Introduction to JavaScript Programming with XML and PHP 1st Edition Drake Solutions Manual instant download
Introduction to JavaScript Programming with XML and PHP 1st Edition Drake Solutions Manual instant download
https://testbankfan.com/product/introduction-to-javascript-programming-
with-xml-and-php-1st-edition-drake-solutions-manual/
https://testbankfan.com/product/introduction-to-javascript-
programming-with-xml-and-php-1st-edition-drake-test-bank/
https://testbankfan.com/product/comprehensive-introduction-to-object-
oriented-programming-with-java-1st-edition-wu-solutions-manual/
https://testbankfan.com/product/introduction-to-programming-with-
java-2nd-edition-dean-solutions-manual/
https://testbankfan.com/product/world-history-before-1600-the-
development-of-early-civilization-volume-i-5th-edition-upshur-test-
bank/
https://testbankfan.com/product/living-religions-10th-edition-fisher-
test-bank/
https://testbankfan.com/product/essentials-of-nursing-leadership-and-
management-6th-edition-weiss-test-bank/
https://testbankfan.com/product/criminal-law-1st-edition-russell-
brown-test-bank/
https://testbankfan.com/product/contemporary-marketing-3rd-edition-
boone-solutions-manual/
International Business The Challenges of Globalization 8th
Edition Wild Test Bank
https://testbankfan.com/product/international-business-the-challenges-
of-globalization-8th-edition-wild-test-bank/
Checkpoint Solutions
6.6 A CGI script is a program that tells the computer what to do with form data that is sent to it. It is
stored on a web server, in a cgi-bin folder.
6.7 All the names are different. For a radio button group to work, each button must have the same name as
the others.
6.8 function checkIt()
{ document.getElementById("agree").checked = true }
6.9 Textboxes can only have widths configured; textarea boxes can be set to however many rows
and columns are desired.
6.10
<html><head><title>Checkpoint 6.10</title>
<script>
function firstName(name)
{
var fname = document.getElementById(name).value;
document.getElementById('f_name').innerHTML = fname;
}
function lastName(name)
{
var lname = document.getElementById(name).value;
document.getElementById('l_name').innerHTML = lname;
}
</script>
</head>
<body>
<p>Enter your first name:<br />
<input type="text" name="firstname" size = "30" maxlength = "28"
id="firstname">
<input type ="button" onclick="firstName('firstname')" value =
"ok"></button></p>
<p>Enter your last name:<br />
<input type="text" name="lastname" size = "30" maxlength = "29"
id="lastname">
<input type ="button" onclick="lastName('lastname')" value =
"ok"></button></p>
<h3>Your first name: <span id = "f_name"> </span> </h3>
<h3>Your last name: <span id = "l_name"> </span> </h3>
</body></html>
6.11
<form name="myform" method="post" enctype="text/plain" action =
"mailto:[email protected]?Here is the requested
information&[email protected]">
6.12 Each control in the email is identified by its name. The user's selection is listed by the form
control's value.
Checkpoint for Section 6.3
6.13 answers will vary
6.14 add to web page <body>:
<input type ="hidden" name ="sides" id ="sides" value = "add lemon wedge
with salmon, ketchup with fries, dressing with salad " />
6.17
<script>
function showWord(pword)
{
var username = document.getElementById(pword).value;
var nameLength = username.length;
var charOne = username.substr(0,1);
var charEnd = username.substr((nameLength - 1),1);
var middleLength = nameLength - 2;
var middle = "";
for (i = 0; i <= middleLength; i++)
middle = middle + "*";
var word = charOne + middle + charEnd;
alert(word);
}
</script>
</head>
<body>
<h3> Enter a password in the box below. </h3>
<p><input type="password" name="user_pwrd" id="passwrd" size =
""/>
<input type ="button" onclick="showWord('passwrd')" value =
"ok"></button></p>
</body>
6.18
<script>
function checkAmp(pword)
{
var checkSpecial = false;
var pword = document.getElementById(pword).value;
var nameLength = pword.length;
for (i = 1; i <= (nameLength - 1); i++)
{
if (pword.charCodeAt(i) == 38)
checkSpecial = true;
}
if (checkSpecial == false)
alert("You don't have an ampersand (&) in your password.");
else
alert("Ampersand (&) found!");
}
</script>
</head>
<body>
<h3> Enter a password in the box below. </h3>
<p><input type="password" name="user_pwrd" id="passwrd" size = ""/>
<input type ="button" onclick="checkAmp('passwrd')" value =
"ok"></button></p>
</body>
Title: The Problem of the Rupee, Its Origin and Its Solution
Creator: B. R. Ambedkar
Language: English
BY
B. R. AMBEDKAR
Sometime Professor of Political Economy at the Sydenham College of
Commerce and Economics, Bombay.
LONDON
P. S. KING & SON, LTD.
ORCHARD HOUSE, 2 & 4 GREAT SMITH STREET
WESTMINSTER
1923
DEDICATED
TO THE MEMORY OF
MY
Printed in Great Britain by Butler & Tanner Ltd., Frome and London
PREFACE
[pg xi]
FOREWORD
Contents
Author's Preface
Foreword by Professor Edwin Cannan
From a Double Standard to a Silver Standard
The Silver Standard and the Dislocation of its Parity
The Silver Standard and the Evils of Its Instability
Towards a Gold Standard
From A Gold Standard to a Gold Exchange Standard
Stability of the Exchange Standard
A Return to the Gold Standard
[pg 1]
THE PROBLEM OF THE RUPEE
CHAPTER I
Trade is an important apparatus in a society based on private property and pursuit of individual gain;
without it, it would be difficult for its members to distribute the specialised products of their labour.
Surely a lottery or an administrative device would be incompatible with its nature. Indeed, if it is to
preserve its character, the only mode for the necessary distribution of the products of separate industry
is that of private trading. But a trading society is unavoidably a pecuniary society, a society which of
necessity carries on its transactions in terms of money. In fact, the distribution is not primarily an
exchange of products against products, but products against money. In such a society, money therefore
necessarily becomes the pivot on which everything revolves. With money as the focusing-point of all
human efforts, interests, desires and ambitions, a trading society is bound to function in a régime of
price where successes and failures are results of nice calculations of price-outlay as against price-
product.
Economists have no doubt insisted that “there cannot … be intrinsically a more significant thing
than money,” which at best is only “a great wheel by means of which every individual in society has his
subsistence, conveniences and amusements regularly distributed to him [pg 2] in their proper
proportions.” Whether or not money values are the definitive terms of economic endeavour may well be
open to discussion.1 But this much is certain, that without the use of money this “distribution of
subsistence, conveniences and amusements,“ far from being a matter of course, will be distressingly
hampered if not altogether suspended. How can this trading of products take place without money? The
difficulties of barter have ever formed an unfailing theme with all economists, including those who have
insisted that money is only a cloak. Money is not only necessary to facilitate trade by obviating the
difficulties of barter, but is also necessary to sustain production by permitting specialisation. For who
would care to specialise if he could not trade his products for those of others which he wanted? Trade is
the handmaid of production, and where the former cannot flourish the latter must languish. It is
therefore evident that if a trading society is not to be out of gear and is not to forego the measureless
advantages of its automatic adjustments in the great give-and-take of specialised industry, it must
provide itself with a sound system of money.2
At the close of the Moghul Empire, India, judged by the standards of the time, was economically an
advanced country. Her trade was large, her banking institutions were well developed, and credit played
an appreciable part in her transactions. But a medium of exchange and a common standard of value
were among others the most supreme desiderata in the economy of the Indian people when they came,
in the middle of the eighteenth century, under the sway of the British. Before the occurrence of this
event, the money of India consisted of both gold and silver. Under the Hindu emperors the emphasis
was laid on gold, while under the Mussalmans silver formed a large [pg 3] part of the circulating
medium.3 Since the time of Akbar, the founder of the economic system of the Moghul Empire in India,
the units of currency had been the gold mohur and the silver rupee. Both coins, the mohur and the
rupee, were identical in weight, i.e. 175 grs. troy,4 and were “supposed to have been coined without
any alloy, or at least intended to be so.”5 But whether they constituted a single standard of value or not
is a matter of some doubt. It is believed that the mohur and the rupee, which at the time were the
common measure of value, circulated without any fixed ratio of exchange between them. The standard,
therefore, was more of the nature of what Jevons called a parallel standard6 than a double standard.7
That this want of ratio could not have worked without some detriment in practice is obvious. But it must
be noted that there existed an alleviating circumstance in the curious contrivance by which the mohur
and the rupee, though unrelated to each other, bore a fixed ratio to the dam, the copper coin of the
Empire.8 So that it is permissible to hold that, as a consequence of being fixed to the same thing, the
two, the mohur and the rupee, circulated at a fixed ratio.
In Southern India, to which part the influence of the [pg 4] Moghuls had not extended, silver as a
part of the currency system was quite unknown. The pagoda, the gold coin of the ancient Hindu kings,
was the standard of value and also the medium of exchange, and continued to be so till the time of the
East India Company.
The right of coinage, which the Moghuls always held as inter jura Majestatis,9 be it said to their
credit was exercised with due sense of responsibility. Never did the Moghul Emperors stoop to debase
their coinage. Making allowance for the imperfect technology of coinage, the coins issued from the
various Mints situated even in the most distant parts of their Empire10 did not materially deviate from
the standard.
Weight Weight
Name of the Rupee in pure Name of the Rupee in pure
Grs. Grs.
[pg 5] The table on p. 4 of the assays of the Moghul rupees shows how the coinage throughout the
period of the Empire adhered to the standard weight of 175 grs. pure.11
So long as the Empire retained unabated sway there was advantage rather than danger in the
plurality of Mints, for they were so many branches of a single department governed by a single
authority. But with the disruption of the Moghul Empire into separate kingdoms these branches of the
Imperial Mint located at different centres became independent factories for purposes of coinage. In the
general scramble for independence which followed the fall of the Empire, the right to coinage, as one of
the most unmistakable insignia of sovereignty, became the right most cherished by the political
adventurers of the time. It was the last privilege to which the falling dynasties clung, and was also the
first to which the adventurers rising to power aspired. The result was that the right, which was at one
time so religiously exercised, came to be most wantonly abused. Everywhere the Mints were kept in full
swing, and soon the country was filled with diverse coins which, while they proclaimed the incessant
rise and fall of dynasties, also presented bewildering media of exchange. If these money-mongering
sovereigns had kept up their issues to the original standard of the Moghul Emperors the multiplicity of
coins of the same denomination would not have been a matter of much concern. But they seemed to
have held that as the money used by their subjects was made by them, they could do what they liked
with their own, and proceeded to debase their coinage to the extent each chose without altering the
denominations. Given the different degrees of debasement, the currency necessarily lost its primary
quality of general and ready acceptability.
The evils consequent upon such a situation may well be imagined. When the contents of the coins
belied the value indicated by their denomination they became mere merchandise and there was no
more a currency by tale to act as a ready means of exchange. The bullion value of each coin had to be
ascertained before it could be accepted as a final [pg 6] discharge of obligations.12 The opportunity for
defrauding the poor and the ignorant thus provided could not have been less13 than that known to have
obtained in England before the great re-coinage of 1696. This constant weighing, valuing, and assaying
the bullion contents of coins was, however, only one aspect in which the evils of the situation made
themselves felt. They also presented another formidable aspect. With the vanishing of the Empire there
ceased to be such a thing as an Imperial legal tender current all through India. In its place there grew
up local tenders current only within the different principalities into which the Empire was broken up.
Under such circumstances exchange was not liquidated by obtaining in return for wares the requisite
bullion value from the coins tendered in payment. Traders had to be certain that the coins were also
legal tender of their domicile. The Preamble to the Bengal Currency Regulation XXXV, of 1793, is
illuminating on this point. It says:—
Welcome to our website – the perfect destination for book lovers and
knowledge seekers. We believe that every book holds a new world,
offering opportunities for learning, discovery, and personal growth.
That’s why we are dedicated to bringing you a diverse collection of
books, ranging from classic literature and specialized publications to
self-development guides and children's books.
testbankfan.com