On Investm Ent: Governance and Returns
On Investm Ent: Governance and Returns
On Investm Ent: Governance and Returns
TheWorldBank
PolicyResearchDepartment
PovertyandHumanResourcesDivision
November1995
VKIICY
RESEARItH WORKINM PAPER 1550
Summary findings
lUsing data frornithe World Bank's Operations Evaluation civil liberties records projects have an economic rate of
D)epartnmcilt,Ishalan,Kaufmann, and Pritchett examine return between 8 and 22 percentage points higher than
the link between the performance of Bank-financed the rate of return in countries with the worst civil
projects and varioLusinLdicatorsof coountrygovernance. liberties. (The average rate of return in the sample is 16
They find that: percent.)
T'here is a strong statistical, and possibly causal, link * The type of political regime (whether authoritarian
berveen civil liberties and project performance. After or democratic) and the status of more purely political
conltrolling for a variety of determiiinalntsof project liberties do not appear to significantly affect project
performance, they find that in countries with the best performance.
T'his paper -- a prodUct of the Poverty and Human Resources Division, Policy Research Department - is part of a larger
effort in the department to understand the donor and country determinants of aid effectiveness. The study was funded by
the Bank's Research Support Budget under the research project "Bank Project Effectiveness and Country Policy
Envirolnmeit" (RPO 679-49). Copies of this paper are available free from the World Bank, 1818 H StreetNW, Washington,
DC 2043.3. Please contact Sheila Fallon, room N8-030, telephone 202-473-8009, fax 202-522-1123, Internet address
sfallon@(aworldbank.org.(44 pages)
The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about
deuelopmrpent issues. At obje ctive of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The
papers carry thc names of the authors and should be used and cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions are the
authors' ownr atnd should no?tbe attributed to the World Bank, its Executive Board of Directors, or any of its member countries.
An Empirical Investigation
Jonathan Isham
Daniel Kaufmann
Lant H. Pritchett
Governance and the Returns to Investment:An Empirical Investigation'
Tntroductinn
issues plague both the evaluation of inputs--what is the appropriate measurement of good
empirical progress in exploring the connection between the governance and economic performance
only by severely limiting our focus. We first isolate one observable indicator of economic
performance: the returns on investment projects of governments that were financed by the World
Bank. We then relate this performance indicator to just two limited dimensions of governance:
a) the degree of civil liberties; and b) the political regime type and the degree of political liberties.
Despite the serious definitional and measurementproblems with each of these indicators (discussed
The first section describes the data (particularly the data on project performance),
variables, and introduces our classification of governance variables. The second section
establishes the positive link between the degree of civil liberties and project performance and
argues that this relationship is causal. The third section shows the lack of such a relationship
between either political liberties or political regime type. The fourth section discusses the
concludes.
A Project dat
The data on the performance of projects is assembled by the World Bank's Operations
years after the opening of the loan--Bank and borrower country staff write a Project Completion
Report (PCR) to assess project performance5 . As one part of this assessment, two performance
-2 -
indicators are created. For all projects, OED staff assign an overall performance indicator on
whether the project was 'satisfactory' or 'unsatisfactory' in achieving its development objectives.
For those projects in eight economic sub-sectors where the stream of project benefits can be
transport, and tourism--Bank project staff, sometimes in collaboration with OED staff, calculate
The ERR is the discounted stream of project costs and benefits over the life of the project,
following the methodology of Squire and van der Tak (1975)'. The ex post ERRs are typically
calculated about two to three years after project completion, in contrast to ex ante ERRs which
are calculated when the project is first assessed8 . Thus, at the time the ex post ERRs are
calculated, project evaluators know the actual investment costs and are somewhat better informed
about actual operating costs and demand; but they still must estimate most of the future stream of
benefits'.
6 Assessingadjustmentlendingis a whole other kettle of fish, a ketde whichhas been fried on several
occasionsbothbyi.heWorldBankand its staff (World Bank 1991, 1992, 1993;Pritchettand Summers 1993)
as well as othersless sympathetic.We excludeadjustmentoperationsfrom our universeof projects. For a
discussionof projectperformanceand adjustmentlending,see Ishamand Kaufmann(1992).
9 Follow-upstudiestendto find that even the ex post ERRstendto overstatethe "true"rate of return as
in many cases, thebenefitflowsare not sustainedas long as anticipatedin the ex post ERR calculations.
-3-
Table 1 shows the basic information about the ERR and overall ratings used in this
analysis, decomposedby region, from 1974 to 199310. The average rate of return was 16.1
percent. The ERRsvariedsubstantiallyacross regions, from nearly 18 percentin both South and
'1 An annualpublicationby OEDon evaluationresults (e.g. WorldBank 1993)uses this data to examine
project performanceby a numberof characteristics.
-4 -
governanceand project performance. Nevertheless, we must still account for country
correlated with each other and/or with the governance variables, includingthe black
D), this estimate could understatethe true total impact of governanceif part of the impactof
3.
better governanceis through better policies"
The inclusionof the regional dummies, which are obviously exogenous,is simply a
robustnesstorture (for us) test. In order to be persuasivewe feel the results shouldsurvive the
reporting the base case results. First, the ERRs are truncated from below as, accordingto
OED conventionthe lowest ERR reported is negative 5 percent. Thus, unless otherwisenoted,
14 . Second, we must match the time period of the
the reported results use a Tobit regression
3 If the set of equationsfor determiningthe rate of return on project with governance(G), exogenous
-6 -
time varyingvariables, such as black market premium or terms of trade, to the period relevant
to the dependent variables, the economic rate of return on projects. This is difficult, as the
projects are implementedover a long (on average seven years) and variable period and are
expected to yield benefits over an extendedperiod as well. While there are argumentsin favor
of various weights, we use a three year weighted average of the time varying variable, going
back from the year in which the project evaluationwas done. Third, although the projects
vary tremendouslyin total cost, from $1.7 million to $5.7 billion, we do not weight the
projects, nor adjust for heteroskedasticity,as the standard tests did not indicate any conditional
In table 2 and in the tables below, we report p-levels of the test whether the coefficientis zero
rather than the usual test (t or chi-square) statisticsthemselves. The p-level is the significance
level at which the null hypothesiscould be rejected. A p-level of less than 0.05 indicatesa
rejection of the null hypothesisat (at least) the 5 percent level. As noted above, specification
A is the regression of the project ERR on exogenousand structural variables (Xs) alone,
endogenouspolicy indicators (Zs), and specificationD is the full regression: Xs, Zs, and
regional dummies.
The results in table 2 are substantiallythe same as those of Isham and Kaufmann(1995)
and hence will not be discussedin any depth. Most of the results are intuitive: ERRsare
premia, and a larger fiscal deficit. In addition, even after controlling for all these factors,
ERRs are substantially lower in Sub-Saharan Africa and modestly lower in Latin America and
EMENA16 .
16 The regionaldefinitionsare based on the (then) standardBank groupingsinto Latin America and
Caribbean,Sub-Saharan
Africa,SouthAsia, East Asia, and the somewhatmixedbag of Europe, MiddleEast
and NorthAfrica(EMENA).
-8 -
Table 2: Non-g vernance determinants of project returns (ERRs): 1974-1987
Specification:
A B C D
Exogenous Exogenous Exogenous Exogenous,
with region and policy policy, and
durnmies region
dummies
Exogenous
ln(capital/labor) -1.28 -1.73 -1.34 -1.39
(.029)a (.050) (.024) (.122)
Dummy for project -5.80 . -5.81 -4.99 -5.06
complexity (.0001) (.0001) (.0003) (.0002)
Terms of trade 0.086 0.096 0.064 0.077
shock (.278) (.218) (.417) (.316)
Policy
Black market -0.046 -0.040
premia (.0001) (.0001)
Fiscal deficit 0.178 0.229
(.194) (.116)
GDP growth 0.233 0.056
(.272) (.799)
Regional Dummiesb
East Asia -0.61 -2.69
_________________ (.791) (.246)
Latin America -3.85 -4.90
(.140) (.065)
EMENA -6.13 -5.51
(.036) (.071)
Sub-Saharan Africa -8.54 -9.12
(.0001) (.0001)
Notes: a) p-levels in parenthesis, b) based on World Bank regional classifications. Sample
size = 761. Source: Authors' calculations
-9-
Since we focus on the impact of governance variables, we will (as a presentational matter)
only report the coefficients of the various governance indicators when added to these four base
specificationsrather than repeat all the results for each control variable for each regression. Little
of substance is lost in not repeating these results: none of the coefficients on any of the variables
D. Measuring "governance"
Discussions of "governance" typically generate more rhetorical heat than empirical light
as politics, like religion, is a topic where beliefs are strong and reliable empirical measurement
is difficult. Even a consensus on definitions is elusive: what does one mean by "governance" or
stable democracy where basic prescriptive human rights are honored and with a competent and
honest civil service would no doubt receive the label "good governance" from most observers; by
contrast, an unstable autocracywhere human rights are abused and with a demoralized and corrupt
civil service would receive the label "bad governance". There is probably also agreement that the
- 10 -
quality of governance can be evaluated along at least the following three dimensions:
human rights), they are conceptually,logically, and empirically distinct. There are clearly
examples of effective but non-democratic governments (e.g. some East Asian countries),
democratic but corrupt governments (e.g. some South Asian countries), and democratic
governments which abuse human rights (e.g. some Latin Americancountries). As an extreme
of the many possible elementsof governance: the extension of civil liberties; and the extension
and Perroti 1993), nor use otherindicators of govemrnentperformance, such as those generated
chosenthe civil and politicaldimensionsfor three reasons: they are at least plausiblyquantifiable,
accountability, openness, and the rule of law; and these same indicators of civil and political
- 11 -
liberties are increasingly being tested in cross-country growth regressions.
There is little international consensus on liberties that ought to be permitted. Moreover, when
those liberties about which there might exist some consensus are suppressed, it is almost always
done surreptitiously. That said, several large efforts have attempted to rank countries by degree
of civil liberties. In this study, we use data from three of these efforts:
* Freedom House19 (1994 and previous years) has constructed a ranking of civil liberties
for 165 countries from 1972 to 1994. This ranking--on a seven point scale--is based upon
the year 1985. This index, on a scale of zero to 100 (actual range is 13 to 98) was based
upon the definition of human rights adopted by the General Assembly of the United
Nations in 1966 under the International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights;
- 12 -
* Coppedge and Reinicke (1990) constructed five series on upolyarchy"22 in 170 countries
for the year 1985. We use "media pluralism" and 'freedom to organize' as indicators of
While each of these indices of civil liberties are subjective and debatable, their cross
correlationsare reasonably high, which creates some confidence that they measure the same thing
and do so reasonably well (althoughwe note that, since Coppedge and Reinicke used the Freedom
House and Humana studies in their own ranking procedure, part of the high correlation between
'
"The set of institutionalarrangementsthat permits public oppositionand establishesthe right to
participatein politics" (Coppedgeand Reinicke1990). The other series are 'fair elections","extensionof
suffrage",and "freedomof expression".We do notreport the resultson these series becausetheyeitherhave
lessvarianceand/orcapturepoliticafreedoms.Consistentwith reports reportedbelow on politicalindicators,
they are in no case statisticallysignificantacrossspecifications.
- 13 -
the lattertwo and former two series is by construction)3. However, we wish to stress that by
the rankingfor any particularcountry. Moreover, by using these numbers strictly for our cross-
Table 3 shows the results of including each of the measures of civil liberties in the project
performance regressions. There is a consistent, statisdcally significant and empirically large effect
measurement error variance for measurement A(B). If the measurement error variance is equal
a 5 thena correlationof .8 impliesthe ratio of measurementerror (noise)to the varianceof
(2
the true variable(signal), g is about .2.
- 14-
of civil liberties on the return to projects25. Taking the estimates from specificationD, if the
Rica for all evaluated years), the ERR is predicted to increase by 7.5 percentage points.
Similarly, with the estimatesusing the Humana index, improvingfrom the worst civil liberties
(13)to one of the best (91, as in CostaRica) would improvethe ERR by 22.5 percentage points.
Since these civil liberties indices are on a different scale, a more standard method for
comparisonis to calculatehow much the ERR is predictedto increaseif each index were improved
wouldraise the predictedERRby 1.6 points; a similar increasein the Humana index would raise
the ERR by 5.2 points; a standard deviation increase in "mediapluralism" would improve the
- 15 -
Table 3: Impact of civil liberties on project rates of return
Specificationa: Effect of
one std.
dev.
A B C D increase on
________
_________ _______ ~~~ERR
d:
with that problemin two ways. First, in additionto a Tobit specificationaccountingfor the lower
- 16 -
truncation,we truncatedthe ERRsabove at the more or less arbitrarylevelof a 50 percentrate of
Using only this rating as the measureof project performance allows a larger sampleof
projects, as social sectorprojectsthat normally do not receive an ERR are rated by OED'2.
Table 4 reports the estimatesof a Probit regression for specificationsC and D (results for A
and B were similar). Naturally,since the binary indicator discards a great deal of statistical
information, these results are less precise: the p-levels are lower, and the estimatesfor the
Humana ranking are insignificant. For the other variables, the estimatesshow large increases
in the likelihood of a good project when implementedunder higher civil liberties. For
2 The comparisonbetweenthe linear regressions and the Probit effects is complicated,but these
magnitudesare roughlysimilar. That is, if we created a dummyvariablefor 'unsatisfactory"based on the
ERR faiingbelowsomecriticallevel,thenthemarginalchangein probabilityof failurefromthe linear model
at a particularpoint (if the error term were normal) wouldbe PIo*o(.), where P is the slopecoefficient,o
- 17 -
Table 4: Impact of civil liberties on the probability of a project being rated as
satisfactory,using Probit regression.
Specification:
C D
Freedom House Civil (1 9 7 8 _9 0 )b .018c .022
N= 1155 (.056)d (.060)
Humana (1982-86) -.00067 .0012
N=604 (.589) (.388)
Media pluralism (1983-90) .022 .054
N=740 - (.296) (.045)
Freedom to organize (1983-90) .042 .040
N =740 (.009) (.085)
Notes: a) for descriptionof the specificationssee table 2, b) Annual values from 1978-87
while for the other three indicesare single values for the listed time period; c) the value
reported is not the Probit coefficient,but the marginal change in the probabilityof a
successfulproject as the variablechanges, evaluated at the means of all independent
variables; d) p-levels of the test that the Probit coefficient is zero in parenthesis.
Source: Authors' calculations
striking. Yet the interpretationof this partial correlation is problematic: it may well be that
some countryconditions causeboth greater civil liberties and better projects. We argue in two
ways that the results suggesta causativeeffect from better civil liberties to better project
- 18 -
implementingofficials are both key elementsof project success: both of these facets of
performance. Second, we show that the data between manifestationsof civil strife and project
projects is key to their success(e.g. World Bank 1995). Myriad case studies (e.g., Korten and
Isham, Narayan, and Pritchett (1995)use data from 121 water projects to show that greater
of civil liberties. At least six of the 14 elementsof the Freedom House civil rightsindex, for
projects is the degree to which the public sector officials are held accountablefor their
- 19 -
performance. For an extreme instance, Dreze and Sen (1991), in their study of famines
elaborateon the fact that no major famine has ever happened in a country with a free press.
are rare, but suggest that the degree to which public sector employees are responsibleis an
officials are facilitatedby an environmentin which basic civil liberties--suchas the freedom to
speak out and the ability of groups to organize to protect and advance their interests--are
recognized.
performanceis a chain that runs from civil liberties through indicators of civil unrest to project
positively correlated with project performance. This finding at first seems paradoxical, but we
show that greater civil libertiesare associatedwith higher values of these civil strife indicators
and that, controllingfor the degree of civil liberties, there is little additional impacton project
performance.
average much higher levels of civil unrest. When we sort countries into groups based in their
- 20 -
average ERR, we find countries in the 'high ERR' category had average rates of return twice
as high as those countries in the "low ERR" category. Interestingly, these high ERR countries
had many more riots, demonstrations and strikes per capita (adjusted for population effects)
Notes: a) ERR categories are determined by average rates of return classified by country for all
countries with at least 10 projects over the period from 1974-1987.
Source: Autifors' calculations
- 21 -
That greater civil unrest is associated with better projects appearsat first to be
However, all the projectsin this analysis are financed by governmentsand, unlike in the
private sector, civil unrest does not create the same kind of risks for performance. By
contrast, there may be a channel whereby civil tension leads to better project choice and
for the monitoringof the performanceof government agents in carrying out their functions It
may be that with more open channels, all forms of expressionof popular will--includingcivil
unrest--are greater.
What is the relationshipbetween the indices of civil libertiesand riots, strikes, and
demonstrations? Table 6 shows that for all indicators except for Humana, greater civil
- 22 -
Table 6: Correlationsbetweenindices of civil liberties and civil unrest
Civil unrest
(all variablesadjusted for populationeffects)'
Civil liberties
indicator Riots Demonstrations Strikes
Table 7 uses the same regressionbase specification as above and showsthat there is, if
return. Projects apparentlydo better in environments with greater civil strife when civil
- 23 -
riots). However, with the additionof any of the indicators of the degree of civil liberties29 ,
riots falls from 0.56 to 0.32 in specificationA. That is, for any given level of civil liberties,
neither riots nor strikesare associatedwith better performance, but protest demonstrations
The results support a chain of causation that runs from greater civil libertiesto higher
is not to suggest that civil unrest is itself the mechanism: it is more likely that environmentsin
which civil unrest is possibleare also those in which other mechanismsfor expressionof
9 Only the FreedomHousecivil indicatoris shown in table 8, but the resultsfor the other three are
similar.
- 24 -
Table 7: Indicators of civil unrest and project returns, without and with
controls for civil liberties.
Specificationa:
A C D
| with
without with without with Freedom
Freedom Freedom House
House House
Adding just riots
Riots 0.56 0.32 0.42 0.21 -0.34
(0.062) (0.148) (0.040) (0.34) (0.245)
Freedom House 1.48 - 1.51 1.19
Civil (0.090) (0.093) l (.083)
Adding just protest demonstrations
Protest 1.04 0.88 0.81 0.68 0.17
demonstrations (0.0001) (0.014) (0.003) (0.013) (0.607)
Freedom House - 1.46 - 1.48 1.08
Civil (0.053) (0.006) (.112)
Adding just political strikes
Political strikes 1.58 0.201 1.67 0.45 -0.81
(0.127) (0.857) (0.097) (0.683) (0.520)
Freedom House 1.77 1.61 1.09
Civil (0.002) (0.006 I 09)
Adding all three civil strife variables
F-testcfor all three 4.39 3.66 2.69 2.30 1.09
indicatorswithout (0.004) (0.012) (0.045) (0.076) (0.352)
and with civil l
liberties _ l l l __ _
Notes: a) for a description of the specificationssee table 2; b) p-levels in
parenthesis;c) F-tests calculatedwith and without all three indicators. Samplesize
= 649.
Source: Authors' calculations.
- 25 -
TV) Political regime tye political liberties and project performance
Civil and political liberties are undoubtedly associated with each other and with
two types of liberties and the type of political regime: for example, the degree of civil and
political liberties varies widely among non-democracies. Therefore, finding that more civil
liberties are associated with better ERRs does not imply that different types of political regimes
are associated with better performance. To try to disentangle these relationships, we test for
the possible association between ERRs and these two related aspects of governance: political
A) Political liberties
The most widely used measure of political liberties is an index also published by
Freedom House, based on 11 indicators of political rights3 0 . Like the ranking of civil
liberties is the index of human rights violations (IHRV) constructed by Pourgerami (1988),
based on reports of Amnesty International on the extent of human rights abuses for the years
- 26 -
1984-86. It takes a value of 4 for the least and 1 for the most human rights abuses31.
_________ A B C D
Freedom House (Political)b 1.16 -.016 1.05 -. 115
(N=649) (.0087)c (.977) (.026) (.840)
Index of Human Rights Violations(IHRV) (N=425)
Dummy variablefor each level of violations (default is most violations, IHR' 1)
iIHRV=2 5.46 3.33 4.23 2.92
(.018) (.193) (.078) (.292)
IHRV=3 0.08 1.66 1.30 3.04
(.974) (.534) (.586) (.310)
IHRV=4 (least violations) 0.90 3.96 4.87 7.83
l _____________________ (.788) (.297) (.154) (.045)
Notes: a) for descriptionof the specifications see table 2; b) Annual values from 1978-
1987. IHRV is a single value extrapolated to cover 1980-1986;c) p-levels in parenthesis.
Source: Authors' calculations
The results reported in table 8 do not show any strikingpositive impact of purely
political rights on ERR. The Freedom House index shows a significantpositive effect in the
least demandingspecification(A), but whereas civil libertiesis robust, the political result is
The index of human rights violations (IHRV) similarlydoes not show any clear pattern
effect, the result is highly non-robust and appears to be driven by a few observationswith very
- 27 -
high ERRs33. Besidesthe possibledistinction between the top and the bottom, the results show
with the second to worst amountof violations (IHRV = 2) do better than countrieswith the
most violations, they also do much better than countries with an even better record (e.g. 5.46
for RV=2 versus 0.08 for IHRV=3 in specification A) and about as well as those with the
best record (e.g., 3.33 for IHRV=2 versus 3.96 for IHRV=4 in specificationB). Therefore,
while there is some mild evidencethat it is better not to be in the worst group, there are no
These weak results on the importance of civil liberties are the result of introducingthe
political variable into the base specificationwithout any indicatorof civil liberties. If we ask
what the effect of politicallibertiesare, conditional on the level of civil libertieswe find that
the civil liberties indicatorsretain all of their iInportancewhile the FreedomHouse political
liberties variable producesweak,or even results which suggesta greater level of political
liberties, holding civil libertiesconstant, worsens project performance. Table 9 shows that,
controllingfor civil libertiesraising political liberties actually reduces the ERR. While not too
much shouldbe read into these results (as the multicollinearityproblemsinvolvedwith the
and the Informal Sector (IRIS)and labeled here as the 'IRIS Indicator of RegimeType'
democracy; transition regime, partial autocracy; and autocracy (IIRT= 1). Matchedwith our
include a dummy variablefor each type. The second indicator, constructedby Alberto
Alesina et. al. (Alesinaet al. 1992) and labeled here the "AlesinaDemocracyIndex"(ADI), is
- 29 -
three. We use the annualobservationsfrom 1974-1982for 48 countries.
The results from includingthese either of these two measures of politicalregime type in
countriesby IIRT, the "autocracy",tends to have a lower ERR than other categories(as
evidencedby the positive signs for most of the others). In specificationsA and C (without
regional dunmmies),IRT categories3 and 5 (most democratic) tend to have higher returns,
Using the ADI, we also find in specificationsA and C some weak evidencethat more
democraticregimes tend to have higher returns, but this is reversed by the inclusionof
regional controls.
Moreover, except for a comparisonbetween the "best" and "worst" regimetype, there
is no clear pattern to the results. For instance, the increment to returns over the autocraciesis
nearly as high when IIRT=3 as when IIRT=5, and countries with IIRT=4 (partial
democracy)are predicted to have an ERR lower by 3.4 percentage points than even
autocracies. The most democratic(ADI= 1) countries are also predicted in specificationD (at
- 30 -
Table 10: Returns and politicalregime type.
Specificationa:
A B IC D
IRIS Indicator of Regime Type (IIRT) (1 9 7 4 -1 98 7 b; N=725)
Dummy variable by regime t ipe (default is least democratic, IIRT= 1)
IIRT=2 -0.48 -0.56 0.24 0.49
(.767) (.733) (.885) (.766)
IIRT=3 5.46 1.61 3.52 1.04
(.107) (.636) (.296) (.757)
IIRT=4 -0.076 -3.68 -0.82 -3.35
(.967) (. 058) (.657) (.091)
IIRT=5 (most democratic) 3.94 0.322 4.17 0.458
(.055) (.892) (.043) (.847)
Alesina democracy index (ADI) ( 19 7 4 - 19 8 2 b; N=369)
Dummy variable by democ level, default is least democratic (ADI=3)
ADI=2 3.10 2.86 2.38 2.41
(.225) (.257) (0.349) (.345)
ADI= 1 (most democratic) 2.93 -1.27 1.93 -1.52
1 (.117) (.542) (.311) (.465)
Notes: a) for description of the variables includedin each specification see table 2; b)
Annual values for time period; c) p-levels in parenthesis.
Source: Authors' calculations.
In summary, there is no clear pattern that suggests that countries with more democratic
The very least democratic countriesperhaps do more poorly than others, but movingtowards a
democracyfrom other levels not have any empiricallydiscernible impact on project returns.
- 31 -
C) Other liter2ntre political freedomand performance
These ambiguous findings roughly agree with other assessments of the degree of
examines the impact of "democracy" on aggregate growth (e.g. Weede 1983, Scully 1988,
Helliwell 1992, Barro 1994, Bhalla 1994, see Alesina and Perotti, 1994 for a review), much
of which uses the Freedom House index of political liberties3 5 as the measure of democracy.
While it is quite difficult to reconcile the strikingly different findings of these papers, in spite
of the fact they use almost identical dependent variables (economic growth) and measures of
political freedom, we think a fair summary of the current state of the macro level literature on
First, higher levels of income are associated with higher levels of the Freedom House
index of political liberties. Second, when some covariates are added, the level of the Freedom
House index of political liberties does not have independent explanatory power for growth of
per capita income. Third, controlling for reverse causation--from economic growth (hence
higher levels of income) to political liberties--reduces the estimated effect of political liberties
on growth. Fourth, the effect of political liberties on growth seems to be non-linear, the
middle levels of the index (e.g East Asia) have higher levels of growth than either very low
(e.g. OECD) or very high (e.g. Africa) levels. Fifth, as with nearly all growth regressions, a
great deal depends on how the newly industrializing economies of East Asia are treated. This
3 Or the sumof the two FreedomHouse indicators. Two other studies-(Kormendiand Meguire1985,
Greir and Tullock 1989)-use dummiesbased on the FreedomHouse civil index in cross-countrygrowth
regressions.
- 32 -
is especiallyimnportant
for politicalquestions, as the East Asian countries were by and large
better performanceon World Bank-financedprojects, and purely political libertiesand the type
interpreted?
what they are an indicatorof. Since the World Bank financesonly a fraction of aid-financed
implementedprojects a proxy for overall governmentefficacy? More broadly, does the return
projectcune
A) Are IRank among aid project?9
There is little reason to believe that World Bank-financedprojects are chosen very
selectionprocess for projects at the World Bank is biased in such a way as to produce results
for a relationshipbetweenprojects and governance that would not apply to projects of other
- 33 -
donors.
R) Cinvernmentperfnrmrnice?
The more difficultand important questions is whether the ERRs of World Bank-
fmanced projects indicatea degree of the efficacy of governmentacross countries. There are
On the one hand, sinceall countries are treated alike by the World Bank in terms of
do reflect countryspecific,rather than Bank specific factors. The Bank is quite centralized
been exogenouswith respectto the variables we are considering. Together, these factors
suggestthat differencesin ERRs across countries probably do not reflect large differencesin
On the other hand, this cannot be established. Countrieschoose whichof their possible
- 34 -
set of projects to financethroughthe World Bank. This choice may involve'cream skimming"
differs across countries, the average return across countries cannotbe interpretedas reflecting
governmentperformance.
various measures are not significantlycorrelated with the ERRs in our data set: they are not
good measures of the samething. It is possible that these private sector ratings are flawed
- 35 -
Q Are projects retimq a
2proxy for overall returns tn invertment?
premia--onproject performance(Isham and Kaufmann 1995), it has been arguedthat the ERRs
performance. How closelyrelated are overall returns to capital and these ERRs? This is
Suppose that growth of outputper worker can be decomposedinto the growthof capitalper
y = ak*k
where lower case letters representper worker and the "dot" representsthe percentagetime rate
=r*K
ky
We typically do not observe r, the return on capital. However, we hypothesizethat r for each
country I varies systematicallyacross countries with the observed rate of return on projects,
ERR:
ri = r + P *ERRi
- 36 -
= r* * + *ERR*( f) *k
so that the first term identifiesthe average rate of return to capital and the secondparameter
the impact of an increase in ERR on the overall return to capital. The results of estimating
this equationusing cross nationaldata are presented in table 11. The estimatedaveragereturn
varies between 10.2 and 17.8 percent, a reasonable range of values. The impact of ERR on
the overall rate of return is between0.44 and 1.08 (with just two countries excluded). The
estimates suggest that the return on Bank projects, the ERR is related one-for-oneto the
economy-widerate of return which suggestsit is a very good proxy for overall investment
performance. This small piece of econometricevidence fortifies the argumentsin earlier work
extremelysevere. With just two variables, over 50 percent of the overall growthrate variance
estimates of each term individuallyare very imprecise and cannot reject zero (or any other
value for that matter) for the the individualterms. We are obviously not happywith this, but
see no solution.
- 37 -
Table 11: Relationshipof overall returns to capital and the country averageof project
rates of return (ERR).
Unweighted Weightedby numberof
projectsa
N 39 37 39 37
Notes: a) observationsare weightedby the square root of the number of projects, b) the two
outliers excludedare Syria and Pakistan, c) standard errors in parentheses,d) R-squaredof
the unweighteddependent variable.
Source: Authors' calculations.
Cnnclusimn
No one would pretendthat the degree of civil or political liberties or the choice of
benefits. What is often meant by the definition of 'human rights" are exactlythose elements
additionalpiece of evidence for the view that increasingpublic voice and accountability--
- 38 -
through both participationand better governance--canlead to greater efficacyin government
On the other hand, the empirical evidence does not provide evidenceof a relationship
against). This merely suggestswith microeconomicdata that which is known from aggregate
- 39 -
References
Alesina, Alberto, Sule Ozler, Nouriel Roubini and Philip Swagel. 1992. "PoliticalInstability
and EconomicGrowth." NBER Working Paper No. 4173 (September). Cambridge,
Mass.: NationalBureau of Economic Research.
Barro, Robert. 1994. "Democracyand Growth." NBER WorkingPaper No. 4909 (October).
Cambridge,Mass.: National Bureau of EconomicResearch.
Dreze, Jean and AmartyaSen. 1989. Hunger and Public Action. New York: Oxford
UniversityPress
Gastil, Raymond. 1987. Freedomin the World: PoliticalRights and CivilLiberties. New
York: GreenwoodPress.
Greene, WilliamH. 1981, "On the Asymptotic Bias of the OrdinaryLeast Squares Estimator
of the Tobit Model."Econometrica, 49, 3: 505-513.
- 40 -
Working Paper No. 4066 (May). Cambridge, Mass.: NationalBureauof Economic
Research.
1995. "The Forgotten Rationale for Policy Reform" Background paper for
WorldDevelopmentReport 1991. Washington: The World Bank.
Kaufmann, Daniel and Yan Wang, 1995. "MacroeconomicPolicies and Project Performance
in the Social Sectors." WorldDevelopment 23(5):751-765.
Little, I.M.D. and J.A. Mirrlees. 1991. "Project Appraisal and Planning TwentyYears On."
Proceedingsof the WorldBank Annual Conferenceon DevelopmentEconomics1990.
351-82.
- 41 -
---------------. 1994. "Does VoiceMatter?" Policy Research Working Paper No. 1388.
Finance and Private Sector Division, the World Bank.
---------------. 1996. "A Citizen Report Card on Public Services: Mixing Barks and Bites?"
Mimeo.
Squire, Lyn and Herman van der Tak. 1975. EconomicAnalysis of Projects. Baltimore:
Johns Hopkins Press.
1993. Annual Evaluation Results for 1991. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
- 42 -
. 1994. World Development Report 1994. New York: Oxford University
Press.
- 43 -
AppendixTable A. 1: Summary statistics of independentvariablesa
Variable
nameb
1Mean
|
| Standard
Deviation
Range
(Possible)
Number of
countries
1Years
A) Civil liberties
Freedom 4.68 1.47 (1 to 7) 56 1974-1990
House
(Civil) _
-44-
Policy Research Working Paper Series
Contact
Title Author Date for paper
WPS1531 Some New Evidence on Determinants Harinder Singh November 1995 S. King-Watson
of Foreign Direct Investment in Kwang W. Jun 31047
Developing Countries
WPS1532 Regulation and Bank Stability: Michael Bordo November 1995 D. Evans
Canada and the United States, 38526
1870-1980
WPS1533 Universal Banking and the Charles W. Calomiris November 1995 D. Evans
Financing of Industrial Development 38526
WPS1534 The Evolution of General Banking Forest Capie November 1995 D. Evans
38526
WPS1535 Financial History: Lessons of the Gerard Caprio, Jr. November 1995 D. Evans
Past for Reformers of the Present Dimitri Vittas 38526
WPS1536 Free Banking: The Scottish Randall iroszner November 1995 D. Evans
Experience as a Model for Emerging 38526
Economies
WPS1537 Before Main Banks: A Selective Frank Packer November 1995 D. Evans
Historical Overview of Japan's 38526
Prewar Financial System
WPS1539 The Rise of Securities Markets: Richard Sylla November 1995 D. Evans
What Can Government Do? 38526
WPS1540 Thrift Deposit Institutions in Europe Dimitri Vittas November 1995 P. Infante
and the United States 37642
WPS1543 The Combined Incidence of Taxes Shantayanan Devarajan November 1995 C. Bernardo
and Public Expenditures in the Shaikh I. Hossain 37699
Philippines
Contact
Title Author Date for paper
WPS1547 Testing the Induced innovation Colin Thirtle November 1995 M. Williams
Hypothesis in South African Robert Townsend 87297
Agriculture (An Error Correction Johan van Zyl
Approach
WPS1548 The Relationship Between Farm Size Johan van Zyl November 1995 M. Williams
and Efficiency in South African Hans Binswanger 87297
Agriculture Colin Thirtle
WPS1549 The Forgotten Rationale for Policy Jonathan Isham November 1995 S. Torres
Reform. The Productivity cf Daniel Kautman 39012
Investment Projects