0% found this document useful (0 votes)
10 views35 pages

Topic 3 Equilibrium and Elasticities

The document outlines key concepts in microeconomics, including demand and supply functions, market equilibrium, and the effects of government intervention such as price floors and ceilings. It discusses the elasticity of demand, detailing how it varies along the demand curve and how it responds to changes in price and income. Additionally, it covers other forms of elasticity, such as income elasticity and cross-price elasticity, providing examples and formulas for calculation.

Uploaded by

harshitagre2005
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
10 views35 pages

Topic 3 Equilibrium and Elasticities

The document outlines key concepts in microeconomics, including demand and supply functions, market equilibrium, and the effects of government intervention such as price floors and ceilings. It discusses the elasticity of demand, detailing how it varies along the demand curve and how it responds to changes in price and income. Additionally, it covers other forms of elasticity, such as income elasticity and cross-price elasticity, providing examples and formulas for calculation.

Uploaded by

harshitagre2005
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 35

Principles of Microeconomics

Prof. Balu Pawde


GIPE, Pune
[email protected]
Review

• A closer look at demand: Demand curve and demand function


• Digressions on functions, marginal thinking and derivatives

• A closer look at supply: Supply curve and supply function


Market Equilibrium, shapes of curves & elasticities
Equilibrium
• Equilibrium: all traders are able to buy or sell as much as they want
• A situation in which no participant wants to change its behavior.
• Graphical: Supply & demand jointly determine equilibrium 𝑃 & 𝑄 (Diagram)
• Intersection e

• Equations. Idea is at e we need 𝑄𝑑 = 𝑄𝑠 = 𝑄


• Demand function: Qd = 12 − 𝑝
• Supply function: Qs = 9 + 0.5𝑝
• At e, 12 − 𝑝 = 9 + 0.5𝑝 i.e. 𝑝 = 2
So, 𝑝 = 2 is the equim. price.

• What is equim. 𝑄𝑒 ?
Substituting 𝑝 = 2 in either 𝑄𝑑 or 𝑄𝑠 will give 𝑄𝑒
Qe = 12 − 𝑝 = 12 − 2 = 10 Qe = 10
Equilibrium

• When in equilibrium,
• One can buy as many units of a good Pe
- Evidence that market is in equilibrium.

• Sellers don’t make explicit attempts for


equilibrium - invisible hand

• Disequilibrium at all prices other than Pe


Govt. intervention & equilibrium
• Interventions: Price floors & price ceilings
• Price floor:
• Govt. regulates P by setting P > Pe

• Example: Minimum wage regulation


y-axis = wages (P) & x-axis = hours of labour (Q)
• 𝑤 > 𝑤 ∗ , not allowed to go below 𝑤

• At floor price 𝑤 there is excess supply


- Meaning unemployment in this case
• w/o intervention, no excess supply – market clears

• What if 𝑤 < 𝑤 ∗ ?
Govt. intervention & equilibrium
• Price ceiling:
• Price set s.t. can’t go above
• Example: Gas price ceiling
y-axis = price (P) & x-axis = quantity (Q)
• 𝑃ത < 𝑃2 , not allowed to go above 𝑃ത

• At ceiling price 𝑃ത there is excess demand

• Existence of excess demand does 2 damages:


• Lost efficiency: less trades made
- pie is not getting maximized
• Allocation problem: with excess demand,
who gets the gas?
Elasticities
• Elasticity = a summary measure of responsiveness of 𝑄𝑑 to change in influencing factors.

• Generally, a measure of responsiveness of DepVar w.r.t. IndepVar.


• E.g. in a demand function 𝑄𝑑 = 8.56 − 𝑃 − 0.3𝑃𝑠 + 0.1𝑌,
how 𝑄𝑑 responds to changes in either of three IndepVars

𝑃𝑒𝑟𝑐𝑒𝑛𝑡 𝑐ℎ𝑎𝑛𝑔𝑒 𝑖𝑛 𝑞𝑢𝑎𝑛𝑡𝑖𝑡𝑦 𝑑𝑒𝑚𝑎𝑛𝑑𝑒𝑑 %𝛥𝑄𝑑


• Elasticity of demand is defined as 𝜖𝑑 = =
𝑃𝑒𝑟𝑐𝑒𝑛𝑡 𝑐ℎ𝑎𝑛𝑔𝑒 𝑖𝑛 𝑝𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒 %𝛥𝑃
𝛥𝑄𝑑
𝑄𝑑 𝛥𝑄𝑑 𝑃
𝜖𝑑 = 𝛥𝑃 = ∗
𝛥𝑃 𝑄𝑑
𝑃
𝛥𝑄𝑑
Term looks familiar? Difference quotient? Derivative?
𝛥𝑃
Yes, the limit of this difference quotient is derivative & therefore 𝜖𝑑 can be written as
𝜕𝑄𝑑 𝑃
𝜖𝑑 = ∗
𝜕𝑃 𝑄𝑑
Elasticities
𝜕𝑄𝑑 𝑃
• Elasticity of demand: 𝜖𝑑 = ∗
𝜕𝑃 𝑄𝑑
• 𝜕 = partial derivative holding other variables constant in DD function

• Elasticity answers question:

“How much does 𝑄𝑑 fall in response to a 1% increase in 𝑃?”

• For a DD function 𝑄𝑑 = 𝑎 − 𝑏𝑝, to calculate 𝜖𝑑 , we need to know three things:


𝜕𝑄𝑑
1. The derivative ; 2. 𝑃 and finally 3. Qd
𝜕𝑃
𝜕𝑄𝑑 𝑃
Here, = −𝑏 and therefore the 𝜖𝑑 = −𝑏 ∗ for this function.
𝜕𝑃 𝑄𝑑
Elasticities
• Real world example (from Roberts and Schlenker (2013)):
• The DD function is: 𝑄𝑑 = 15.6 − 0.5𝑝,
what is elasticity of demand at 𝑝 = 7.2?
• Ans:
Elasticities
• Ans:
Remember, we need to know 3 things?

From given price, we can find 𝑄𝑑 by simple substitution:


𝜕𝑄𝑑
𝑄𝑑 = 15.6 − 0.5𝑝 = 15.6 − 0.5 ∗ 7.2 = 12, 𝑄𝑑 = 12 | 𝑝 = 7.2 And = −0.5
𝜕𝑃

Plugging these in elasticity formula gives us elasticity of demand


𝜕𝑄𝑑 𝑃 7.2
𝜖𝑑 = ∗ = (−0.5) ∗ − 0.3 So, 𝜖𝑑 = −0.3
𝜕𝑃 𝑄𝑑 12
• -ve sign illustrates law of demand.
• Interpretation: “a 1% increase in the price reduces the demand by -0.3%.”
Price elasticity along DD curve

• The 𝜖𝑑 along DD curve varies. Why?


𝜕𝑄𝑑 𝑃
Look at 𝜖𝑑 = ∗
𝜕𝑃 𝑄𝑑

• Slope is constant but others vary


• As 𝑃 ↑ (& 𝑄 ↓ following law of demand),
𝜖𝑑 becomes more -ve.

• So, though the slope is constant.


elasticity is not.
Price elasticity along DD curve
• Elasticity values: (DD function: 𝑄𝑑 = 𝑎 − 𝑏𝑃)
• Elasticity in 5 areas
1. 𝑃 = 0; 2. 𝑄 = 0; 3. Midpoint
4. Midpoint to 𝑄 = 0 and 5. Midpoint to P = 0

• Area 1: 𝑃 = 0 ; DD function hits quantity axis, with


𝑄𝑑 = 𝑎, 𝜖𝑑 = −𝑏 ∗ (0/𝑎) i.e 𝜖𝑑 = 0
- One end of the range of 𝜖𝑑
- Demand is perfectly inelastic
Like a steel rod, stretching - length does not change

• Area 2: Q = 0 ; DD function hits price axis at


𝑎/𝑏
𝑃 = 𝑎/𝑏, 𝜖𝑑 = −𝑏 ∗ = −𝑏 ∗ ∞ = −∞ i.e 𝜖𝑑 = −∞
0
- This is the toehr end of the range of 𝜖𝑑 . So 𝜖𝑑 = {−∞, 0}. Here, demand is perfectly elastic
Price elasticity along DD curve
• Area 3: Midpoint. (DD function: 𝑄𝑑 = 𝑎 − 𝑏𝑃)
DD function hits 𝑃 axis at P = 𝑎/𝑏; & 𝑄 axis at P = 0
𝑎
−0 𝑎
𝑏
Midpoint at 𝑃 = =
2 2𝑏 Area 2
similarly, at 𝑄𝑑 = (𝑎 − 0)/2 = 𝑎/2
𝑎 𝑎
so, the midpoint is at P = and Q = Area 4
2𝑏 2
𝑎
2𝑏
𝜖𝑑 = −𝑏 ∗ 𝑎 = −1 i.e 𝜖𝑑 = −1
2
- Demand is unitary elastic Area 3 Area 5

Area 1
• Area 4: Midpoint to 𝑄 = 0;
𝜖𝑑 < −1, Demand is relatively elastic
• Area 5: Midpoint to 𝑃 = 0;
0 > 𝜖𝑑 > −1, Demand is relatively inelastic
Price elasticity
• Horizontal DD curve: 𝜖𝑑 is perfectly elastic - small Δ in 𝑃 leads to huge Δ in 𝑄𝑑
• Vertical DD curve: 𝜖𝑑 is perfectly inelastic - small Δ in 𝑃 leads to no Δ in 𝑄𝑑  necessities
Other elasticities, income elasticity
• What about responsiveness of 𝑄𝑑 w.r.t change in other factors? Demand Function:
• Other factors: price of substitute, price of complement & income 𝑸𝒅 = 𝟖. 𝟓𝟔 − 𝒑 − 𝟎. 𝟑𝒑𝒔 + 𝟎. 𝟏𝒀
• We can find elasticities for these factors also

• Income elasticity of demand


• We know that increase in 𝒀 shifts DD curve
• If 𝑸𝒅 ↑ with 𝒀 ↑ ; the DD curve shifts to the right and
• If 𝑸𝒅 ↓ with 𝒀 ↑ ; the DD curve shifts to the left
• Responsiveness of 𝑸𝒅 to changes in 𝒀 => income elasticity of demand
𝛥𝑄𝑑
𝑃𝑒𝑟𝑐𝑒𝑛𝑡 𝑐ℎ𝑎𝑛𝑔𝑒 𝑖𝑛 𝑞𝑢𝑎𝑛𝑡𝑖𝑡𝑦 𝑑𝑒𝑚𝑎𝑛𝑑𝑒𝑑 %𝛥𝑄𝑑 𝑄𝑑 Δ𝑄𝑑 𝑌 𝜕𝑄𝑑 𝑌
𝜉= = | 𝜉= 𝛥𝑃 = ∗ = ∗
𝑃𝑒𝑟𝑐𝑒𝑛𝑡 𝑐ℎ𝑎𝑛𝑔𝑒 𝑖𝑛 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 %𝛥𝑌 Δ𝑌 𝑄 𝜕𝑌 𝑄
𝑃

• Income elasticity (𝜉) can be +ve, -ve & 0,

𝜉 > 0 if 𝑄𝑑 ↑ with 𝑌 ↑ ; 𝜉 < 0 if 𝑄𝑑 ↑ with 𝑌 ↑ ; & 𝜉 = 0 if 𝑄𝑑 = 𝑐𝑜𝑛𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑡 with 𝑌 ↑


Other elasticities, income elasticity
• Example: income elasticity of DD for 𝑸𝒅 = 𝟖. 𝟓𝟔 − 𝒑 − 𝟎. 𝟑𝒑𝒔 + 𝟎. 𝟏𝒀 at 𝑄 = 10, & 𝑌 = 35?

𝜕𝑄𝑑
What is for this function?
𝜕𝑌

𝜕𝑄𝑑 𝑌 𝜕𝑄𝑑 𝑌 35
𝜉= ∗ ; plugging the values we get 𝜉 = ∗ = 0.1 ∗ = 0.35
𝜕𝑌 𝑄 𝜕𝑌 𝑄 10
• +ve 𝜉 shows that 𝒀 ↑ causes the coffee demand to shift to right (i.e. increase in 𝑸𝒅 )

• Goods that are necessities have income elasticities near zero


• Goods that are luxuries have high income elasticities
Other elasticities, cross-price elasticity
• Responsiveness of 𝑸𝒅 of a good to change in other good’s 𝑷 Demand Function:
𝑸𝒅 = 𝟖. 𝟓𝟔 − 𝒑 − 𝟎. 𝟑𝒑𝒔 + 𝟎. 𝟏𝒀
𝛥𝑄𝑑
𝑄𝑑 𝜕𝑄𝑑 𝑃𝑠
𝜖𝑑𝑐𝑟 = 𝛥𝑃𝑠 = ∗
𝜕𝑃𝑠 𝑄
𝑃𝑠

• 𝜖𝑑𝑐𝑟 > 0 for substitutes: If 𝑃𝑠 ↑, the 𝑸𝒅 of the first good increases - curve shifts to right
• 𝜖𝑑𝑐𝑟 < 0 for compliments: If 𝑃𝑠 ↑, the 𝑸𝒅 of the first good decreases - curve shifts to left
• Example: Coffee & Sugar are compliments in 𝑸𝒅 = 𝟖. 𝟓𝟔 − 𝒑 − 𝟎. 𝟑𝒑𝒔 + 𝟎. 𝟏𝒀
𝜕𝑄𝑑 𝑃𝑠 𝜕𝑄𝑑
𝜖𝑑𝑐𝑟 = ∗ What is here ?
𝜕𝑃𝑠 𝑄𝑑 𝜕𝑃𝑠
0.2
At the original equilibrium 𝑄𝑑 = 10 & 𝑃𝑠 = 0.2 ; 𝜖𝑑𝑐𝑟 = −0.3 ∗ = −0.006
10
• Interpretation: as price of sugar increases by 1%, quantity demanded of coffee reduces by 0.006%

• The elasticities are important for business and policy decisions – examples?
Elasticity of supply
• Like DD, summarise information about responsiveness of supply to influencing factors – elasticity

%𝛥𝑄𝑠 𝛥𝑄𝑠 /𝑄𝑠 𝜕𝑄𝑠 𝑃


• Supply elasticity: 𝜂 = = = ∗
%𝛥𝑃 𝛥𝑃/𝑃 𝜕𝑃 𝑄
• So, if 𝜂 = 2, it means 1% increase in price leads to 2% increase in quantity supplied.

• Demand elasticity & supply elasticity are very similar except:


• Demand elasticity is movement along the demand curve

Supply elasticity is movement along the supply curve

%𝛥𝑄𝑠
• The difference is only the numerator in
%𝛥𝑃
Elasticity of supply
• Direction of 𝜂 depends on the slope of the supply curve

𝜕𝑄𝑠
• Upward sloping curve, > 0 and hence 𝜂 > 0
𝜕𝑃

𝜕𝑄𝑠
• Downward sloping curve, < 0 and hence 𝜂 < 0 (similar to demand curve)
𝜕𝑃

• Values:

• When 𝜂 = 0, the supply curve is perfectly inelastic.

• 0 < 𝜂 < 1 is relatively inelastic - as price changes by 1% , change in quantity is less than 1%.

• 𝜂 > 1 the supply curve is relatively elastic

• 𝜂 = ∞ the supply curve is perfectly elastic


Elasticity of supply
• Example:
• Supply function for coffee 𝑄𝑠 = 9.6 + 0.5𝑝 − 0.2𝑝𝑐 . What is elasticity at 𝑝 = 2 given 𝑝𝑐 = 3 is constant

%𝛥𝑄𝑠 𝛥𝑄𝑠 /𝑄𝑠 𝜕𝑄𝑠 𝑃 2


Ans: 𝜂 = = = ∗ = 0.5 ∗ = 0.1
%𝛥𝑃 𝛥𝑃/𝑃 𝜕𝑃 𝑄𝑠 10

• Interpretation: as coffee’s 𝑃 ↑ by 1%, suppliers increase 𝑄𝑠 by 0.1% ; supply curve is relatively inelastic here

• Similar to 𝜖𝑑 , the 𝜂 is also not constant across the supply curve.

• Constant elasticity of supply:


Example: 𝑄𝑠 = 5𝑝3
𝜕𝑄𝑠 𝜕𝑄𝑠 𝑃 𝑝
= 15𝑝2 ; 𝜂 = ∗ = 15𝑝2 ∗ =3 | For any value of 𝑃, the elasticity is 3
𝜕𝑃 𝜕𝑃 𝑄𝑠 5𝑝3
Elasticity: Practice
• Calculate demand elasticity; price, cross price and income

• Demand functions

• 𝑄𝑑 = 𝐴𝑝𝜖

• 𝑄𝑑 = 8 − 𝑝, at the point 𝑝 = 2

• Calculate supply elasticity: price and others

• Supply functions

• 𝑄𝑠 = 10.2 + 0.25𝑝, at the point 𝑝 = 7.2

• 𝑄𝑠 = 9.6 + 0.5𝑝, at the point 𝑝 = 3.5


Elasticity and tax incidence
• Effects of tax on equilibrium & burden of tax depends on the elasticities of demand & supply
• Info about elasticities of demand & supply help make accurate predictions about effects of a tax

• In the context of elasticity, we can think of the tax incidence

• Tax incidence = who bears the burden of the tax


• Statutory tax incidence = whoever is making payment of tax to authority, bears statutory burden
• Economic Incidence = Difference in a party’s resources before and after the tax is imposed.

• Economic incidence differs from statutory incidence. This is because the market reacts to a tax.
Elasticity and tax incidence
• Statutory tax incidence != economic incidence

• If tax is imposed on the producer, the producer might increase price which offsets the amount
paid to the government as tax.
• So, the economic incidence on the producer will be less than the statutory incidence.

• If tax is levied on the consumers, they buy less and hence lower the price.
• Therefore economic incidence on consumers would be less than amount they send to the government.

• So, price responses offset statutory burdens.

• 𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑠𝑢𝑚𝑒𝑟 𝑇𝑎𝑥 𝐵𝑢𝑟𝑑𝑒𝑛 = ( 𝑃𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒𝑝𝑜𝑠𝑡𝑡𝑎𝑥 − 𝑃𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑡𝑎𝑥 ) + 𝑡𝑎𝑥 𝑝𝑎𝑦𝑚𝑒𝑛𝑡 𝑝𝑒𝑟 𝑢𝑛𝑖𝑡


• 𝑃𝑟𝑜𝑑𝑢𝑐𝑒𝑟 𝑇𝑎𝑥 𝐵𝑢𝑟𝑑𝑒𝑛 = ( 𝑃𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑡𝑎𝑥 − 𝑃𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒𝑝𝑜𝑠𝑡𝑡𝑎𝑥 ) + 𝑡𝑎𝑥 𝑝𝑎𝑦𝑚𝑒𝑛𝑡 𝑝𝑒𝑟 𝑢𝑛𝑖𝑡
Elasticity and tax incidence
• Example – market for Gas:
• Panel A: equim. 𝑄𝑒 = 100 & 𝑃𝑒 = 1.5 Rule 1: Statutory incidence ≠ economic incidence
• Panel B: tax of 0.5/per unit
• As the tax is other factor, SS curve
shifts to the left  cost increase
• New, 𝑄𝑒 = 90 and 𝑃𝑒 = 1.8

𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑠𝑢𝑚𝑒𝑟 𝑇𝑎𝑥 𝐵𝑢𝑟𝑑𝑒𝑛


= 1.8 − 1.5 + 0 = $0.3
&
𝑃𝑟𝑜𝑑𝑢𝑐𝑒𝑟 𝑇𝑎𝑥 𝐵𝑢𝑟𝑑𝑒𝑛
= ( 1.5 − 1.8) + 0.5 = $0.2
• So, in spite of gas station paying the tax,
the consumer bears more burden
• Taxes usually shared by both sides of
market, regardless of who pays
Elasticity and tax incidence
• It doesn’t matter who pays the tax. Rule 2: The side of the market is irrelevant
• 0.5 tax levied on consumer
• DD curve shifts to left by 0.5
• Due to this producer reduces the price
• New, 𝑄𝑒 = 90 and 𝑃𝑒 = 1.3 as in the case of tax
on producer
• Burden is the same!

𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑠𝑢𝑚𝑒𝑟 𝑇𝑎𝑥 𝐵𝑢𝑟𝑑𝑒𝑛 = 1.3 − 1.5 + 0.5


= $0.3

𝑃𝑟𝑜𝑑𝑢𝑐𝑒𝑟 𝑇𝑎𝑥 𝐵𝑢𝑟𝑑𝑒𝑛 = ( 1.5 − 1.3) + 0


= $0.2

• Everything is exactly same – who pays tax is


immaterial
Economic incidence depends on Elasticity
• The elasticity determines how burden of tax is split
• If demand is perfectly inelastic: seller shift all burden, so P ↑= 𝑇
• 𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑠. 𝑇𝑎𝑥 𝐵𝑢𝑟𝑑𝑒𝑛 = 2 − 1.5 + 0 = $0.5 & 𝑃𝑟𝑜𝑑. 𝑇𝑎𝑥 𝐵𝑢𝑟𝑑𝑒𝑛 = ( 1.5 − 2) + 0.5 = $0
• If demand is perfectly elastic: seller can’t raise the price above $1.50
• 𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑠. 𝑇𝑎𝑥 𝐵𝑢𝑟𝑑𝑒𝑛 = 1.5 − 1.5 + 0 = $0 & 𝑃𝑟𝑜𝑑. 𝑇𝑎𝑥 𝐵𝑢𝑟𝑑𝑒𝑛 = ( 1.5 − 1.5) + 0.5 = $0.50
• Extreme cases, generally curve becoming inelastic = losing bargaining power = bear larger burden

Rule 3: elasticities determine


economic incidence
Homework
• From the referred study write a 1 page explanation about how the demand elasticities
for the apple store and that for the android store compare? What are the conclusions
about the elasticities?
Refer: Ghose, A., & Han, S. P. (2014). Estimating demand for mobile applications in the new
economy. Management Science, 60(6), 1470-1488.
Link: https://www.jstor.org/stable/pdf/42919615.pdf
Resources/references
• Perloff, chapter 2 – supply and demand
• Varian, chapter 15 – market demand
• Serrano, chapters 4 & 5 – demand functions & supply functions

• Refer: Ghose, A., & Han, S. P. (2014). Estimating demand for mobile applications in the new
economy. Management Science, 60(6), 1470-1488.
Link: https://www.jstor.org/stable/pdf/42919615.pdf

You might also like