Labor Markets and Economic Growth: Robert Topel University of Chicago
Labor Markets and Economic Growth: Robert Topel University of Chicago
Robert Topel
University of Chicago
Thanks to Kevin Murphy, Canice Prendergast, and Pete Klenow for helpful discussions;
the usual disclaimer applies. Support from the Lynde and Harry Bradley Foundation and
the Sarah Scaife Foundation as administered by the George J. Stigler Center for the
growth. Among macroeconomists, the shift of research effort is near total, eclipsing the
business-cycle focus that had dominated the field for decades. Behind this is a recognition
of the enormous welfare implications of sustained economic growth, and a renewed desire
to understand the vast differences in living standards among countries, which dates back at
least to Smith. What some have called the “neoclassical revival” in growth economics has
because much of the revival of growth economics builds on the theory of human capital.
Because human capital is, by definition, embodied skills and knowledge, and because
advances in technical knowledge drive economic growth, it follows that human capital
accumulation and economic growth are intimately related. Indeed, many of the issues of
modern growth economics involve questions that are familiar to labor economists. How is
human capital produced and distributed? What are the private and social returns to human
capital investment, and how do people respond to those returns? How do labor markets
operate during the development process? Most of the growth-related work on these
focus on labor market and human capital issues. My openly confessed motive is to interest
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 2
labor economists in problems of economic growth, and especially to motivate empirical
research. The paper has three substantive sections, and it unfolds as follows.
accumulation of human capital, beginning with Uzawa (1965) and Lucas (1988). This
survey of theory is in no way exhaustive, or even a modestly complete review of the field,
but it serves as a template for understanding the major empirical issues in growth
economics as they apply to labor markets. I briefly cover the theory’s predictions about
transitional dynamics for economies that are away from their long run growth paths, the
role of human capital in producing new human capital, and the relation between economic
growth and inequality. This section closes with a summary of empirical implications.
Section 3 turns to the data, reviewing both empirical methodologies and the state
component of human capital – to economic growth. While richer countries are generally
more educated, it is difficult to isolate the channel through which education affects
relationship between changes in the education of a country’s labor force and changes in
output per worker. Instead, the level of education in a country does seem to affect
growth. I re-evaluate this evidence, using panel data on output per worker and
educational attainment for 111 countries over a 30-year period. Unlike previous
literature, I find social returns to investments in education that are as large as, or perhaps
larger than, the estimates of private returns that are generally found in micro-data on
productivity, I find that a 1-year increase in average years of schooling for a country’s
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 3
workforce raises output per worker by between 5 and 15 percent. The level of schooling
also affects growth in this analysis, so it appears that the social returns to education are at
famous hypothesis of Kuznets (1955) posits that wage inequality first rises and then falls
many of the stylized “facts” about labor markets during periods of rapid economic growth.
In the model, export-driven demand for industrial output raises the demand for skilled
skilled and unskilled labor. Wage inequality spurs investment in human capital and more
rapid economic growth, but increased relative abundance of skills serves to reduce
inequality. One of the open questions of this and related models is the impact of
investment in human capital on the relative price of skills. Factor price equalization
indicates that this effect should be negligible, but empirical evidence suggests that a rising
relative supply of skilled labor reduces its relative wage. In spite of trade theories, factor
This section reviews basic models of economic growth, as a basis for thinking
about data. I make no attempt to be exhaustive, or even to cover models in all of their
technical detail. The goal is to set out the broad outlines of growth models in a way that
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 4
will be useful to labor economists. For technical surveys of growth theory see Barro and
2.1 Background
study by macroeconomists. Behind this renewed interest is the enormous impact that
changes in growth can have on economic well being. For example, real per capita income
in the United States in 1950 was $8605, the highest in the world. By 1990, this figure
stood at $18,258 (still the highest), for an average annual growth rate of 1.9 percent. In
contrast, 1950 per capita income in Canada – the third richest country at the time -- was
$6112, which grew to $17,070 by 1990; a growth rate of 2.6 percent per year. If the
United States had achieved the same rate of growth as did Canada, the effect of a 0.7
percent higher growth rate – cumulated over 40 years – would have raised per capita
income in the U.S. in 1990 to $24,033, a gain of $5775 per person. At 5 percent interest
(which is probably high for this calculation), this represents a hypothetical gain in
discounted lifetime wealth of over $100,000 per person.1 Are there changes in institutions
or government policies that could deliver such gains? As a more extreme example, are
there changes in policies or institutions that would transform a growth laggard, like India,
into an Asian “miracle”, like South Korea? Even the remote prospect of gains like these
1
Perhaps it is infeasible for the richest country in the world (the U.S.) to raise its growth rate by 0.7 points
per year, since the richest countries are presumably at the frontier of available technologies and productive
knowledge. So consider a less developed country like the Phillipines. Suppose Phillipine incomes had
grown at the Canadian rate of 2.6 percent instead of its actual rate of 1.6 percent. By 1990, per capita
income in the Phillipines would have been $2507 instead of its actual value of $1519; a 65 percent
difference.
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 5
has led some economists to call economic growth “the part of macroeconomics that really
matters.”2
society’s accumulation of knowledge and the ability, or skills, needed to apply it. We
expect to be wealthier in the future because we will know how to do more things than at
present. Seemingly supportive evidence comes from Denison (1985), who estimated that
changes in schooling accounted for about 25 percent of growth in U.S. per-capita income
after 1929, and Shultz (1960), who estimated that investment in schooling grew much
more rapidly than investment in physical capital after 1910.3 Indeed, one view of the
differences in the ability to apply technologies that are, in a general sense, already
broadly known (Lucas, 1988). Then the wealth of a society is determined by its stock of
human capital, and economic growth is the process of human capital accumulation at the
level of an economy. This means that growth is supported by human capital investment
decisions that are made in labor markets. As it turns out, the role of the labor market in
2
Barro and Sala-i-Martin, 1995. They conclude that if economists can have “even small effects on the long
term growth rate, then we can contribute much more to improvements in standards of living than has been
provided by the entire history of macroeconomic analysis of countercyclical policy and fine tuning.” This
is no doubt true.
3
Estimates of the contribution of labor – including human capital – to economic growth are all over the
map. Dougherty (1991) puts labor’s share of U.S. growth at 41 percent for the 1960-90 period, but the
conformable estimate for Germany is -8.1 percent. Christianson, Cummings, and Jorgensen (1980)
estimate essentially zero contribution from human capital in Germany for the years 1947-73.
One of the key “facts” about economic growth is that most countries have
experienced sustained growth over long periods of time (Kaldor, 1963). For example, the
annual rate of growth in per-capita income in the U.S. has averaged about 1.75 percent
since the beginning of the 20th century. Similarly, the capital-output ratio is remarkably
stable across countries, both rich and poor (see Figure 1). To accommodate these facts,
modern growth models introduce some additional form of non-physical capital that offsets
(1) Y ( t ) = K ( t )α ( A( t ) L )1−α
•
where A denotes the state of labor augmenting technical progress, which grows at rate a
(2) Y ( t ) / L = A( t )[ K ( t ) / A( t ) L]α
Assuming a constant saving rate, s, under perfect competition the per-worker rates of
•
output, capital, and consumption grow at the steady-state rate a . 4 Since capital and
4
It is straightforward to endogenize the savings rate by modelling intertemporal optimization by
consumers. For present purposes, this only makes the analysis more complicated, without adding new
insights.
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 7
output grow at a common rate, the capital-output ratio is constant in the steady state.
This correspondence with the data is the motive for specifying technical change as labor-
augmenting.
This model of growth has the unsatisfying feature that technical change is both
growth after the contributions of other, observable, factors are taken into account. This
fact led T.W. Shultz (1961) and other development economists to reinterpret the residual
in terms of human capital, on the argument that technical progress is hard to distinguish
from advancement of knowledge.5 The idea was formalized by in a modern growth model
by Uzawa (1965) and later Lucas (1988), who interpret A(t) as the average stock of
formulation of the problem, output and the law of motion for the accumulation of human
capital are
(3) Y ( t ) = K ( t )α ( uH ( t ))1−α
(4) H = BH (1 − u) − δH
5
I.M.D. Little (1982) contains a brief intellectual history of the connection between the technical progress
and human capital in growth theory and growth accounting.
6
See also Jones and Manuelli (1990), Rebelo (1991), and Stokey (1991). Others model human capital
accumulation as learning by doing (Romer, 1986; Stokey 1988; and Young, 1991) or as knowledge
accumulation through R&D (Romer, 1990; Grossman and Helpman, 1991; Aghion and Howitt, 1992).
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 8
where 1-u is the portion of time devoted to production of new human capital, similar to
Ben-Porath’s (1967) model of human capital accumulation for an individual.7 Then (2)
postulates that average productivity depends on the ratio of the stocks of physical and
embody productive skills that are accumulated through endogenous, wealth maximizing
equilibrium of the model, the economy’s stocks of physical capital and human capital grow
at the same endogenous rate, which sustains economic growth in the long run. Human
human capital accumulates at the socially efficient rate. Economic growth is efficient, and
wealth. Yet education is almost always publicly financed to some (usually large) degree,
well. (German apprenticeship programs are the latest popular example, alleged to improve
German economic performance compared to the U.S.). This positive role for government
can be rationalized when individual decisions to acquire human capital create external
7
The constant returns assumption in (4) is key. If investment is subject to diminishing returns then
human capital cannot grow indefinitely at a constant rate, so sustained growth is impossible.
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 9
benefits for others.8 For example, it is plausible that an individual’s human capital is more
productive when other members of society are more skilled. Lucas (1988) analyzes an
extension of (3) in which the output of each firm depends on the human capital of its
workers, say h, as well as the average value of human capital per worker in the economy,
say ha. With this technology, decentralized decisionmaking yields too little investment in
human capital, as individual decisions to invest do not take into account the effect on
others’ productivity. Steady state output is too low relative to the social optimum, and
While models like Lucas’ show that human capital accumulation can sustain
growth, they don’t go far in detailing the role of the labor market and individuals’
investment decisions in this process. Second-generation models have enriched the basic
production and utilization of human capital. Yet for labor economists and others
interested in applied work, the message of growth theory does not go far beyond a
statement that “human capital is important.” The theory provides no guidance about why
Singapore has grown faster than, say, India, except perhaps the accounting answer that
people in Singapore have accumulated more skills (and other factors that go with them).
It does, however, provide some foundation for empirical studies of differences in growth
rates across countries, and a number of empirical implications that can be confronted with
8
Liquidity constraints will also do the trick, though I don’t analyze them in any detail. These may be
relevant, for the usual reason that human capital provides no collateral against which to finance
investments.
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 10
data (see section 2.5). Even so, the only tested implications have to do with transitional
dynamics for economies that may be off of their equilibrium growth paths (see below) and
the issue of whether measures of human capital – like education – raise productivity at all.
On the latter point, the connection of human capital to growth has proven surprisingly
Rodriguez-Clare, 1997) calls the entire enterprise into question. At the least, there is
substantial debate over the channel through which human capital may affect growth. I
for economies that are away from the steady state ratio of physical to human capital for
one reason or another. For example, consider an economy that “loses” capital in a war,
leaving the stock of human capital intact. The stock of physical capital is too low relative
to the stock of human capital. Then the path back to the steady state involves higher
growth and more rapid investment in physical capital. This is consistent with the actual
performances of Germany and Japan in the decades following World War II. Symmetrical
dynamics are implied for a country that finds itself with “too little” human capital per
worker, say because of past policy mistakes. The returns to human capital investment are
high – due to diminishing returns – and so output grows faster than in the steady state.
These are examples of what has come to be called “conditional convergence”: an economy
9
Romer (1986) studies a similar model, in which aggregate capital enters each firm’s production
function, because of spillover effects in R&D. As in the model with human capital externalities,
competitive growth is inefficient.
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 11
invests more and grows faster when its current ratio of physical to human capital is
different than its steady state value. Note that this effect is different than the idea that
countries with greater stocks of human capital have an advantage in growing because
One of the puzzles of economic growth is that some countries suddenly rise
from underdevelopment, accumulating human (and physical) capital along a path of rapid
output growth, while other countries seem to trapped in a low growth state. Becker,
Murphy, and Tamura (BMT, 1990) and Azariadis and Drazen (1990) model this as a
problem of multiple growth equilibria, where the needed non-convexity comes from the
technology for producing human capital. Both of these papers argue that human capital
begets the production of more human capital: education and other sectors that produce
human capital are intensive users of skilled (e.g. educated) labor. Within a country, this
means that rates of return on investment in human capital may initially rise instead of fall
as the stock of human capital increases, because the large stock makes it cheaper to
produce more. Comparing countries, this means that differences in initial conditions can
lead to different long run growth paths. The result is multiple steady states, one with low
output, little human capital investment, and (in BMT) high fertility; the other with higher
returns, greater investment, skills, and growth, and lower fertility. BMT argue that the
circumstances that push an economy from one steady state to another may be largely a
matter of “history and luck,” and “accidents and good fortune,” while Azariadis and
Drazen see a role for government policy in getting the ball rolling. In their model of
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 12
overlapping generations with a threshold externality in the production of human capital, a
Luck and accidents aside, this type of model can help us to understand a key
feature of human capital investment in the development process. In the Asian miracles like
Taiwan (Lu, 1993) and Korea (Kim and Topel, 1995) and in some Latin American
economies (Robbins, 1996), successive cohorts of the young acquire human capital in
larger and larger numbers. Yet empirical evidence discussed below suggests that
increased stocks of educated labor cause the returns to human capital to fall. With
constant costs of educating the young, declining returns should reduce investment. But a
technology in which the existing stock of human capital raises the productivity of current
investment can generate declining costs of adding to the stock. Then investment can rise
concerned with the effects of growth on wage and income inequality. Human capital
the growth rate of output. Yet human capital investment affects inequality in at least two
ways. First, it affects the distribution of the stock of human capital, which could either
increase or decrease inequality depending on where in the distribution of skills the new
investments occur. For example, at the initial stages of economic development human
capital investment in the form of education may be concentrated among a privileged elite.
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 13
This would tend to raise inequality. Later investment may be concentrated on the least
inequality may eventually fall. This pattern is consistent with the “Kuznets Curve”
hypothesis that inequality first rises and then falls as development proceeds.
Glomm and Ravikumar (1992) and Benabou (1996) analyze different structures for
school finance, and how differential access to human capital among individuals can affect
inequality and growth. In Glomm and Ravikumar (1992) a spillover externality in public
school finance makes individual human capital accumulation more productive when the
average human capital of the population is higher. This effective “subsidy” of the less
skilled causes inequality of human capital to die out over time. In contrast, privately
financed schooling tends to make inequality persist. Benebou (1996) analyzes the effects
or mixed together. In the short run, segregation may increase growth because talented
people are complements in producing new human capital. In the long run, however,
segregation leaves intact the overall heterogeneity of skills in the economy, which is a drag
on productivity growth. This perpetuates inequality in the long run, and can reduce
growth. This has implications for school finance. If schools are financed locally, in
communities that are sorted on talent or resources, then expenditures on education will
tend to perpetuate inequality and, perhaps, reduce long run growth. Greater funding
equity – say through centralized taxation to finance schools and reduced segregation on
talent – leads to lower long run inequality and higher growth. In this model, centralized
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 14
financing and a national curriculum – along the lines of some European countries – may
human capital investment affects factor proportions, which should impact relative wages.
As human capital accumulates, the aggregate share of skilled labor rises so that the relative
price of skills may fall. As Leamer (1995) argues, this force is mitigated by Stolper-
Samuelson effects of unimpeded trade. If output prices are fixed on international markets,
and if sectoral production functions exhibit constant returns, then factor price equalization
implies that relative wages of different skill groups are independent of their factor shares
within a particular country. (The technical conditions for this are discussed in greater
detail in Section 4). With constant returns, an increase in the labor force share of skilled
sectors, leaving factor proportions in each sector (and thus relative wages) unchanged.
Empirical evidence from a number of countries appears to reject this prediction, however.
Increases in the aggregate share of educated labor do not simply increase the size of skill-
intensive sectors. Within-sector shares of educated labor rise as well (Murphy and Welch,
1993; Topel, 1994; Kim and Topel, 1995, Robbins, 1996), which indicates that the relative
“price” of skilled labor will fall as it becomes more abundant. Empirical evidence on this
10
For example, Swedish schools are centrally financed, and funding equity is strictly adhered to.
Curriculum is uniform across schools.
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 15
Models that base sustained growth on human capital accumulation have a number
human capital increases economic growth. As discussed below (Section 3), this central
prediction has proven surprisingly resistant to empirical confirmation, at least in the form
that the theory implies. Secondary and more subtle predictions are (i) rising returns to
skill should spur investment and, therefore, growth; (ii) the private and social returns to
human capital may differ when spillover effects are important; and (iii) economies that are
initially below their steady state values of physical or human capital will experience faster
growth. Complementarity between the existing stock of human capital and new
investment implies that: (iv) investment in human capital may rise, even while the returns
are declining; (v) countries with little initial human capital may be “trapped” in a low
growth, low income state; and (vi) the distribution of human capital can affect investment,
and hence growth. Some of these predictions are taken up in Sections 3 and 4.
In the models outlined above, human capital drives growth because it is an input
to the production of goods and services, as in (3). Then growth in human capital per
worker is equivalent to growth in output per worker; human capital simply earns its
private marginal product. Nelson and Phelps (1966) offer an alternative view. In their
analysis, growth is driven by the stock of human capital because skilled workers are more
likely to innovate new technologies and – for countries that are not at the technological
frontier – more able to adopt existing technologies. In this analysis, a greater level of
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 16
number of microeconomic studies of the role of education in production, beginning with
Welch (1966), find empirical evidence for the idea that educated workers are more likely
to adopt new productive technologies. For example, in a study of Indian farmers, Foster
and Rosenzweig (1996) find that more educated farmers are the first to adopt new seed
technologies.
At the aggregate level the most obvious empirical implication of this view is
that changes in the rate of output can depend on the level of human capital, rather than
simply on the change in human capital as implied by standard growth models. This
prediction is consistent with empirical results of Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995) and
Benhabib and Spiegel (1994), who estimate models of economic growth on a cross-
section of countries. They find little evidence that growth of human capital is associated
with growth of output, but a higher level of education per worker (measured by average
years of schooling in the population) is associated with a higher rate of economic growth.
stronger effect than years of primary education, which may also reflect greater ability to
innovate and adopt technologies among more skilled workers. Benhabib and Spiegel find
that the level of education has a stronger effect on growth for relatively low income
countries, which may indicate a role for education in “catching up” to technological
leaders. The next section provides a more detailed discussion of these and other empirical
results.
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 17
The recent revival of growth theory is built on the idea that human capital is
central to growth. Yet there is little consensus on what is the channel of causality leading
that growth of human capital and growth of output are nearly synonymous. An alternative
theory, with support in some recent empirical work, is that the level of human capital
affects growth through greater innovation and adoption of technologies. As pointed out
by Aghion and Howitt (1998), the theories have starkly different implications for the
neoclassical models imply that current investment leads to a one-time surge in output as
new human capital is applied in production. In contrast, models like that of Nelson and
Phelps (1966) imply that current investment – by raising the level of human capital – has a
It is plausible that both theories of the role of human capital are true. Growth of
human capital may increase output and set the stage for subsequent growth. Yet even
then, the differences between the theories is more semantic than real. Neoclassical
encompasses the accumulation of knowledge and the ability to apply it in productive ways.
If this is so, then why do some empirical studies – like Barro and Sala-i-Martin
(1995) and Benhabib and Spiegel (1994) – find that the level of human capital, as
measured by average years of schooling, raises growth? An answer is that human capital
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 18
is an input to its own production, a fact that is central to many growth models, and that
schooling is only one form of human capital. Other forms of human capital accumulation
– like on the job training, acquisition of knowledge outside of formal schooling, and
learning-by-doing – are unmeasured. Empirically, this means that the level of schooling
will be correlated with growth because countries with more education invest more in other
forms of human capital. A related point is that countries with more schooling may have
lower costs of investing in other forms of human capital, so schooling is simply a proxy for
3. Empirical Evidence
3.1 Background
theory does not go much beyond the idea that human capital should be important to
sustained economic growth. The empirical questions are (i) How important is it?; and (ii)
What are the channels through which human capital affects growth? Does growth of
broadly-defined human capital “account” for what we would otherwise call productivity
growth, as suggested by Lucas (1988) and others? If so, would government policies that
encourage human capital investment improve welfare, especially among less developed
countries that might be able to “catch up” with more advanced countries, which are closer
to the technological frontier? Are some policies and institutions, such as income
11
In this sense, I think that Aghion and Howitt (1998) greatly exaggerate the difference between
neoclassical and “Shumpertarian” models of human capital and growth.
12
In earnings data for individuals, age-earnings data for more educated workers are steeper for more
educated workers. The standard explanation is that education reduces the costs of subsequent, on-the-job
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 19
redistribution and centralized wage setting, a hindrance or boon to human capital
investment and growth? These are key empirical issues for which we have few good
answers.
There are two main strands of empirical research on economic growth. Both
measurable input quantities – physical and human capital -- and a residual called “total
factor productivity” (TFP). The art in this approach lies in measuring inputs, which is
especially difficult when the input in question is an abstract stock like “human capital.”
and panel models of the determinants of countries’ incomes. Our main interest in this
literature will stem from what can be learned about the empirical relationship between
This section also provides some new evidence on the effects of schooling on
economic growth. I find that returns to schooling estimated from aggregate data on
country growth rates are generally as large, or larger than, the returns estimated by labor
investment in human capital. Heterogeneity of talent has the same implication: those with more education
have lower costs of investing, so we expect them to invest more in other forms of human capital.
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 20
physical capital (K) and human capital (H) via F(K,AH), where A denotes the state of
labor augmenting technical progress. Assuming constant returns to scale and competitive
factor markets, the rate of change of output for country i at date t is given by
• • • •
(5) y it = α it k it + (1 − α it ) hit + pit
• • • •
where, y , k , h and p refer to the proportional rates of change of output, physical
capital, human capital, and TFP, respectively, and α is capital’s share of national income.
With the exception of p, all quantities in (5) are measurable, at least to some degree,
which leaves TFP as the part of output growth that remains unexplained after taking
account of the growth rates of physical and human capital. Hence the estimate of TFP is
Original applications of (5), such as Solow (1957) and Denison (1962, 1967)
treated raw labor as the human capital input, and did not account for changes in the
quality of capital, so that a large portion of growth was attributed to TFP. Later work by
Jorgensen and Griliches (1967) and Jorgensen, Gollop, and Fraumeni (1987) showed that
a substantial portion of the Solow residual could be accounted for by changes in input
quality. For our purposes, the quality of the human capital input has increased in most
countries because of improvements in health and in the quantity and quality of schooling
among working age populations. This means that subcategories of the labor force (years
of schooling and experience, gender, and so on) should be weighted by their marginal
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 21
products (wages) in forming a human capital aggregate.13 Then accumulation of human
capital means that H grows faster than the labor force, which accounts for some of
productivity growth.
The most recent applications of this method are in three influential papers by
Young (1992, 1994, 1995). He studies the growth experience of the four “Asian tigers:”
South Korea, Hong Kong, Taiwan, and Singapore. As shown in Table 1, between 1966
and 1990 output per worker in these economies grew at average annual rates of between 4
and 5 percent, far above the 1.4 percent rate achieved by the U.S. over this period. Before
Young’s work, many observers attributed this remarkable growth record to technical
physical and human capital in these countries, Young concludes that their rapid growth is
due to input accumulation (and utilization, in the case of labor), while TFP growth was
not unusually high by world standards. In fact, for Singapore, Young finds that TFP
growth contributed essentially nothing to income growth over this period. All of the
growth in output can be accounted for by changes in the quantity and quality of capital,
sharply increased labor force participation, and increased years of schooling of workers.
The implication is that the remarkable growth record of these economies is unlikely to be
13
The production function is y = F(K,Σ ni Hi ), where ni is the number of workers in group i and Hi is
average human capital of those in the group. Equating marginal products to wages for each group, we get
Hi /Hj = wi /wj, so Hi = (wi /wj)Hj. For example, an increase in the number of high school graduates relative
to elementary school graduates, holding population fixed, will raise the measured stock of human capital
in proportion to the college/high-school wage ratio.
14
In Table 1, the differences between the growth rates of GDP and GDP per worker are largest for the
four “Asian Tigers.” Much of GDP growth in these economies was accomplished by increased labor force
particiapation.
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 22
The growth accounting literature suggests an important role for the labor market
in economic growth. Consider Young’s results for Korea. Beginning in 1966, growth in
labor input (including quality) “contributed” a breathtaking 4.4 percent per year, for a 25
year period, to growth in aggregate output. As shown in Table 1, almost all of this effect
was due to increased labor utilization rather than to any increase in measured human
capital per worker. Over this period, the Korean non-agricultural labor force grew at an
annual rate of 5.4 percent per year (!), while population grew at only 1.6 percent. The
difference reflects increased labor force participation and a wholesale migration out of
agriculture. A growth accounting measure of human capital per Korean worker grew at
an annual average rate of .007/(1-.32) = 1 percent per year, faster than for any country in
the table save Singapore. This increase was driven by a massive investment in public
education that reduced the share of workers with a primary education from over 60
percent in 1970 to less than 30 percent by 1990 (Kim and Topel, 1995). Yet rising human
capital per worker was swamped by the concomitant rise in the capital/labor ratio, which
“accounted” for 61 percent of the increase in Korean labor productivity. By this method,
human capital growth accounted for only 14 percent of the growth in output per worker.
Indeed, for the countries in Table 1, human capital never accounts for the major portion of
economic growth. Does this mean that human capital isn’t so important after all?
human and physical capital in virtually identical ways. It has nothing to say about how or
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 23
why factor accumulation took place, or whether human capital accumulation is essential
The first point has to do with what it means to measure a factor’s contribution to
growth. Consider again the estimate that human capital contributed 0.7 percentage points
per year to Korea’s productivity growth. This figure is simply an average of marginal
contributions of labor, along the actual path of physical and human capital
accumulation. It doesn’t say that output per worker would have grown at 0.7 percent had
capital remained fixed. Even so, it may vastly understate the importance of human capital
to the growth process. Suppose for the sake of argument that a Lucas-Uzawa style model
is an appropriate description. Their theory is that human capital is the whole story. In the
steady state, the proportional rate of growth of physical capital is equal to the proportional
•
rate of growth of human capital, given by a = B(1 − u ∗ ) − δ (see equation (4)). The ratio
of physical to human capital is constant in the steady state, so that output per capita also
•
grows at rate a . Growth is driven by human capital accumulation, but a growth
•
accounting exercise attributes the product of capital’s share and a to capital.
More generally, the quantity and type of physical capital investments that actually
occurred may depend on the quality of human capital that is available to work with it.
Without large investments in human capital, particularly in education, Korea may not have
adopted the existing technologies that fueled its growth. In this sense, investments in
human capital, such as education, may be essential to the growth process. Then growth
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 24
A second limitation is that changes in human capital are poorly measured. A virtue
of studying developing nations is that changes in the amount of human capital employed in
production may be well measured by changes in observable quantities like the number of
workers and their years of schooling and experience. Think of the typical Korean worker
who, let’s say, now enters the labor market with a secondary instead of a primary
education. The things he learned in those additional years are “common knowledge,” like
arithmetic and grammar, well inside the frontier of ideas. In this case, the change in the
quantity of human capital per worker may be well approximated by increased years of
schooling. Now think of workers in a developed economy, like the U.S, where average
years of schooling has changed by less. The additional knowledge that workers bring to
the labor market largely consists of new knowledge, like how to use a computer. Their
human capital is greater, but no observable measure picks this up. Conceptually, the
contribution of human capital is the same in both economies, but in Korea the increase in
human capital is more accurately measured by observables. In the U.S., where observable
quantities did not change by much, more of the contribution of human capital is attributed
More broadly, any measure of human capital for growth accounting is based on
prices that those observables command. If school quality improves at all levels, or if post-
The third limitation of growth accounting is that it is silent about how the labor
market actually operates during economic growth. In rapidly growing Asian (and other)
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 25
economies, we know that industrial expansion was fueled by migration of workers from
agriculture. We also know that public investments in education sharply raised average
schooling levels. What market forces supported this? A market-driven scenario is that the
relative price of skilled labor, needed for industrial production, was initially quite high
because skilled labor was scarce. Expansion of public education increased opportunities to
invest in skills, and wage inequality provided the incentive for young workers to do so.
industrial employment, the relative price of skilled labor fell, which further fueled growth.
This description of events gives a prominent role to a smoothly operating labor market,
supporting growth. Indeed, in this scenario, educational opportunities start the ball
rolling. The modern macroeconomics of growth provides little evidence on whether this
be at least equal to the private return. Human capital is measured by a wage-weighted sum
of labor inputs, which is simply multiplied by 1-(capital’s share) to get an estimate of the
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 26
( 6) ln(Yit / Lit ) = α i ln( K it / Lit ) + (1 − α i ) ln(hit ) + (1 − α i ) ln( Ait )
The parameters β k and β h represent the contributions of physical capital and human
capital to aggregate productivity, and β i allows for differences in total factor productivity
across countries. Assume that adequate measures of output per worker and physical and
human capital are available for a large sample of countries at a point in time. Then with
(good luck), β k and β h can, in principle, be estimated from cross-sectional data. This is
the basic approach taken in empirical studies by Mankiw, Romer, and Weil (1992) and
Klenow and Rodriguez-Clare (1997). Alternatively, with panel data equation (7) can be
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 27
(8) ∆ ln(Yit / Lit ) = β k ∆ ln( K it / Lit ) + β h ∆ ln(hit ) + ∆ ε it
Variants of equation (8) underlie empirical growth studies by Benhabib and Spiegel
(1994), Pritchett (1997), and (to a lesser extent) Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995). Notice
that unlike the growth accounting approach, models (7) and (8) treat β k and β h as free
Mankiw, Romer, and Weil (MRW, 1992) reach a similar conclusion to that of
countries. They study the cross-country distribution of output per capita in 1985, using a
Solow-type model that is extended to account for differences in the quality of human
capital across countries. To measure stocks, they capitalize investment flows using the
average 1960-85 flow of investment in physical capital (for K) and the 1960-85 secondary
school enrollment rate (for H). They find that input differences – especially human capital
differences – “account” for nearly 80% of the cross-country variance in income.15 Only
about 1/5 of the variance is due to unobserved productivity differences. Thus Mankiw
(1995) concludes that “most international differences in living standards can be explained
This conclusion clearly rests on the dubious assumption that physical and human
15
Formally, using data on 98 countries, they estimate a model of the form ln(Y/L) = b1ln(K/Y) + b2ln
(H/Y) + e. The R2 from this regression is .78, with elasticities of b1 = .30 for capital and b2 = .28 for labor.
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 28
productive (higher A) countries are also more intense users of physical and human capital,
approach. And if it isn’t “A” that drives things, this research also leaves open the question
of why countries with similar technological and other opportunities end up with
dramatically varying stocks of physical and human capital. Do poor countries experience
decades of sub-optimal investment because of policy mistakes, like excessive taxes and
might give economists real value as policy advisors (“Stop doing that. Invest.”). Or do
observed stocks of physical and human capital reflect optimal responses to other, country-
specific constraints? The empirical literature on economic growth leaves this basic
question unanswered.
MRW’s conclusion that inputs account for income differences has also been
1997b) argue that MRW misstate the contribution of human capital by calculating human
According to their estimates, human capital stocks vary less across countries when
16
See Chari, Kehoe, and McGratten (1996), who argue that such inefficiencies can explain international
income differences.
17
Klenow and Rodriguez-Clare also account for differences in shapes of age-earnings profiles, based on
standard Mincerian regression techniques. Implicitly, then, their analysis also accounts for international
differences in post-schooling investments in human capital and learning-by-doing.
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 30
sectional data differences in output per worker are more strongly correlated with
interpret their findings as favoring the notion of technological “catch-up” rather than
below, support this interpretation.18 The usual method of aggregating skill groups simply
weights the number of worker hours in each group by its relative wage, resulting in an
estimate of “H.” This method assumes that human capital of high school graduates (for
example), measured in efficiency units, is a perfect substitute for the human capital of
college graduates. A long list of country studies of relative wages rejects this assumption
(e.g. Freeman, 1980, 1986; Katz and Murphy, 1990; Kim and Topel, 1992; Edin and
Heston (1995) international data set. For our purposes, they study two main issues. First,
do international and other data contain evidence that would favor convergence of
incomes? That is, do low-income countries (or regions) grow faster than high-income
18
The growth regressions of Barro and Sala-i-Martin, discussed below, are consistent with this. They find
that a higher initial of stock of secondary school graduates raises a country’s growth rate, but that the
stock of primary graduates has no effect. Klenow and Rodriguez-Clare also use United Nations data on
the share of each country’s population at various ages to construct an experience measure. Their measure
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 30
ones? Using data on European regions, U.S. states, and Japanese prefectures, they find
evidence that strongly favors the convergence hypothesis. For example, the poorest U.S.
states in 1880 had the highest rates of per-capita income growth over the 1980-1990
period. The underlying assumption of these regressions is that different areas have similar
institutions and access to the same basic technology, so that income differences reflect
deviations from steady-state values. Again, however, we are left with little understanding
of why different areas started with different incomes and, correspondingly, different levels
of human and physical capital. Even so, the findings are important and are consistent with
related work on changing quality of inputs. For example, Smith and Welch (1986) and
Card and Krueger (1992), among others, have documented the long-term improvement in
educational quality (and years of schooling) in the American South during the 20th century.
Surely this is a contributor to the long-term relative economic growth of the region. Yet,
given the costs of investing in physical and human capital, the growth process itself is
disturbingly long. After a century of convergence, with largely identical legal and
economic institutions, per-capita income in Mississippi remains less than half of that in
schooling and health, to economic growth. Their concern with issues of convergence
leads them to bypass a formal specification like (8). Instead they found their empirical
of H is then based on returns to schooling and experience derived from a standard cross sectional earnings
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 31
where G denotes country i’s average annual rate of growth between time 0 and t, Yi0 is the
log of initial per-capita income, Yi* is the log of steady state per-capita income, and β i is a
steady-state growth rate for country i. The parameter β 1 indexes the average “speed of
convergence” over [0,t]. In light of (9), BSM estimate models of the form
where H is a vector of human capital measures, and X is a vector of controls for political
stability, terms of trade, and the like. The hypothesis of convergence (which doesn’t
concern us much here) is that β 1 > 0: rich countries grow slower than poor ones, other
things equal.
current income per-capita, a country with a more skilled workforce “should” be richer. So
we expect β 2 > 0 from the convergence hypothesis. In this case human capital raises the
steady state income of country i without affecting steady state growth. Alternatively,
human capital can affect the growth rate itself. There are three possibilities. First,
education can be a boon to technical change, as a more educated workforce is more likely
to think of and implement new ways of doing things (Nelson and Phelps, 1966). This
raises steady state income growth, even for economies that are at their current steady state
income level. Again, this implies β 2 > 0. Alternatively, a more skilled workforce may be
regression.
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 32
better at adopting existing technologies (Welch, 1966). For example, South Korea’s post-
1970 expansion of secondary and higher education may have positioned it for more rapid
adopt (Kim and Topel, 1995). This effect raises the speed of convergence for economies
that are below their steady state income level. This might yield β 3 < 0: additional human
capital has a smaller impact on growth when initial income is high, and there is less to
The third possibility is that β 2 < 0: countries with low initial stocks of human
convergence. Further, for less developed countries much of the growth process is likely
low levels, is simply the transference of knowledge that has already been produced and
used somewhere else. Other things equal, a country with low initial educational
attainment may have lower costs of growing. To me, this means that little can be learned
from a model like (10) about the effects of initial human capital on growth. Both β 2 > 0
and β 2 < 0 are consistent with the idea that human capital investment is a boon to growth
and development.19
These points aside, what do the data reveal about the relationship between
initial human capital and growth? BSM estimate models of long term (1960-85) growth,
with controls for H that include the time-0 average years of primary, secondary, and
19
Using BSM’s educational data for 1960-1990, a regression of the growth of average years of schooling
on initial schooling and initial log output per worker yields a coefficient of -.005 (t=2.9) on initial
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 33
expectancy at birth. Consistent with the findings of MRW, above, BSM find that initial
subsequent economic growth, but that secondary higher educational attainment are related
to growth. For men, they find that a one standard deviation increase in average years of
secondary education (about .9 years) raises the average annual growth rate by 1.5
percentage points per year. A one standard deviation increase in average years of post-
secondary education (.2 years) raises growth by 1.0 points per year. For women, BSM’s
estimates imply that greater educational attainment reduces growth. For example, a one
standard deviation increase in years of secondary schooling for women (.9 years) reduces
annual growth by 0.8 points per year. This is consistent with the argument for β 2 < 0
stated above; countries with low educational attainment for women may have greater
human capital.
education seems to do something – but it is hard to take them seriously for any sort of
calibration or policy purposes, even ignoring the negative effects of female schooling.
Consider what we might expect to from standard estimates of the private returns to
schooling and from a Solow-type model augmented to include human capital. Let the
human capital stock be H=hL, where L is the labor force and h is human capital per
schooling. Over a 30 year period, a 2 standard deviation increase in initial schooling (5.3 years) reduces
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 34
(11) ln(Y / N ) i = α ln( K / N ) i + (1 − α )[ln( L / N ) i + ln hi ] + (1 − α ) ln Ai
Human capital models of endogenous growth imply that the capital/output ratio is
constant, which seems to supported by the data (see Young, 1992, and Figure 1, above,
for evidence on this). With this condition we can rewrite (11) as:
where φi is the constant log capital/output ratio for country i. Equation (12) says that
increases in human capital per worker result in equal proportionate increases in per capita
(13) ln hi = θ i + θ S S i + θ X X i
average human capital per worker such as experience, on-the-job training, and the like.
Equation (13) can be interpreted as an aggregate form of human capital earnings functions
that are commonly estimated on micro-data, which assume that wages are proportional to
human capital supplied.20 Notice that the form of (13) implies that an additional year of
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 35
schooling raises human capital by a constant percentage amount, θ S , independent of the
level of hi. Typical estimates of the returns to schooling from micro-data yield a effect of
a year of additional schooling on log wages in the range of .06-.10, depending on country
and time period under study. For the sake of argument, put this value at .08. To gauge
this impact on labor’s marginal product against θ S , divide by labor’s share of aggregate
output, which we can put at about .60 (see Table 1). This yields an approximate value for
θ S of .13, so an additional year of schooling for the average worker should raise per-
capita income by about 13 percent if the private and social returns to schooling are equal.
Unless the human capital externalities suggested by Lucas (1988) and others are truly
grand, this puts an approximate upper bound on the impact of schooling on output per
worker.
Now compare this value to BSM’s estimates of the impact of human capital on
growth. Under one interpretation, human capital raises steady-state income, Yi*, in (9). If
a year of additional schooling raises steady state income by 13 percent – using the private
returns – and the rate of convergence is on the order of β 1 = .03 per year, then the effect
of additional human capital on growth should be about .03x.13 = .0039 per year of
additional schooling. Thus the BSM estimates – which suggest effects of well over .01
per year of schooling—are vastly too big for the model they purport to estimate. The
steady state growth rate by over 1% per year, does not have a well-defined benchmark
from micro-data. Yet at any reasonable rate of interest this effect on growth implies a
interpretation of equation (13). To the extent that variance terms are relatively stable within a country,
they are removed by the fixed effects estimator employed here.
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 36
huge rate of return.21 The conclusion that seems warranted is that countries with high
Benhabib and Spiegel (1994), Pritchett (1997), and Bils and Klenow (1997)
study the impact of growth in imputed human capital on growth in output per worker,
using a form of equation (8). Each of these studies finds minor, or even negative, effects
of growth in imputed human capital on growth in output, though Benhabib and Spiegel
confirm BSM’s finding that the level, as opposed to the change in the stock of educational
capital is correlated with growth. Like BSM’s estimates, however, the magnitude of the
short, the empirical growth literature does not lend much support to the idea that human
however.
To examine the relationship between education and economic growth, I use the
Summers-Heston Mark 5.6 (1995) data, combined with the Barro-Lee (1993) data on
attainment for a panel of 118 countries, at 5-year intervals from 1960 to 1990. The
Summers-Heston data record various measures of output, investment, and living standards
21
At 5% real interest and a .01 effect on growth, the returns are roughly 4 times the costs.
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 37
for 152 countries beginning in the 1950’s. Merging these two sources yields an
unbalanced panel of 111 countries, with usable data on education and output, beginning in
1960. Most previous efforts with data like these examine the determinants of long-term
changes in output, typically over the period from 1960-85. Instead I look for a closer
connection between the timing of input and output changes, using the data recorded at 5-
year intervals from 1960 to 1990. Combining (6) and (13), write output per worker in
components of human capital. Data on capital per worker are fairly sparse, which leads
by Klenow and Rodriguez-Clare (1997) for 1965 and 1985, I impute estimated
capital/labor ratios in other years by linear interpolation. Then rearrange (14) to obtain
Application of (15) requires an assumption about capital’s share, α, to measure the left-
hand side, along with the assumption that this value does not differ across countries.
22
They find that an additional year of average schooling raises the 1965-85 growth of rate by about .13
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 38
Alternatively, if we accept the evidence that motivates endogenous growth models and
across countries, both (15) and (16) involve country-specific fixed effects that should be
accounted for in estimating the model. These effects can be eliminated by using either a
equations (15) and (16) when the only measured determinant of human capital is average
years of schooling. The data on output and schooling are recorded at 5 year intervals, on
an unbalanced panel of 111 countries, yielding 719 observations. All models contain
country effects to account for the terms φi + θi, so the estimates are generated solely by
estimates (columns 1-4) assumes that the capital-output ratio is fixed within a country, so
no adjustment for capital intensity is needed.23 The estimated social returns to schooling
are remarkably large. Omitting year effects in columns (1) and (2), the effect of an
23
A within-country regression of (imputed) log capital per worker on log output per worker has a
coefficient of 1.17 (se = .05).
24
Heckman and Klenow (1997) report cross-sectional estimates of a regression of GDP per-capita on
average years of schooling, also using the Summers-Heston data, for 1960, 1985, and 1990. Their
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 39
Some care should be taken in interpreting these, and the following effects. The
effect of .226 in column (1) means that an additional year of schooling raises productivity
by this amount, allowing for the endogenous response of capital that keeps the capital-
output ratio fixed. It should be multiplied by labor’s share to gauge how schooling affects
the marginal product of labor, which is then comparable to estimates of the private returns
taken from individual data. For example, if labor’s share is .6 then the effect of schooling
on the log average wage is .6x.226 = .135 per year of additional schooling. This exceeds
When year effects are added to the model in column 3, the estimated unconditional
return to an additional year of schooling is falls to 10 percent. Accounting for year effects
(column 4), when average years of schooling are broken down into primary and secondary
components, the estimated returns to secondary schooling are more than double the
returns to primary schooling, though both are different than zero by the usual criterion.
Columns 5-8 of the table drop the assumption of a constant capital/output ratio
columns 5-6 I assume that capital’s share of aggregate output is .35 – assumed to be fixed
across countries and over time – while the estimates in columns 7-8 assume α = .50. The
latter estimate is probably at the upper end of what can be deemed reasonable – see Table
1 above. The estimated returns to schooling fall as capital’s assumed share rises, and
estimated standard errors rise as well. Even so, the implied returns in columns 5 and 7 of
the table are not unreasonable in light of the effects of schooling typically found in micro
estimates, generated by between country variation in average school attainment, also show returns in the
.2-.3 range.
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 40
data. Again, the division between years of primary and years of secondary schooling
human capital. This is not a concern if neglected elements of human capital are fixed
within countries, as these differences are absorbed by the fixed effects. But measured and
unmeasured innovations to human capital (or other inputs that are complementary with
human capital) might well be correlated, which would lead to an overestimate of the
returns to schooling. I considered two other measurable correlates of human capital. The
U.S. Census Bureau compiles international statistics on the age distribution of the
economically active population for various years and for most of the countries used in the
estimation procedure, using census and other data from each country. I used these data to
construct average age and experience (age - schooling - 6) for the working aged
population. The Census also reports average life expectancy at birth for most countries
and years, using age-specific mortality rates. As shown in Table 3, after controlling for
The finding that changes in life expectancy at birth do not have a substantial
effect is not too surprising, since much of increased life expectancy in developing
countries is accomplished through reductions in infant mortality. These changes may have
little to do with improvements in the human capital of the working age population.25
Further, any effects that do emerge from the least-squares estimates – as in columns 1 and
25
For example, in Gineau-Bissau in 1980 the average age of the economically active population was 38.7
years, while life expectancy was just 44.4 years. In the same year, the average age of the economically
active in Israel was 38.1 years, but life expectancy was 75 years. There is remarkably little variation in
average ages of the economically active. In 1990, the mean age across countries was 36 years, with a
standard deviation of 1.79.
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 41
2 – may reflect the effect of economic growth on health. The negligible impact of average
age (and thus of experience) is more surprising in light of evidence from micro data on the
private returns to experience. The panel data on average age of the economically active
population are fairly meager, however. And even accurate measurements would be
affected by improving health status of successive cohorts of workers, which could reduce
in schooling and productivity, the fixed-effects estimator is not an explicit empirical model
of growth. Fixed effects can also be removed by first-differencing the data, so the
Estimates based on (17) are more comparable to the empirical growth literature, especially
contributions by Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995), Pritchett (1997), and Benhabib and
Speigel (1994). Before proceeding to the estimates, it is worth noting the effect of
Assume that average years of recorded schooling measures true schooling with classically
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 42
θS
(18) p lim(θ S ) =
σ2
1+ 2 e
σ S (1 − ρ )
where ρ is the correlation between St and St-1. Thus serial correlation in St increases the
noise-to-signal ratio in differenced data, magnifying the downward bias caused by classical
of economic growth: more frequent observations increase sample size, but frequent
observations are less informative about the effects of interest in the presence of
of output per worker based on intervals of 5, 10, 15, and 20 years, along with the average
growth of output on growth in educational attainment and year effects. Notice that when
the 5-year average growth rate is used, the effect of measured schooling on productivity is
only .028 per year, which is barely significant by conventional standards and which implies
an effect on wages that is well below the private returns to schooling estimated in micro-
data. This estimate rises, however, as the interval for calculating growth lengthens. At
intervals greater than 20 years the effect of an additional year of schooling on log output
per worker is .167, which implies an effect of .10 of schooling on wages. This rising
impact of schooling as the length of the growth interval is lengthened may reflect the
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 43
impact of measurement error, or the effect of accumulating complementary inputs in the
longer run.
Columns 2, 5, 8, and 11 of Table 4 repeat the exercise, but add initial years of
schooling and initial log output per worker to the growth regressions. An additional year
of initial schooling raises subsequent growth by about 0.4 percent per year, independent of
the length of the interval used to gauge growth27. While this is smaller than the effects of
initial schooling found in Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995), in combination with the effect of
initial log output per worker it is still too large to be interpreted as the effect of schooling
alone on steady-state growth. The effects of lagged output show what is typically
interpreted as evidence of convergence: at any point in time, lower income countries tend
to grow (slightly) faster. Conditioning on these initial values tends to raise the effects of
The last column of estimates under each growth interval adds an interaction
between growth in average schooling and initial log income per worker. Initial income is
deviated from its year-specific mean, so the reported main effect is the impact of additional
schooling at the mean of the distribution of initial productivity. At least for the shorter
growth intervals, there is some evidence that additional years of schooling have a larger
impact at low levels of initial output per worker. The fact that the interaction dies out as
the growth interval is lengthened indicates that most of the effect comes from within-
26
More generally, differencing exacerbates the effect of measurement error if serial correlation in
schooling exceeds serial correlation in measurement error.
27
Benhabib and Spiegal (1994) and Barrro and Sala-i-Martin (1995) also find that initial schooling raises
growth. Benhabib and Spiegal interpret this effect as reflecting the ability of more educated workers to
adopt existing technologies.
28
I do not report similar regressions which allow for separate effects of primary and secondary schooling.
Tests of the restriction that primary and secondary schooling have identical effects cannot be rejected for
these models.
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 44
country variation in growth. At a 20-year interval, the estimated impact of a year of
schooling on average productivity rises to .246, evaluated at the mean level of initial
productivity.
capital, ∆Xit , which may be correlated with changes in schooling. Given the quality of the
data, direct measurement of these is infeasible. Further, average growth in schooling may
assume that unobserved components of human capital and technical progress evolve at a
constant rate within a country, so that θx∆Xit = λi. Then λi is a fixed effect in the growth
model (17), which can be eliminated (in panel data) by standard methods. The resulting
average schooling and unmeasured factors in λi. A limitation of this approach is that the
fixed effects estimator is best suited to “short” growth intervals – say 5 or 10 years in the
panel length available here – which increases the number of observations per country. But
indicated above.
schooling on economic growth, controlling for fixed country effects, in productivity data
measured at 5 and 10 year intervals. Despite issues of measurement error, there remains a
positive (and reasonable) effect of schooling in the 10-year growth data. At the mean
level of initial productivity, the estimates in column 4 of the table indicate that an
additional year of schooling raises average productivity by nearly 9 percent. This estimate
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 45
may understate the true returns to the extent that measurement error is exacerbated by the
difference-in-differences estimator.
The estimates in Tables 2-5 indicate that increases in average years of schooling
estimates of the contribution of average years of schooling to the stock of human capital,
the low end of the range of these estimates – say 7-10 percent per year of schooling -- is
consistent with comparable estimates of the private returns to schooling derived from
micro-data. The upper end of the range of estimates suggests social returns to an
additional year of schooling that may be larger than traditional estimates of private returns.
This possible excess of social over private returns is consistent with growth models that
(1988).29 Then private decisions lead to too little investment in human capital, and too
little growth, compared to the social optimum. The confirmation that the level of
schooling also affects growth, though with a smaller impact than in previous literature,
suggests that more than simple input accumulation is at work in generating growth.
different from the conclusions of Pritchett (1997) and Benhabib and Spiegel (1994).
Using data on long term (20 years or more) growth for roughly the same sample of
countries examined here, they find that changes in the measured stock of human capital
29
Heckman and Klenow (1997) make a similar point.
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 46
are unrelated to changes in the average product of labor.30 Why do they find negligible
Pritchett’s (1997) results are due to the way he measures human capital. Unlike
equation (13), which is the aggregate analogue of the usual human capital earnings
function, Pritchett’s measure assumes that an additional year of schooling raises the stock
of human capital by a larger proportional amount in less educated countries than in more
educated ones. When this form for human capital is used in the data for tables 2-5, I also
find no effect of schooling on growth. This restriction is rejected by the data, and it is
inconsistent with widely accepted evidence on the form of human capital earnings
functions.31 Benhabib and Spiegel (1994) obtain their measure of human capital from
Kyriacou (1991), who imputed average years of schooling from a linear regression of
schooling on past enrollment rates. Their regressor is the log change in imputed average
years of schooling for a country; thus, like Pritchett (1997) they assume that a year of
schooling has a larger proportional impact on the stock of human capital in low-education
countries. The models estimated here assume that each additional year of schooling raises
the stock by a constant proportional amount, as is implied by the standard form of human
30
As noted above, Benhabib and Spiegel (1994) do find that the initial stock of measured human capital
raises subsequent growth, which they attribute to the ability of a more educated workforce to adopt
existing technologies from abroad.
31
More formally, Pritchett assumes that lnh = H0 + ln(exp(θsSi ) - 1). Then dlnh/dS = θs/(exp(θsSi - 1),
which →∞ as S → 0.
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 47
As this discussion indicates, the empirical literature connecting human capital
cross-country comparisons of the levels of productivity often hinge on the particular way
that human capital is measured. Thus in the parlance of “ models, Mankiw, Romer,
(measured inputs), while Klenow and Rodrigues-Clare (1997) give greater weight to “A”
conclude that human capital – especially schooling – plays a role, but the particular
channels through which schooling affects growth are open to debate. Several studies find
that initial levels of schooling raise subsequent growth though, as noted above, these
effects appear suspiciously large. And there is no well-articulated theory of how these
effects come about. A more direct connection follows from Solow-style models of
economic growth, which predict that changes in the stock of human capital should drive
changes in output. This relationship appears to hold in the data examined above, and the
magnitude of the estimated effect appears reasonable in light of prior knowledge of the
imply that the private returns to schooling can exceed the social returns, empirical
evidence for important signalling effects is at best meager. In my view, the weight of
evidence from micro-data yields a strong prior that rising educational attainment of the
labor force should spur economic growth. Further, this evidence on private returns
provides a fairly precise range for how big the effects should be. The key empirical issue
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 48
is not whether schooling raises aggregate output – evidence to the contrary should be
regarded with great suspicion, especially given the quality of data that are used in
aggregate growth studies. Rather, the significant open question is whether the social
returns to human capital investment substantially exceed the private returns (Heckman and
Klenow, 1997). Then public expansion of education may be a key ingredient in economic
growth.
4.1 Background
themes. Unlike the balanced growth models in vogue today, he viewed rapid economic
effects of growth on income distribution, hypothesizing that wage and income inequality
increased in the early stages of rapid growth, but later fell. This inverted-U relation of
In Kuznet’s description of events, rising demand for industrial labor is the precursor
of growth. How does this come about? A plausible candidate is trade liberalization. As
described in Tsiang (1979), early economic policies in less developed countries emphasized
Taiwan and other Asian economies discredited this approach, and the opening to trade led
to rising demand for manufactured exports. In this description of events, rising export
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 49
demand raises the demand for skilled industrial workers, leading to rising investment in
human capital and an exodus of labor from agriculture. The Kuznets Curve occurs because
rising industrial wages draw the small number of skilled workers to that sector, raising
inequality, but later migration and investment in human capital changes overall factor
proportions. Skill intensive sectors expand during the development process, but wage
To focus on this process, consider an economy with two labor types, skilled (S)
and unskilled (U) and two sectors. Output in sector j is Yj = Fj(Sj,Uj), with constant
returns to scale. Assume that sector 1 is relatively skill intensive; think of it as the
The stock of skilled labor can be augmented by investments in human capital, which
•
(20) S t = Bf (vt , S t )S t − δS t
In (20), v is the proportion of the stock of skilled labor that is devoted to training, and B is
the number of unskilled workers who obtain training per unit of v. The function f satisfies
fvv < 0, so there are diminishing returns to raising v. I also assume complementarity
between the stock of skilled labor and the productivity of time devoted to training, fvS >
0. The model is closed by labor supply constraints for each labor type:
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 50
(21) (1 − vt ) S t = S t1 + S t2
(22) U t = U t1 + U t2 + Bvt S t
(23) Nt = St + Ut
An efficient allocation maximizes the present value of social output by allocating labor
among production and training. In addition to the usual marginal conditions equating the
marginal products of skilled and unskilled labor across sectors, an interior solution for
∞
(24) Wt s + BWbu = Bf v (vt , S t ) ∫ (Wτs − Wτu )e −( r +δ − g ( v , S ))(τ −t ) dτ
t
Where g(v,S) > 0 is the difference between the average and marginal products of f.
Equation (24) is the condition of interest for the following discussion. The left hand side
is the opportunity cost of human capital investment: Each unit of skilled labor devoted to
training has an opportunity cost of Ws – the wage of skilled labor – and the student-
teacher ratio of B requires that B unskilled workers be withdrawn from production as well.
The right side represents the present value of human capital produced by raising vt, where
Ws - Wu is the wage premium commanded by skilled labor. Equation (23) has several
important implications.
First, suppose that Ws and Wu are fixed through time. This means that relative
wages in this economy are independent of factor proportions, as would occur under factor
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 51
price equalization for a small open economy. With constant returns to scale in each
sector, a sufficient condition for this Stolper-Samuelson result is that the prices of each
sector’s output are fixed, say on international markets. Given this, (24) presents two
interesting cases. First, if St is sufficiently low then the marginal product of new
investments may be too small to satisfy (23). As in Becker, Murphy, and Tamura (1990)
or Azariadis and Drazen (1990) the economy is stuck in a low growth “trap” because the
marginal cost of investing in skills is too high. This is an outcome of the fact that it takes
human capital to produce more, and the stock has a spillover effect in f, so poor initial
The second case occurs when S is sufficiently large to spur investment and
growth. It is obvious from (24) that, for any S sufficiently large, v is increasing with the
wage premium Ws - Wu. Then S, aggregate output, and output per capita all rise over
time, and labor migrates from low-skill sector 2 to high-skill sector 1. Relative wages are
unchanged, however. With constant returns and fixed output prices in each sector the
labor to the skill-intensive sector, 1. The skill ratio in each sector is unchanged, which
devoted to human capital investment. In other words, development begins slowly because
S is initially low, but it accelerates as the stock of skilled labor rises over time.
The dynamics of this model incorporate a sort of “Kuznets Curve” in that the
relative proportions of high and low-wage labor change over time. If the share of skilled
labor in the labor force is initially low, then measures of wage dispersion can rise, and
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 52
then fall, as “development” (skill upgrading) proceeds.32 While this is much of what
Kuznets had in mind, the more interesting case occurs when factor prices adjust to the
increased skill intensity of the labor force. Then the wage distribution may narrow
because investment makes skilled labor relatively less scarce. Indeed, in this case
investment in human capital serves to offset wage inequality. When will this occur?
factor price equalization (FPE) nails down the skill premium in wages. But the
conditions for FPE are so strong that it would be surprising if factor proportions did not
affect relative wages. FPE will fail if (i) there are diminishing returns in production; or
(ii) output prices decline with quantities produced – the economy’s goods are imperfect
substitutes for others on international markets; or (iii) there are more labor types than
sectors with constant returns and fixed output prices. If any of these conditions are true,
then the relative price of skilled labor will fall as skills become more abundant.
In this case, a rising stock of skilled labor reduces the present value of wage
premiums on the right side of (24). If the initial value of S is too low, the model implies a
“low growth” state with low investment, low growth, and a large skill premium in wages.
But if S is above a threshold that generates investment, the model implies rising per-
capita output along with: (i) migration of labor from the low-skill to the high-skill sector;
(ii) skill upgrading (increasing Sj/Uj) in each sector; and (iii) a steadily declining wage
differential, Ws - Wu, between skilled and unskilled labor, as the real wages of both skill
32
Here, the variance of wages is rising with S so long as the skilled share of the labor force is smaller than
.5.
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 53
the relative abundance of skills, which is a force toward greater wage and income
equality.
The assumption of complementarity between the stock of skills, S, and the portion
of that stock devoted to investment, v, delivers a final implication. Suppose the contrary,
that fvS = 0, so abundant skills do not affect the productivity of training. Then a rising
stock of skills reduces the present value of wage premiums on the right side of (24).
With diminishing returns, this means that the portion of the stock devoted to new
investment declines over time, as the marginal returns on investment are falling. From
(19) this means that the rate of growth of S is falling as well. But fvS > 0 implies that
productivity rises over time, so the rate of growth in the stock of skilled labor need not
Evidence on the relationship between wage or income inequality and the process of
development is fairly limited. There are two main empirical issues. First, in a model like
the one outlined above, wage inequality can increase growth by raising the returns to
human capital investment. So the first question is: Do greater returns to skill increase
human capital investment? The second question has to do with how relative wages
relative price of skilled labor and thus reduce wage inequality? In effect, we need to
separate (i) the effects of skill prices on the flow of new investment from (ii) the effects of
Evidence on the effect of wage differences on human capital investment requires time
series data on measurable investment activity, and corresponding data on the returns.
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 54
Edin and Topel (1996) and Topel (1997) examine the one dimension of human capital
investment that is directly observable and measurable, schooling, in Sweden and the U.S.
Figure 2, taken from Edin and Topel (1996), graphs the relation between the estimated
returns to a college education in Sweden on the left hand scale (measured as the difference
in log wages between workers with 16 years of schooling and workers with 12 years), and
the proportion of Swedish men aged 20-24 who are enrolled in school on the right-hand
scale.33 Between 1968 and 1984, the log wage differential for a college graduate fell from
.59 to .20, with most of the drop occurring in the six years 1968-74. At its nadir, the
returns to a college education in Sweden were less than half of the lowest returns
Swedish wage distribution during this period. How did young people respond? The
figure shows that the proportion of young men attending college fell from 13 percent in
1968 to only 8 percent in the early 1980’s. The correspondence between enrollments and
are measured as the fraction of men aged 20-24 with some college. Again, the
correspondence in the two series is striking. As the college wage premium rose through
the 1960’s, the fraction of young men with some college climbed, peaking at 44 percent in
the early 1970’s, when the returns to college were higher than ever before. As the college
wage premium fell in the 1970’s (why? See below), so did school attendance, reaching a
low of 37 percent in 1980. Then both the returns to college and college attendance
trended up, the latter reaching an all time high of 46 percent in 1992, when the returns
33
The wage figures are for workers with 1-9 years of labor market experience.
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 55
were also at a record high. Similar patterns hold for young women. From 1979 to 1993,
school attendance rates for young women rose from .30 to .41. As in Sweden, the
American evidence is that the supply of human capital rises with the relative price of skill.
Greater investment increases the stock of human capital, and we expect the
rental price to fall with the stock. This underlies Katz and Murphy’s (1990) explanation of
the time series shape of the college wage premium in the U.S., shown in Figure 3.34 They
assume that the relative demand for college graduates grows at a steady pace (trend) –
presumably because of skill-biased technical change – and they show that changes in the
relative supply of college graduates is inversely related to the college premium. The glut
of college graduates in the 1970’s, driven by baby boom cohorts, caused the college
premium to decline. Katz and Murphy’s implied elasticity of substitution between college
and high school graduates (about 1.4) is consistent with other labor demand studies
(Hamermesh, 1993).
This basic approach has been replicated in other countries, which have experienced
even larger changes in the relative supplies of educated labor (see Katz, Loveman, and
Blanchflower, 1995, for comparisons of the U.S., Japan, France, and the U.K.). Edin and
Holmlund (1995) show that the rapid decline in the college wage premium in Sweden
coincides with an increase in the labor force share of college graduates, which more than
doubled between 1971 and 1985. Their estimate of the elasticity of substitution between
college and high school graduates (2.9) is substantially larger than what has been found in
other labor demand studies, however (Freeman, 1986). Table 6 provides illustrative
34
Freeman (1980) is a related analysis of the changing returns to a college education.
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 56
estimates of the effects of factor proportions on relative wages for the small number of
While the college premium in western economies increased during the 1980’s, it
fell dramatically in some developing countries. In Korea, the college wage premium fell
by 25 log points between 1976 and 1989. By the end of the 1980’s, the return to a college
education in was Korea only two-thirds as large as in the U.S.; it had been double the U.S.
return in 1979. Kim and Topel (1995) argue that this compression was driven by a rapid
upgrading of educational attainment in the Korean labor force. The labor force share of
elementary school graduates fell from 60 to 30 percent in only 19 years, while the shares
of college and high school graduates soared. Consistent with this, the relative wage of
university graduates fell and the relative wage of those with an elementary education rose
sharply (see Figure 4). The result was a decline in wage inequality in Korea – shown in
Table 7 – that ran against the trend toward greater inequality in developed economies.
How do these results square with the notion that free trade equalizes factor
prices, so that factor proportions in any particular country should not affect that country’s
relative wages? As noted above, the conditions for factor price equalization are, at best,
proportions in individual industries are independent of overall factor proportions for the
skilled labor without affecting relative wages. This prediction is at odds with evidence
from a number of countries, most notably the U.S., where rising educational attainment of
the labor force has resulted in skill upgrading in virtually all industries (Murphy and
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 57
Robbins (1996) summarizes a number of country studies of the effects of trade
liberalization and changes in relative supplies of skills on relative wages. His main concern
other studies surveyed above, he finds a general pattern that relative wages are inversely
related to relative supplies, even in apparently open economies where FPE might hold.
What can we take from this evidence? If we accept the postulate of modern
growth theory, that human capital accumulation is the engine of economic growth, the
data tell us that there is a trade-off between growth and income redistribution. Policies
that compress wage or after-tax income differences across skill groups reduce human
capital investment and, in so doing, reduce steady state growth and long-run prosperity.
Many critics of redistributional policies recognize this, at least implicitly, and some
Australia and Sweden – where centralized wage setting serves to compress skill premiums
in wages (Gregory and Vella, 1995; Edin and Topel, 1997) – policymakers went beyond
education is only one component of human capital investment. Policies that artificially
compress the wage distribution also reduce the return on post-schooling investment, such
represent an important social problem. Schooling is the one dimension of human capital
investment that is directly observable and measurable, and the evidence is that it responds
35
Lindbeck et. al. (1994) are explicit: “Empirical studies indicate that slower accumulation of physical
capital can only explain the Swedish fall in productivity growth in the 1970’s and 1980’s to a limited
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 58
to changes in returns. As importantly, evidence from several countries indicates that
changes in the relative quantity of skilled labor, driven by investment, causes inequality to
fall. To the extent that rising inequality is driven by increased scarcity of skilled labor,
investment in human capital is the long run solution.36 In the long run, policies that
compress wages or incomes may exacerbate the underlying economic forces that cause
5. Concluding Remarks
bias toward issues of interest to labor economists. The recent “growth of growth” as an
area of economic research has been dominated by theory, and there has been little
But barriers to entry by applied researchers are not low. The fact that growth
theory is far ahead of empirical research has much to do with the quality and quantity of
analyses of the empirical determinants of economic growth have been largely constrained
to a single (valuable) data set, covering roughly 100 countries and a few standard
measures of inputs and output. These data seem to confirm a connection between human
capital (mainly measured by schooling) and economic growth, though the channels
extent....It is then tempting to pinpoint the accumulation of human capital. The private return on
education and on-the-job training has indeed been quite low in Sweden for a long time.”
36
Topel (1997) contains a more detailed discussion.
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 59
through which these effects operate is open to debate. Barring a specification no one has
thought of, there isn’t much more to be learned from these data.
The most fruitful path may be closer to “development” economics than to the
kinds of empirical research that has been carried out thus far. By this I mean detailed
empirical studies of the operation of labor markets and the impact of policies and
institutions within individual countries. Emerging economies of Asia and Latin America
offer on-going laboratories in which to study labor markets during periods of rapid
economic growth, and many collect the kinds of detailed data that labor economists are
known to relish. It is only through this kind of tedious but rewarding empirical work that
we will come to understand the role of labor markets in the growth process.
C:\TOPEL\PAPERS\growth.doc 60
References
Aghion, P. and Howitt, P. (1998) Endogenous growth theory, Cambridge, MA: M.I.T
Press.
Becker, G., Murphy, K.M. and Tamura, R. (1990) ‘Human capital, fertility, and economic
Journal of Political Economy, 98:S12–S37.
Ben-Porath, Y. (1967). ‘The production of human capital and the life cycle model of labor
supply’, Journal of Political Economy 75:352–65.
Card, D. and Krueger, A. (1992) ‘Does school quality matter? Returns to education and
the characteristics of public schools in the United States’, Journal of Political
Economy 100:1-40.
Chari, V.V., Kehoe, P., and McGratten, E. (1996) ‘The poverty of nations: a quantitative
exploration’, NBER Working Paper #5414, Cambridge, MA.
Christensen, L., Cummings, D., and Jorgensen, D.W. (1980) ‘Economic growth, 1947–
1973: an international comparison’, in: John W. Kendrick and Beatrice Vaccara,
eds., Developments in productivity measurement and analysis. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press.
Denison, E.F. (1967) Why growth rates differ. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution.
Edin, P-A. and Topel, R. (1997) ‘Wage policy and restructuring: the Swedish labor
market since 1960’, in: Richard Freeman, Robert Topel, and Birgitta Swedenborg,
eds., The welfare state in transition. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Edin, P-A. and Holmlund, B. (1992) ‘The Swedish wage structure: the rise and fall of
solidaristic wage policy?’ in: Richard Freeman and Lawrence Katz, eds.,
Differences and Changes in Wage Structures. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press.
Elias, V. (1990) Sources of growth: A study of seven Latin American economies. San
Francisco: ISC Press.
Foster, A.D. and Rosenzweig, M.R. (1996) ‘Technical change and human-capital returns
and investments: evidence from the green revolution’, American Economic
Review, 86:931–953.
Freeman, R. and Needels, K. (1993) ‘Skill differentials in Canada in an era of rising labor
market inequality’, in: David Card and Richard Freeman, eds., Small differences
that matter, Chicago: University of Chicago Press for NBER.
Glomm, G. and Ravikumar, B. (1992) ‘Public vs. private investment in human capital:
endogenous growth and income inequality’, Journal of Political Economy,
100:818-834.
Gregory, R. and Vella, F. (1995) ‘Real wages, employment, and wage dispersion in U.S.
and Australian labor markets’, in: Richard Freeman and Lawrence Katz, eds.,
Differences and changes in wage structures, Chicago: University of Chicago Press
for NBER.
Grossman, G. and Helpman, E. (1991) Innovation and growth in the global economy.
Cambridge, MA: M.I.T. Press.
Heckman, J. and Klenow, P. (1997), “Human capital policy,” Working Paper, University
of Chicago, December.
Jones, L.E. and Manuelli, R.E. (1990) ‘A convex model of equilibrium growth: theory and
Journal of Political Economy, 98:1008–1038.
Jorgensen , D., Gollop, F.M., and Fraumeni, B.M. (1987) Productivity and U.S. economic
growth. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Kaldor, N. (1963) ‘Capital accumulation and economic growth’, in: Friedrich A. Lutz and
Douglas C. Hague, eds., Proceedings of a conference held by the London
Economics Association. London: Macmillan.
Katz, L. and Murphy, K.M. (1992) “Changes in relative wages, 1963-1987: supply and
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107:35–78
Katz, L., Loveman, G., and Blanchflower, D. (1995), ‘Changes in the structure of wages
in four OECD countries’, in: Richard Freeman and Lawrence Katz. eds.,
Difference and changes in wage structures. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Kim, D. and Topel, R. (1995) ‘Labor market and economic growth: lessons from Korea’s
industrialization, 1970-1990’, in: Richard Freeman and Lawrence Katz. eds.,
Difference and changes in wage structures. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Kyriacou, G. (1991) ‘Level and growth effects of human capital’, Working Paper, C.V.
Starr Center, New York University.
Lindbeck, A., Mulander, P., Persson, T., Petesson, O., Sandmo, A., Swedenborg, B., and
Thygesen, N. (1994), Turning Sweden around. Cambridge, MA: M.I.T. Press.
Mankiw, N.G. (1995), “The growth of nations,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity,
G. Perry and W. Brainard ed., vol 1, 275-326.
Mankiw, N.G., Romer, D., and Weil, D.M. (1992) ‘A contribution to the empirics of
Quarterly Journal of Economics 107:407–437.
Murphy, K.M. and Welch, F. (1991) ‘The role of international trade in wage differentials’,
in: Marvin Kosters, ed., Workers and their wages. Washington, D.C.: AEI Press.
Pritchett, L. (1997) ‘Where has all the education gone’, Policy Research Working Paper,
Washington, D.C.: World Bank, June.
Rebelo, S. (1991) ‘Long-run policy analysis and long-run growth’, Journal of Political
Economy, 99:500–521.
Robbins, D. (1996) “HOS meets facts, facts win: evidence on trade and wages in the
developing world,” Working Paper, Harvard Institute for International
Development, Cambridge.
Smith, J. and Welch, F. (1986) ‘Closing the Gap: Forty Years of Economic Progress for
Blacks’, Rand Publication Series R-3330-DOL, 1986.
Solow, R. (1957) ‘Technical change and the aggregate production function’, Review of
Economics and Statistics, 39:312–320.
Stokey, N. (1988) ‘Learning by doing and the introduction of new goods,” Journal of
Political Economy, 96, 4, 701-17.
Summers, R. and Heston, A. (1991) ‘The Penn world table (Mark 5): An expanded set of
international comparisons, 1950–1988’, Quarterly Journal of Economics,
106:327–368.
Topel, R. (1997) ‘Factor proportions and relative wages: the supply side determinants of
Journal of Economic Perspectives 11:55–74.
Tsiang, S.C. (1984) ‘Taiwan’s economic miracle: lessons in economic development’, in:
Arnold Harberger, ed., World economic growth. San Francisco: ICS Press.
Young, A. (1991) ‘Learning by doing and the dynamic effects of international trade’,
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106:369–406.
Young, A. (1994) ‘Lessons from the East Asian NIC’s: a contrarian view,” European
Economic Review, 38:964–73.
Young, A. (1992) ‘A tale of two cities: factor accumulation and technical change in Hong
Kong and Singapore’, in: Olivier J. Blanchard and Stanley Fischer, eds., NBER
Macroeconomics Annual. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Young, A. (1995) ‘The tyranny of numbers: confronting the statistical realities of the East
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110:641–80.
Table 2
(Dependent variable is log real output per worker, measured at 5-year intervals)
__________________________________________________________________________________________________________
Note.--Data are from Summers and Heston (1991) and Barro and Lee (1993). Data on capital stocks were provided by Pete Klenow.
Absolute t-ratios are in paretheses. All models contain 111 country effects.
Table 3
______________________________________________________________________________
Notes.--See notes to Table 2. Age and life expectancy data are available from the U.S. Census
website at http://www.census.gov.
Table 4
) Years of Schooling .028 .041 .058 .064 .085 .115 .120 .148 .155 .167 .252 .246
(2.02) (2.95) (3.70) (3.15) (4.26) (5.07) (4.01) (5.07) (5.23) (3.66) (6.10) (5.73)
Initial Years of Schooling .004 .004 .004 .003 .004 .003 .004 .004
(5.71) (5.57) (5.02) (4.85) (4.84) (4.59) (6.37) (5.93)
Log Inital Output per !.007 !.005 !.007 !.004 !.008 !.005 !.010 !.009
Worker: Rn(Y/L) (4.06) (2.56) (3.54) (1.56) (3.68) (1.77) (4.86) (2.26)
Year Effects yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes
R2 .176 .218 .224 .256 .315 .332 .308 .386 .391 .133 .397 .399
N 608 608 608 290 290 290 186 186 186 101 101 101
____________________________________________________________________________________________________________
Five-Year Ten-Year
Growth Growth
(1) (2) (3) (4)
__________________________________________________________________
Note: Estimates are coefficient from regressions of the form ln(wi/wj) = $0 + $1 ln(Li/Lj) + $2X +
u, where Li is the labor supply of individuals from skill group I.
Sources: Sweden: Edin and Holmlund (1995); South Korea: Kim and Topel (1995); Taiwan: Lu
(1993); U.S. and Canada: Freeman and Needels (1993).