currency: An
Analysis with Household Data, Bank of Italy, Temi di Discussione, Nr. 697, Roma.
OECD (2002), Measuring the Non-Observed Economy A Handbook, Paris.
Pickhardt, M. and Sard J. (2010), The Size of the Underground Economy in Germany: A
Correction of the Record and New Evidence from the Modified-Cash-Deposit-Ratio Approach,

24
Institute of Spatial and Housing Economics, Working Paper 201036, University of
Mnster.
Rogoff, K. (1998), Blessing or curse? Foreign and underground demand for euro notes,
Economic Policy, 13(26), 261303.
Schneider, F. (2010), The Influence of Public Institutions on the Shadow Economy: An
Empirical Investigation for OECD Countries, Review of Law and Economics, 6(3), 441-
468.
Schneider, F. (2009), The Shadow Economy in Europe. Using Payment Systems to Combat the
Shadow Economy, A.T. Kearney Research Report, September.
Schneider, F. and Enste D.H. (2000), Shadow Economies: Size, Causes and Consequences,
Journal of Economic Literature, 38(1), 77-114.
Schneider, F. and Enste, D.H. (2002), The Shadow Economy: Theoretical Approaches,
Empirical Studies, and Political Implications, Cambridge University Press, UK.
Tanzi, V. (1980), The Underground Economy in the United States: Estimates and
Implications, Banca Nazionale del Lavoro Quarterly Review, 135(4), 427-453.
Tanzi, V. (1983), The Underground Economy in the United States: Annual Estimates 1930-
1980, IMF Staff Papers, 30(2), 283-305.
Thomas, J.J. (1992), Informal Economic Activity, LSE Handbooks in Economics, London:
Harvester Wheatsheaf.
Torgler, B. and Schneider, F. (2009) The Impact of Tax Morale and Institutional Quality on
the Shadow Economy, Journal of Economic Psychology, 30(2), 228-245.
Wooldridge, J.M. (2002), Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data, MIT Press,
Cambridge, Massachusetts.
World Bank (2005), International Migration, Remittances, and the Brain Drain, M. Schiff and
C. Ozden (eds.), Washington, D.C.
Zizza, R. (2002), Metodologie di stima delleconomia sommersa: unapplicazione al caso italiano,
Bank of Italy, Temi di Discussione, No. 463, December.

25
Appendix. The data

This study uses an original dataset on a balanced panel of 91 Italian provinces in the
period 2005-2008. The dataset merges four different sources: Bank of Italy (BI), the Italian
finance police (Guardia di Finanza, GdF), the Italian National Institute of Statistics (Istat),
and Eurostat. All monetary variables are provided by the Bank of Italy. Data on provincial
GDP come from Eurostat. The proxies for tax evasion are computed using data from GdF
fiscal inspections for the period 2005-2008. The crime index uses information on criminal
offenses from Istats website http://giustiziaincifre.istat.it.


Table A1. Data description (definition of variables and data sources)
Variable Definition Source
CASH Ratio of the value of cash withdrawn from current (bank
and postal) accounts to the value of total payments settled
by instruments other than cash
BI
Structural factors
YPC Provincial GDP per capita Eurostat
BANK Per capita number of current accounts BI
ELECTRO Ratio of the value of transactions settled by electronic
payments to GDP
BI and Eurostat
INT Rate of interest on current deposits BI
Tax evasion
EVAS1 Number of targeted tax audits in a province divided by
its sample mean value (weighted by a GDP concentration
index)
GdF and Eurostat
EVAS2 Ratio of the number of positive audits on cash registers
and tax receipts to the number of POS terminals in the
province (weighted by a GDP concentration index)
GdF and Eurostat
Criminal economy
CRIME Share of crimes violating laws on drugs and prostitution
in total reported crimes (weighted by a GDP concentration
index)
Istat and Eurostat


26
Table A2. Descriptive statistics
a


Standard Deviation
Variable Mean
Total Between Within
Min Max
CASH 0.108 0.048 0.046 0.013 0.010 0.236
YPC (10
4
)

2.491 0.596 0.590 0.099 1.235 3.908
BANK 0.584 0.193 0.189 0.042 0.236 1.177
ELECTRO 2.100 1.728 1.598 0.672 0.538 16.638
INT 1.247 0.488 0.265 0.410 0.472 2.909
EVAS1 1.151 0.594 0.575 0.159 0.222 3.839
EVAS2 0.204 0.215 0.207 0.063 0.001 1.233
CRIME 0.023 0.020 0.019 0.004 0.001 0.116
a
Based on a balanced panel of 91 Italian provinces observed in 2005-2008 (364 total observations).

(*) Requestsforcopiesshouldbesentto:
BancadItaliaServizioStudidistrutturaeconomicaefnanziariaDivisioneBibliotecaeArchiviostoricoVia
Nazionale,9100184Rome(fax00390647922059).TheyareavailableontheInternetwww.bancaditalia.it.
RECENTLYPUBLISHEDTEMI(*)
N. 841 Real term structure and infation compensation in the euro area, by Marcello
Pericoli(January2012).
N. 842 Expected infation and infation risk premium in the euro area and in the United
States,byMarcelloPericoli(January2012).
N. 843 Wealth effects in emerging economies,byAlessioCiarlone(January2012).
N. 844 How sticky are local expenditures in Italy? Assessing the relevance of the fypaper
effect through municipal data,byElenaGennariandGiovannaMessina(January
2012).
N. 845 Do wealth fuctuations generate time-varying risk aversion? Italian micro-evidence
on household asset allocation,byGiuseppeCappelletti(January2012).
N. 846 Welcome to the machine: frms reaction to low-skilled immigration, byAntonio
Accetturo,MatteoBugamelliandAndreaLamorgese(January2012).
N. 847 Forecasting economic activity with higher frequency targeted predictors,byGuido
Bulligan,MassimilianoMarcellinoandFabrizioVenditti(January2012).
N. 848 Bank balance sheets and the transmission of fnancial shocks to borrowers:
evidence from the 2007-2008 crisis,byEmiliaBonaccorsidiPattiandEnricoSette
(January2012).
N. 849 The role of fnancial investments in agricultural commodity derivatives markets,by
AlessandroBorinandVirginiaDiNino(January2012).
N. 850 Mapping local productivity advantages in Italy: industrial districts, cities or both?,
byValterDiGiacinto,MatteoGomellini,GiacintoMicucciandMarcelloPagnini
(January2012).
N. 851 The impact of monetary policy shocks on commodity prices,byAlessioAnzuini,
MarcoJ.LombardiandPatrizioPagano(February2012).
N. 852 Statistical models for measuring job satisfaction, by Romina Gambacorta and
MariaIannario(February2012).
N. 853 Forecasting world output: the rising importance of emerging economies, by
Alessandro Borin, Riccardo Cristadoro, Roberto Golinelli and Giuseppe Parigi
(February2012).
N. 854 Entry dynamics as a solution to the puzzling behaviour of real marginal costs in the
Ghironi-Melitz model,byAlbertoFelettigh(February2012).
N. 855 Trade openness and international fragmentation of production in the European
Union: the new divide?,byPaoloGuerrieriandFilippoVergaraCaffarelli(February
2012).
N. 856 Optimal dynamic public communication,byMarcelloMiccoli(February2012).
N. 857 Modelling loans to non-fnancial corporations in the euro area,byChristofferKok
Srensen,DavidMarqusIbezandCarlottaRossi(February2012).
N. 858 Economic (in)stability under monetary targeting,byLucaSessa(March2012).
N. 859 Optimal fscal policy when agents fear government default,byFrancescoCaprioli,
PietroRizzaandPietroTommasino(March2012).
N. 860 The effects of unemployment benefts in Italy: evidence from an institutional
change,byAlfonsoRosoliaandPaoloSestito(March2012).
N. 861 Monetary policy and the fow of funds in the euro area,byRiccardoBonci(March
2012).
"TEMI" LATER PUBLISHED ELSEWHERE

2009

F. PANETTA, F. SCHIVARDI and M. SHUM, Do mergers improve information? Evidence from the loan market,
Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, v. 41, 4, pp. 673-709, TD No. 521 (October 2004).
M. BUGAMELLI and F. PATERN, Do workers remittances reduce the probability of current account
reversals?, World Development, v. 37, 12, pp. 1821-1838, TD No. 573 (January 2006).
P. PAGANO and M. PISANI, Risk-adjusted forecasts of oil prices, The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics, v.
9, 1, Article 24, TD No. 585 (March 2006).
M. PERICOLI and M. SBRACIA, The CAPM and the risk appetite index: theoretical differences, empirical
similarities, and implementation problems, International Finance, v. 12, 2, pp. 123-150, TD No.
586 (March 2006).
R. BRONZINI and P. PISELLI, Determinants of long-run regional productivity with geographical spillovers:
the role of R&D, human capital and public infrastructure, Regional Science and Urban
Economics, v. 39, 2, pp.187-199, TD No. 597 (September 2006).
U. ALBERTAZZI and L. GAMBACORTA, Bank profitability and the business cycle, Journal of Financial
Stability, v. 5, 4, pp. 393-409, TD No. 601 (September 2006).
F. BALASSONE, D. FRANCO and S. ZOTTERI, The reliability of EMU fiscal indicators: risks and safeguards,
in M. Larch and J. Nogueira Martins (eds.), Fiscal Policy Making in the European Union: an
Assessment of Current Practice and Challenges, London, Routledge, TD No. 633 (June 2007).
A. CIARLONE, P. PISELLI and G. TREBESCHI, Emerging Markets' Spreads and Global Financial Conditions, Journal
of International Financial Markets, Institutions & Money, v. 19, 2, pp. 222-239, TD No. 637 (June 2007).
S. MAGRI, The financing of small innovative firms: the Italian case, Economics of Innovation and New
Technology, v. 18, 2, pp. 181-204, TD No. 640 (September 2007).
V. DI GIACINTO and G. MICUCCI, The producer service sector in Italy: long-term growth and its local
determinants, Spatial Economic Analysis, Vol. 4, No. 4, pp. 391-425, TD No. 643 (September 2007).
F. LORENZO, L. MONTEFORTE and L. SESSA, The general equilibrium effects of fiscal policy: estimates for the
euro area, Journal of Public Economics, v. 93, 3-4, pp. 559-585, TD No. 652 (November 2007).
Y. ALTUNBAS, L. GAMBACORTA and D. MARQUS, Securitisation and the bank lending channel, European
Economic Review, v. 53, 8, pp. 996-1009, TD No. 653 (November 2007).
R. GOLINELLI and S. MOMIGLIANO, The Cyclical Reaction of Fiscal Policies in the Euro Area. A Critical
Survey of Empirical Research, Fiscal Studies, v. 30, 1, pp. 39-72, TD No. 654 (January 2008).
P. DEL GIOVANE, S. FABIANI and R. SABBATINI, Whats behind Inflation Perceptions? A survey-based
analysis of Italian consumers, Giornale degli Economisti e Annali di Economia, v. 68, 1, pp. 25-
52, TD No. 655 (January 2008).
F. MACCHERONI, M. MARINACCI, A. RUSTICHINI and M. TABOGA, Portfolio selection with monotone mean-
variance preferences, Mathematical Finance, v. 19, 3, pp. 487-521, TD No. 664 (April 2008).
M. AFFINITO and M. PIAZZA, What are borders made of? An analysis of barriers to European banking
integration, in P. Alessandrini, M. Fratianni and A. Zazzaro (eds.): The Changing Geography of
Banking and Finance, Dordrecht Heidelberg London New York, Springer, TD No. 666 (April 2008).
A. BRANDOLINI, On applying synthetic indices of multidimensional well-being: health and income
inequalities in France, Germany, Italy, and the United Kingdom, in R. Gotoh and P. Dumouchel
(eds.), Against Injustice. The New Economics of Amartya Sen, Cambridge, Cambridge University
Press, TD No. 668 (April 2008).
G. FERRERO and A. NOBILI, Futures contract rates as monetary policy forecasts, International Journal of
Central Banking, v. 5, 2, pp. 109-145, TD No. 681 (June 2008).
P. CASADIO, M. LO CONTE and A. NERI, Balancing work and family in Italy: the new mothers employment
decisions around childbearing, in T. Addabbo and G. Solinas (eds.), Non-Standard Employment and
Qualit of Work, Physica-Verlag. A Sprinter Company, TD No. 684 (August 2008).
L. ARCIERO, C. BIANCOTTI, L. D'AURIZIO and C. IMPENNA, Exploring agent-based methods for the analysis
of payment systems: A crisis model for StarLogo TNG, Journal of Artificial Societies and Social
Simulation, v. 12, 1, TD No. 686 (August 2008).
A. CALZA and A. ZAGHINI, Nonlinearities in the dynamics of the euro area demand for M1,
Macroeconomic Dynamics, v. 13, 1, pp. 1-19, TD No. 690 (September 2008).
L. FRANCESCO and A. SECCHI, Technological change and the households demand for currency, Journal of
Monetary Economics, v. 56, 2, pp. 222-230, TD No. 697 (December 2008).
G. ASCARI and T. ROPELE, Trend inflation, taylor principle, and indeterminacy, Journal of Money, Credit
and Banking, v. 41, 8, pp. 1557-1584, TD No. 708 (May 2007).
S. COLAROSSI and A. ZAGHINI, Gradualism, transparency and the improved operational framework: a look at
overnight volatility transmission, International Finance, v. 12, 2, pp. 151-170, TD No. 710 (May 2009).
M. BUGAMELLI, F. SCHIVARDI and R. ZIZZA, The euro and firm restructuring, in A. Alesina e F. Giavazzi
(eds): Europe and the Euro, Chicago, University of Chicago Press, TD No. 716 (June 2009).
B. HALL, F. LOTTI and J. MAIRESSE, Innovation and productivity in SMEs: empirical evidence for Italy,
Small Business Economics, v. 33, 1, pp. 13-33, TD No. 718 (June 2009).

2010

A. PRATI and M. SBRACIA, Uncertainty and currency crises: evidence from survey data, Journal of
Monetary Economics, v, 57, 6, pp. 668-681, TD No. 446 (July 2002).
L. MONTEFORTE and S. SIVIERO, The Economic Consequences of Euro Area Modelling Shortcuts, Applied
Economics, v. 42, 19-21, pp. 2399-2415, TD No. 458 (December 2002).
S. MAGRI, Debt maturity choice of nonpublic Italian firms , Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, v.42,
2-3, pp. 443-463, TD No. 574 (January 2006).
G. DE BLASIO and G. NUZZO, Historical traditions of civicness and local economic development, Journal of
Regional Science, v. 50, 4, pp. 833-857, TD No. 591 (May 2006).
E. IOSSA and G. PALUMBO, Over-optimism and lender liability in the consumer credit market, Oxford
Economic Papers, v. 62, 2, pp. 374-394, TD No. 598 (September 2006).
S. NERI and A. NOBILI, The transmission of US monetary policy to the euro area, International Finance, v.
13, 1, pp. 55-78, TD No. 606 (December 2006).
F. ALTISSIMO, R. CRISTADORO, M. FORNI, M. LIPPI and G. VERONESE, New Eurocoin: Tracking Economic Growth
in Real Time, Review of Economics and Statistics, v. 92, 4, pp. 1024-1034, TD No. 631 (June 2007).
U. ALBERTAZZI and L. GAMBACORTA, Bank profitability and taxation, Journal of Banking and Finance, v.
34, 11, pp. 2801-2810, TD No. 649 (November 2007).
M. IACOVIELLO and S. NERI, Housing market spillovers: evidence from an estimated DSGE model,
American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, v. 2, 2, pp. 125-164, TD No. 659 (January 2008).
F. BALASSONE, F. MAURA and S. ZOTTERI, Cyclical asymmetry in fiscal variables in the EU, Empirica, TD
No. 671, v. 37, 4, pp. 381-402 (June 2008).
F. D'AMURI, O. GIANMARCO I.P. and P. GIOVANNI, The labor market impact of immigration on the western
german labor market in the 1990s, European Economic Review, v. 54, 4, pp. 550-570, TD No.
687 (August 2008).
A. ACCETTURO, Agglomeration and growth: the effects of commuting costs, Papers in Regional Science, v.
89, 1, pp. 173-190, TD No. 688 (September 2008).
S. NOBILI and G. PALAZZO, Explaining and forecasting bond risk premiums, Financial Analysts Journal, v.
66, 4, pp. 67-82, TD No. 689 (September 2008).
A. B. ATKINSON and A. BRANDOLINI, On analysing the world distribution of income, World Bank
Economic Review , v. 24, 1 , pp. 1-37, TD No. 701 (January 2009).
R. CAPPARIELLO and R. ZIZZA, Dropping the Books and Working Off the Books, Labour, v. 24, 2, pp. 139-
162 ,TD No. 702 (January 2009).
C. NICOLETTI and C. RONDINELLI, The (mis)specification of discrete duration models with unobserved
heterogeneity: a Monte Carlo study, Journal of Econometrics, v. 159, 1, pp. 1-13, TD No. 705
(March 2009).
L. FORNI, A. GERALI and M. PISANI, Macroeconomic effects of greater competition in the service sector:
the case of Italy, Macroeconomic Dynamics, v. 14, 5, pp. 677-708, TD No. 706 (March 2009).
V. DI GIACINTO, G. MICUCCI and P. MONTANARO, Dynamic macroeconomic effects of public capital:
evidence from regional Italian data, Giornale degli economisti e annali di economia, v. 69, 1, pp. 29-
66, TD No. 733 (November 2009).
F. COLUMBA, L. GAMBACORTA and P. E. MISTRULLI, Mutual Guarantee institutions and small business
finance, Journal of Financial Stability, v. 6, 1, pp. 45-54, TD No. 735 (November 2009).
A. GERALI, S. NERI, L. SESSA and F. M. SIGNORETTI, Credit and banking in a DSGE model of the Euro
Area, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, v. 42, 6, pp. 107-141, TD No. 740 (January 2010).
M. AFFINITO and E. TAGLIAFERRI, Why do (or did?) banks securitize their loans? Evidence from Italy, Journal
of Financial Stability, v. 6, 4, pp. 189-202, TD No. 741 (January 2010).
S. FEDERICO, Outsourcing versus integration at home or abroad and firm heterogeneity, Empirica, v. 37,
1, pp. 47-63, TD No. 742 (February 2010).
V. DI GIACINTO, On vector autoregressive modeling in space and time, Journal of Geographical Systems, v. 12,
2, pp. 125-154, TD No. 746 (February 2010).
L. FORNI, A. GERALI and M. PISANI, The macroeconomics of fiscal consolidations in euro area countries,
Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, v. 34, 9, pp. 1791-1812, TD No. 747 (March 2010).
S. MOCETTI and C. PORELLO, How does immigration affect native internal mobility? new evidence from
Italy, Regional Science and Urban Economics, v. 40, 6, pp. 427-439, TD No. 748 (March 2010).
A. DI CESARE and G. GUAZZAROTTI, An analysis of the determinants of credit default swap spread
changes before and during the subprime financial turmoil, Journal of Current Issues in Finance,
Business and Economics, v. 3, 4, pp., TD No. 749 (March 2010).
P. CIPOLLONE, P. MONTANARO and P. SESTITO, Value-added measures in Italian high schools: problems
and findings, Giornale degli economisti e annali di economia, v. 69, 2, pp. 81-114, TD No. 754
(March 2010).
A. BRANDOLINI, S. MAGRI and T. M SMEEDING, Asset-based measurement of poverty, Journal of Policy
Analysis and Management, v. 29, 2 , pp. 267-284, TD No. 755 (March 2010).
G. CAPPELLETTI, A Note on rationalizability and restrictions on beliefs, The B.E. Journal of Theoretical
Economics, v. 10, 1, pp. 1-11,TD No. 757 (April 2010).
S. DI ADDARIO and D. VURI, Entrepreneurship and market size. the case of young college graduates in
Italy, Labour Economics, v. 17, 5, pp. 848-858, TD No. 775 (September 2010).
A. CALZA and A. ZAGHINI, Sectoral money demand and the great disinflation in the US, Journal of Money,
Credit, and Banking, v. 42, 8, pp. 1663-1678, TD No. 785 (January 2011).

2011

S. DI ADDARIO, Job search in thick markets, Journal of Urban Economics, v. 69, 3, pp. 303-318, TD No.
605 (December 2006).
F. SCHIVARDI and E. VIVIANO, Entry barriers in retail trade, Economic Journal, v. 121, 551, pp. 145-170, TD
No. 616 (February 2007).
G. FERRERO, A. NOBILI and P. PASSIGLIA, Assessing excess liquidity in the Euro Area: the role of sectoral
distribution of money, Applied Economics, v. 43, 23, pp. 3213-3230, TD No. 627 (April 2007).
P. E. MISTRULLI, Assessing financial contagion in the interbank market: maximun entropy versus observed
interbank lending patterns, Journal of Banking & Finance, v. 35, 5, pp. 1114-1127, TD No. 641
(September 2007).
E. CIAPANNA, Directed matching with endogenous markov probability: clients or competitors?, The
RAND Journal of Economics, v. 42, 1, pp. 92-120, TD No. 665 (April 2008).
M. BUGAMELLI and F. PATERN, Output growth volatility and remittances, Economica, v. 78, 311, pp.
480-500, TD No. 673 (June 2008).
V. DI GIACINTO e M. PAGNINI, Local and global agglomeration patterns: two econometrics-based
indicators, Regional Science and Urban Economics, v. 41, 3, pp. 266-280, TD No. 674 (June 2008).
G. BARONE and F. CINGANO, Service regulation and growth: evidence from OECD countries, Economic
Journal, v. 121, 555, pp. 931-957, TD No. 675 (June 2008).
R. GIORDANO and P. TOMMASINO, What determines debt intolerance? The role of political and monetary
institutions, European Journal of Political Economy, v. 27, 3, pp. 471-484, TD No. 700 (January 2009).
P. ANGELINI, A. NOBILI e C. PICILLO, The interbank market after August 2007: What has changed, and
why?, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, v. 43, 5, pp. 923-958, TD No. 731 (October 2009).
L. FORNI, A. GERALI and M. PISANI, The Macroeconomics of Fiscal Consolidation in a Monetary Union:
the Case of Italy, in Luigi Paganetto (ed.), Recovery after the crisis. Perspectives and policies,
VDM Verlag Dr. Muller, TD No. 747 (March 2010).
A. DI CESARE and G. GUAZZAROTTI, An analysis of the determinants of credit default swap changes before
and during the subprime financial turmoil, in Barbara L. Campos and Janet P. Wilkins (eds.), The
Financial Crisis: Issues in Business, Finance and Global Economics, New York, Nova Science
Publishers, Inc., TD No. 749 (March 2010).
A. LEVY and A. ZAGHINI, The pricing of government guaranteed bank bonds, Banks and Bank Systems, v.
6, 3, pp. 16-24, TD No. 753 (March 2010).
G. GRANDE and I. VISCO, A public guarantee of a minimum return to defined contribution pension scheme
members, The Journal of Risk, v. 13, 3, pp. 3-43, TD No. 762 (June 2010).
P. DEL GIOVANE, G. ERAMO and A. NOBILI, Disentangling demand and supply in credit developments: a
survey-based analysis for Italy, Journal of Banking and Finance, v. 35, 10, pp. 2719-2732, TD No.
764 (June 2010).
G. BARONE and S. MOCETTI, With a little help from abroad: the effect of low-skilled immigration on the
female labour supply, Labour Economics, v. 18, 5, pp. 664-675, TD No. 766 (July 2010).
A. FELETTIGH and S. FEDERICO, Measuring the price elasticity of import demand in the destination markets of
italian exports, Economia e Politica Industriale, v. 38, 1, pp. 127-162, TD No. 776 (October 2010).
S. MAGRI and R. PICO, The rise of risk-based pricing of mortgage interest rates in Italy, Journal of
Banking and Finance, v. 35, 5, pp. 1277-1290, TD No. 778 (October 2010).
M. TABOGA, Under/over-valuation of the stock market and cyclically adjusted earnings, International
Finance, v. 14, 1, pp. 135-164, TD No. 780 (December 2010).
S. NERI, Housing, consumption and monetary policy: how different are the U.S. and the Euro area?, Journal
of Banking and Finance, v.35, 11, pp. 3019-3041, TD No. 807 (April 2011).
V. CUCINIELLO, The welfare effect of foreign monetary conservatism with non-atomistic wage setters, Journal
of Money, Credit and Banking, v. 43, 8, pp. 1719-1734, TD No. 810 (June 2011).
A. CALZA and A. ZAGHINI, welfare costs of inflation and the circulation of US currency abroad, The B.E.
Journal of Macroeconomics, v. 11, 1, Art. 12, TD No. 812 (June 2011).
I. FAIELLA, La spesa energetica delle famiglie italiane, Energia, v. 32, 4, pp. 40-46, TD No. 822 (September
2011).
R. DE BONIS and A. SILVESTRINI, The effects of financial and real wealth on consumption: new evidence from
OECD countries, Applied Financial Economics, v. 21, 5, pp. 409425, TD No. 837 (November 2011).

2012

A. ACCETTURO and G. DE BLASIO, Policies for local development: an evaluation of Italys Patti
Territoriali, Regional Science and Urban Economics, v. 42, 1-2, pp. 15-26, TD No. 789
(January 2006).

FORTHCOMING

M. BUGAMELLI and A. ROSOLIA, Produttivit e concorrenza estera, Rivista di politica economica, TD No.
578 (February 2006).
F. CINGANO and A. ROSOLIA, People I know: job search and social networks, Journal of Labor Economics,
TD No. 600 (September 2006).
S. MOCETTI, Educational choices and the selection process before and after compulsory school, Education
Economics, TD No. 691 (September 2008).
P. SESTITO and E. VIVIANO, Reservation wages: explaining some puzzling regional patterns, Labour,
TD No. 696 (December 2008).
P. PINOTTI, M. BIANCHI and P. BUONANNO, Do immigrants cause crime?, Journal of the European
Economic Association, TD No. 698 (December 2008).
F. LIPPI and A. NOBILI, Oil and the macroeconomy: a quantitative structural analysis, Journal of European
Economic Association, TD No. 704 (March 2009).
F. CINGANO and P. PINOTTI, Politicians at work. The private returns and social costs of political connections,
Journal of the European Economic Association, TD No. 709 (May 2009).
Y. ALTUNBAS, L. GAMBACORTA, and D. MARQUS-IBEZ, Bank risk and monetary policy, Journal of
Financial Stability, TD No. 712 (May 2009).
G. BARONE and S. MOCETTI, Tax morale and public spending inefficiency, International Tax and Public
Finance, TD No. 732 (November 2009).
I. BUONO and G. LALANNE, The effect of the Uruguay Round on the intensive and extensive margins of
trade, Journal of International Economics, TD No. 835 (February 2011).
G. BARONE, R. FELICI and M. PAGNINI, Switching costs in local credit markets, International Journal of
Industrial Organization, TD No. 760 (June 2010).
E. COCOZZA and P. PISELLI, Testing for east-west contagion in the European banking sector during the
financial crisis, in R. Matouek; D. Stavrek (eds.), Financial Integration in the European Union,
Taylor & Francis, TD No. 790 (February 2011).
S. NERI and T. ROPELE, Imperfect information, real-time data and monetary policy in the Euro area, The
Economic Journal, TD No. 802 (March 2011).
M. AFFINITO, Do interbank customer relationships exist? And how did they function in the crisis? Learning
from Italy, Journal of Banking and Finance, TD No. 826 (October 2011).
O. BLANCHARD and M. RIGGI, Why are the 2000s so different from the 1970s? A structural interpretation
of changes in the macroeconomic effects of oil prices, Journal of the European Economic
Association, TD No. 835 (November 2011).
R. CRISTADORO and D. MARCONI, Households Savings in China, Chinese Economic and Business Studies,
TD No. 838 (November 2011).

You might also like