Week 3
Week 3
Portfolio Management
3.1 Risk and Return
Net return
Pt +1 + Dt +1
rt +1 = −1
Pt
Dt +1 Pt +1 − Pt
= +
Pt Pt
= income yield + capital gain/loss
1 T
r = ∑ rt
T t =1
– Sample standard deviation is then
T
1
V[~
r ] = σˆ =
2
∑
T − 1 t =1
(rt − r ) 2
σˆ = σˆ 2
Source: CRSP, Morgan Stanley Capital International and Global Financial Data.
Copyright © 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights
reserved.
10-7
Geometric Average
• We can define rGEO as the return that makes
• or
rGEO = [(1 + r1 )(1 + r2 )...(1 + rT )]
1/ T
−1
13
If you can only choose one stock?
• Most investors like expected return and dislike
uncertainty (risk aversion)
.B
µΑ .A .C
.D
σΑ σ
Indifference Curves
µ
µ
B
B
A
A
σ σ
18
Portfolio variance
• The expected return is a weighted average of
the expected return on the assets in the
portfolio.
• But, the variance is not a weighted average. It
depends on how the returns on the assets in
the portfolio covary (correlation, covariance).
• Diversification can reduce the variance of a
portfolio.
Portfolio variance
• The variance of a two-asset portfolio is
σ2p = wx2 σ2x + wy2 σ2y + 2wx wy σxy
σ2p = wx2 σ2x + wy2 σ2y + 2wx wy ρxy σx σy
Rem Var(aX+bY)=a2Var(X)+b2Var(Y)+2abCov(X,Y)
σ P2 = ∑ wi2σ i2 + ∑ ∑w w σ σ
i j i j ρij
i i j ≠i
Two risky assets
• Two risky assets – bond and stock portfolios
– Means of 3.0% and 7.5%
– Standard deviations of 10% and 20%
– Correlation of 0.2
• Consider a portfolio with 1/3 of funds invested
in bond and 2/3 of funds invested in stock
portfolios
21
Two risky assets
• Portfolio expected return
µp = 1/3 × 0.03 + 2/3 × 0.075
= 0.06 = 6.0%
• Portfolio variance= wx2 σ2x + wy2 σ2y + 2wx wy σxy σxy = ρσxσy
σp2 = (1/3)2 (0.1)2+(2/3)2(0.2)2+2 (1/3)(2/3)(0.2 × 0.1 × 0.2)
= 0.0207
• Portfolio standard deviation
σp =√0.0207
= 0.1438 = 14.38%
• What happens if the proportions change?
• What happens when the correlation changes?
22
Two risky assets when proportions change
return
100%
Asset Y
100%
ρ = 0.2
Asset X
ρ = −1
σ P2 = ( wxσ x − wyσ y ) 2
σ P = wxσ x − wyσ y > 0
σ P = wyσ y − wxσ x > 0
wx σ y
σ P = 0 when =
wy σ x
Two-Assets: Different Correlations
return
100%
ρ = -1.0 Asset B
ρ = 1.0
100%
ρ = 0.2
Asset A
7.000%
6.000%
5.000%
E xpec ted R eturn
4.000%
3.000%
2.000%
1.000%
0.000%
0.000% 5.000% 10.000% 15.000% 20.000% 25.000%
V ola tility
27
Correlation and Diversification
• The various combinations of risk and return available
all fall on a smooth curve.
• This curve is called an investment opportunity set
because it shows the possible combinations of risk
and return available from portfolios of these two
assets.
• A portfolio that offers the highest return for its level
of risk is said to be an efficient portfolio.
• The undesirable portfolios are said to be dominated
or inefficient.
Diversification and Risk
• In a large portfolio, some stocks will go up in value
because of positive company-specific events, while
others will go down in value because of negative
company-specific events.
• Unsystematic risk is essentially eliminated by
diversification, so a portfolio with many assets has
almost no unsystematic risk.
• Unsystematic risk is also called diversifiable risk,
while systematic risk is also called nondiversifiable
risk.
Why does diversification work?
30
Diversification and Portfolio Risk
Portfolio Risk
In a large portfolio the variance terms are effectively
σ diversified away, but the covariance terms are not.
Diversifiable Risk;
Nonsystematic Risk;
Firm Specific Risk;
Unique Risk
Portfolio risk
Nondiversifiable risk;
Systematic Risk;
Market Risk
n
Thus diversification can eliminate some, but not all of the
risk of individual securities.
Systematic Risk
• The risk of a well diversified portfolio depends on
the market risk of the securities included in the
portfolio
• The reward for bearing risk depends only on the
systematic risk of an investment, not on the risk
that can be diversified away.
• So, no matter how much total risk an asset has,
only the systematic portion is relevant in
determining the expected return (and the risk
premium) on that asset.
Market Risk is Measured by Beta
• If you want to measure the contribution of an individual
security to the risk of a well-diversified portfolio, it is no good
thinking about how risky that security is in isolation, you need
to measure its market risk, and that boils down to measuring
how sensitive it is to market movements. This sensitivity is
called beta (β).
• Stocks with β>1 amplify movements in market
• Stocks with 0<β<1tend to move in the same direction as the
market, but not so far.
36
Most of Global’s risk is unique and can be
diversified away:
15.00%
5.00%
0.00%
12/1/05 1/1/06 2/1/06 3/1/06 4/1/06 5/1/06 6/1/06 7/1/06 8/1/06 9/1/06 10/1/06 11/1/06 12/1/06
Market
Unique
-5.00%
-10.00%
-15.00%
-20.00%
37
Dynamo has much more market risk which
cannot be diversified away:
15.00%
5.00%
0.00%
12/1/05 1/1/06 2/1/06 3/1/06 4/1/06 5/1/06 6/1/06 7/1/06 8/1/06 9/1/06 10/1/06 11/1/06 12/1/06
Market
Unique
-5.00%
-10.00%
-15.00%
-20.00%
38
Beta or Marginal Volatility Matters!
39
Only market or systematic risk matters:
40
3.3 The Capital Asset
Pricing Model
Efficient Investments
Efficient Frontier
return Inefficient
Investments
σ
As we discussed, since investors want to minimize risk
and maximize return, they will not invest in portfolios that
are dominated on either dimension. This leads to an
Efficient Frontier.
Market Equilibrium
return Optimal
Risky
Portfolio
rf
σ
If all investors have the same expectations about risk and return,
all investors will have the same CAL because they all have the
same optimal risky portfolio given the risk-free rate. This is the
Capital Market Line (CML).
Market Equilibrium
Market
return
Portfolio
rf
σP
With the capital market line identified, all investors choose a
point along the line: some combination of the risk-free asset
and the common optimal risky portfolio. In equilibrium this
portfolio has to be the market portfolio M.
Market Equilibrium
• If all investors have the same set of
expectations, they will choose the same
optimal risky portfolio. All investors will always
hold this portfolio. In market equilibrium,
demand will equal supply. This optimal risky
portfolio will then be the market portfolio, the
value-weighted portfolio of all risky assets.
• Then with borrowing or lending, the investor
selects a point along the CML, the Capital
Market Line.
Intuition
• If everyone in the economy holds an efficient
portfolio, how should securities be priced so that
demand equals supply?
• If, for given expected returns, variances, and
covariances, no investor wants to hold Xerox, what
will happen?
– Price (and expected return) of Xerox needs to adjust
• Equilibrium
– Every investor is happy with her portfolio
– Supply of assets is equal to demand for assets
Intuition
• Every investor solves the mean-variance problem
and holds a combination of risk-free asset and
portfolio of risky assets (tangency portfolio)
• With homogeneous expectations, tangency
portfolio is the same for all investors
• In equilibrium the sum of all investors’ desired
portfolios must equal the supply of assets
• Aggregate supply of asset is the market portfolio
• Market portfolio has to be the tangency portfolio
The Market Portfolio
• Everybody will want to invest in Portfolio M and
borrow or lend to be somewhere on the CML
– Therefore this portfolio must include all risky assets (or
else some assets would have no demand)
E(r)
CML
M
E(rM)
rf
σ
σM
Capital Market Line
• The CML is a straight line with intercept rf and
slope equal to the Sharpe Ratio of the market
portfolio E[r ] − r
Slope =
M f
σM
• The equation for the CML
E[rM ] − rf
E[rE ] = rf + σE
σM
• The slope gives us the market price of risk in the
market.
Relationship between Risk and Return
• In the mid 1960 three economists Sharpe,
Lintner and Treynor showed that in a
competitive market the expected risk
premium on a security varies in direct
proportion to its beta (its measure of
systematic risk)
• The relevant measure of risk is the covariance
of the asset or portfolio with the market
(beta)
CAPM
• Expected Return on the Market:
E[rM ] = r M = rf + Market Risk Premium
E[ri ] = r i = rf + β i × (r M − rf )
Expected return
SML
E[rM ]
Slope = (E[rM ] − rf )
rf
1.0 β
E[ri ] = rf + β i (E[rM ] − rf )
Relationship Between Risk & Expected
Return
Expected
return
SML
13.5%
10%
3%
1.0 1.5 β
β i = 1.5 r f = 3% r M = 10%
Unlike the case for large portfolios, there is no precise relationship between
volatility and average return for individual stocks. Individual stocks have higher
volatility and lower average returns than the relationship shown for large
portfolios.
Portfolio Betas
(
r i = rf + β i r M − rf )
∑ w r = ∑ w r + ∑ w β (r
i
i i
i
i f
i
i i M )
i
(
− rf = rf ∑ wi + r M − rf )∑ w β
i
i i
(
r P = rf + β P r M − rf )
Beta of a portfolio is portfolio-weighted average of
individual assets
β P = ∑ wi β i
i
∑ i xi βi =
βP = (.40)(0.69) + (.60)(1.77) =
1.338
rf + β (E[RPortfolio ] − rf )
E[Ri ] = i
Mkt
ri ,t − rf ,t = α i + β i (rM ,t − rf ,t ) + ε i ,t
• Estimation issues
– Betas may change over time
– Don’t use data from too long ago
– Five years of weekly or monthly data is reasonable
– Use Data Analysis / Regression or Linest in Excel
IBM example
15%
10%
5%
0%
-15% -10% -5% -5% 0% 5% 10%
-10%
-15%
-20%
Excess market return
IBM example
• Assume riskfree rate of 3% and equity premium of
6%
• Expected return on IBM assuming CAPM is true is
r=3%+1.237*6%= 10.42%
• In valuation applications, 10.42% would be the
discount rate in the present value formula
– E.g. If you expect IBM’s price to be $50 in one year
and expect it to pay a dividend of $2, then the
current fair price should be
$(50+2)/(1+.1042)=$47.1
Testing the CAPM
• Method 1:
– Take a large number of stocks
– Over some time period, e.g. 1975-1995, estimate
the beta for each of them
– Then look at the average return on each stock in
the subsequent period, say 1995-2015
– Do the average returns line up with measures of
beta?
Testing the CAPM
• Method 2:
– Take a large number of stocks
– Over some long period, e.g. 1950-2015, estimate
alpha and beta for each of them by running an
excess return regression
– Are the alphas on average zero
– Can the alphas be predicted by any security
characteristic like firm size or past performance?
Testing the CAPM: Results
• Mixed: results with both approaches
– Higher beta stocks do earn higher returns on
average, but not that much
– Low beta stocks have higher returns than the
formula predicts
– High beta stocks have lower returns than formula
predicts
• A number of stock characteristics explain
average returns better than beta
Testing the CAPM: Results
• Fama French (1992)
– No relation between beta and average returns
once you control for:
• Size (market capitalization)
• Ratio of book value of equity to market value
– “Beta is dead!”
– Multifactor models
Testing the CAPM: Caveat
• Roll Critique (1977)
– Market portfolio not observable
– Limits tests of CAPM
• Also,
– Still used widely in corporate finance and portfolio
management
– Convenient was to estimate expected returns
– Theoretically plausible and intuitive
3.4 Equity Valuation
Readings: Berk and DeMarzo, Chapter 9.
D1
P0 =
r −g
D1
r= +g
P0
D1 = 4(1.2) = 4.80,
D2 = 4(1.2)2 = 4.8(1.2) = 5.76,
D3 = 5.76(1.05) = 6.048, and
Dt = Dt −1 (1.05) for t = 4, 5, . . .
0 1 2 3 4 5 ...
Our basic stock price valuation formula relates the stock price to
expected dividends. However, one of the most commonly used
indicators of a stock’s value is its P/E ratio (that is, their ratio of
price to earnings per share).
– Some industries, like automotive, have very low P/E’s (about 5),
whereas other industries, like drugs, have high P/E’s (about 20).
– Does this mean that the drugs industry is overpriced?
In order to understand the relationship between price and earnings, let
us consider a firm with no debt and a fixed amount of stock
outstanding. Define
Dt = Dividends per share at date t (end of year t )
Et = Earnings per share at date t (end of year t )
It = New investment per share at date t (end of year t)
Et Dt
Et = Dt + It ⇔ Dt = Et − It .
Substituting this cash flow identity into the basic valuation formula
(on page 31) gives
∞
Et − It
P0 = ∑ (1 + r )t .
t =1
The dividend models that we explored are not that helpful in valuing
stocks for companies that do not pay dividends.
Also, as just explained, we cannot rely on comparables to value stocks.
As such, we will now learn a commonly used method called
Discounted Cash Flows (DCF).
As we will see, we need to forecast future cash flows over a finite
horizon for which we have good information and then estimate a
terminal value.
As such, the expression at the bottom of slide is re-written as
T
Ct 1 CT +1
P0 = ∑ ( 1 + r ) t
+
( 1 + r ) T r −g
t =1
Using a firm’s financial statements, the historical free cash flows are
calculated on the next slide over the time period 2006-2010.
Recall from Lecture 2 that we can calculate free cash flow (FCF) as
But we also have to consider the value of the firm after this
three-year period. This requires computation of a terminal value.
1% = $2.80 6% = $5.86
2% = $3.11 7% = $7.70
3% = $3.50 8% = $11.38
4% = $4.03 9% = $22.40
5% = $4.76