Article DID
Article DID
Abstract—Despite dozens of studies, research on crime has struggled to researchers have found that RTC laws either have little
reach consensus about the impact of right-to-carry (RTC) gun laws. With
this in mind, we formalize and apply a class of bounded-variation impact or may increase violent crime rates.2 Consider, for
assumptions that flexibly restrict the degree to which outcomes may vary example, Aneja, Donohue, and Zhang (2011), who make
across time and space. Using these assumptions, we present empirical seemingly minor modifications to the basic model and data
analysis of the effect of RTC laws on violent and property crimes in Vir-
ginia, Maryland, and Illinois. Imposing specific assumptions that we (e.g., reducing the number of demographic covariates) that
believe worthy of consideration, we find that RTC laws increase some Lott (2010) used. Whereas Lott (2010) found that RTC laws
crimes, decrease other crimes, and have effects that vary over time decrease the different violent crime rates by between 5%
for others.
and 8%, Aneja et al. (2011) found that RTC laws have a
negligible impact on murder but increase other violent
I. Introduction crime rates by 20% to 30%. Aneja et al. (2011) also report
that many of the point estimates are statistically insignifi-
identifying power, recognizing the tension between the Virginia. In an online appendix, we further illustrate the
strength of assumptions and their credibility. Research on approach by examining what can be inferred about the
RTC laws has commonly made invariance assumptions impact of RTC laws in Maryland and Illinois, two states
asserting that specified features of treatment response are that did not adopt RTC statutes during the period we study.
constant across space or time. These assumptions may be In section III, we illustrate the sensitivity of inferences to
too strong, but weaker assumptions asserting bounded var- different identifying restrictions but do not argue in a favor
iation may be credible. of any particular assumption. Here, as in earlier research,
For example, an invariance assumption may assert that we find it valuable to entertain a set of assumptions of vary-
neighboring states such as Virginia and Maryland have ing strength and determine how the strength of the assump-
identical environments and propensities for criminality. tions imposed affects the strength of the conclusions drawn.
This assumption may seem attractive because it enables (See Manski & Pepper, 2000, 2013, for other applications
contemporaneous comparison of the two states, but it may of this research philosophy).
not be credible. Yet it may be credible to assume that these In section IV, we motivate particular bounded-variation
states are similar to one another. Likewise, an invariance assumptions and present results on the impact of RTC laws
assumption may be that in the absence of RTC statutes, Vir- under these assumptions. Here, we find that RTC laws
ginia and Maryland would have experienced the same appear to reduce some crimes, increase others, and for
change in murder rates between two periods, say, 1988 and some, the results vary over time. In Virginia for example,
1990. This assumption enables difference-in-differences the data combined with these assumptions imply that the
analysis of treatment response, but, again, it may not be RTC law in the state reduced murder and larceny rates in
credible. Yet it may be credible to assume that the two nearly every year after 1989 but increased assaults after
states would have experienced similar changes. 1997. For other crimes, the sign of the bounds is generally
With this in mind, we formalize and apply a class of negative in the 1990s but positive or indeterminate in the
bounded-variation assumptions that flexibly restrict the var- 2000s. Section V draws conclusions.
iation of treatment response across states and years. These
assumptions generally do not point-identify the effects of
II. Data
RTC laws on crime rates. Instead, they partially identify
them, yielding bounds rather than precise conclusions.3 To evaluate the impact of RTC laws on crime, we use
Some readers may believe that partial identification ana- state-level data on annual crime rates (per 100,000 resi-
lysis cannot lead to informative conclusions about the dents) from 1970 to 2007. The focus on annual crime rates
effects of RTC laws on crime. Under very weak assump- within states has been common in the literature.4 However,
tions, it is correct that the data cannot reveal whether RTC we do not normalize crime rates to lie in the unit interval or
laws increase or decrease crime. However, under a specific take the natural log of the crime rate, as is done in much of
set of bounded-variation assumptions that we believe the literature. Rather we are interested in directly studying
worthy of consideration, we draw substantive conclusions state-year crime rates: 100,000 times the ratio of the num-
about the qualitative and quantitative impact of RTC ber of reported crimes to the population of the state. We
laws (see section IV). Moreover, our analysis makes trans- mostly focus on crime rates in Virginia. To further illustrate
parent how these conclusions depend on the maintained the bounded-variation assumptions, we examine crime rates
assumptions. in Maryland and Illinois in an online appendix.
The paper is organized as follows: After providing a brief The crime data, obtained from the FBI’s Uniform Crime
overview of the data in section II, section III formally Reports (UCR), were originally assembled by Lott and
defines the empirical question and the selection problem Mustard and have subsequently been modified, corrected,
and then introduces invariance and bounded-variation and updated several times. Our analysis uses the iteration
assumptions. Throughout, we allow for the possibility that assembled and evaluated by Aneja et al. (2011).5 For each
the effects of RTC laws vary across years, states, and state and year, we observe crime rates separately for mur-
crimes. To keep our task manageable, we focus on drawing der, rape, assault, robbery, auto theft, burglary, and larceny.
inferences on the impact of RTC laws in a single state,
4
Some studies take the county rather than the state as the geographic
unit of analysis, and most studies condition the analysis on characteristics
3
Partial identification analysis of treatment effects from observational of the state or county (e.g., demographics, number of police per capita, or
data was initiated in Manski (1990) and has developed subsequently. median county income). It may be of interest to perform more disaggre-
Manski (2007) provides a textbook exposition. The closest methodologi- gated analyses that examine crime commission by particular categories of
cal precedent to our study is the Manski and Pepper (2000) study of person or even by individuals. However, the requisite data to support such
monotone instrumental variable assumptions. The closest applied prece- analyses are not available. Likewise, rather than evaluating the effect of
dent to our study is the Manski and Pepper (2013) analysis of the deter- an RTC statute, it may be of interest to study how the number of RTC per-
rent effect of the death penalty, which uses some simple bounded-varia- mits affect crime. However, in general, data on the number of permits or
tion assumptions to examine data from two repeated cross-sections. In the number of persons carrying concealed handguns are not available
this paper, we introduce a much broader class of bounded-variation (Lott, 2010).
5
assumptions to evaluate annual state crime rates from multiple repeated The data were downloaded from http://works.bepress.com/john_dono
cross-sections. hue/89/ in June 2012.
234 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS
FIGURE 1.—MURDER AND ROBBERY RATES BY YEAR AND STATE and dropping faster in the 1990s. Virginia enacted an RTC
A: Murder Rate by Year and State statute in 1989.
14
10
350
300 the observed data on crime rates to motivate a particular set
250 Maryland of bounded-variation assumptions and explore, in some
200 Virginia detail, the inferences that arise from this set of assumptions.
150
Departing from conventional practice in applied econo-
100
metric analysis, we do not refer to our empirical findings as
50
0
‘‘estimates’’ and do not provide measures of statistical pre-
cision when studying the impact of RTC laws. Instead, we
1970
1972
1974
1976
1978
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
tive state-year crime rates. But what random process should from a superpopulation. Given that state populations are so
be assumed to have generated the existing United States, large, containing millions of persons, the sampling variabil-
with its realized state-year crime rates? ity of counts would be a negligible consideration except
There is no obvious answer, and the literature analyzing possibly when considering relatively rare crimes such as
RTC laws has not engaged the question. We do not argue murder.
that it would be impossible to specify a credible random In the setting of a randomized experimental design, Aba-
process generating the United States and base statistical die et al. (2014) raise similar concerns about drawing infer-
inference on this process, but doing so goes well beyond ences in state-level analyses and propose an alternative
the scope of this paper. We leave this an open question that approach for measuring uncertainty. In particular, they
may perhaps draw attention in our own future research or argue that if one observes the population, there is no sam-
that of others. pling variability, but there is statistical uncertainty if treat-
A reviewer has suggested that we compute confidence ments are assigned at random. The fact that one cannot
intervals using methods studied in the econometric litera- observe counterfactual outcomes creates randomization uncer-
ture on inference in settings with partial identification. tainty. Abadie et al. (2014) propose using randomization-
Existing methods for computing such confidence intervals based standard errors to express such uncertainty. They find
assume that the data are a random sample drawn from an that these standard errors are generally smaller than the
infinite population (see, e.g., Imbens & Manski, 2004; conventional sampling-based standard errors made under a
Chernozhukov, Hong, & Tamer, 2007; Chernozhukov, Lee, random sampling assumption.
& Rosen, 2013; and Kaido, Molinari, & Stoye, 2016). Like- This approach provides an alternative way to conceptua-
wise, random sampling assumptions are implicit in the lize uncertainty in cases where one observes a population
inferential methods used to estimate the standard errors of rather than a sample. The proposed randomized-based stan-
parameter estimates in the linear panel data models preva- dard errors, however, apply only when treatments are ran-
lent in the existing literature on RTC laws.9 Random sam- domly assigned, in which case the average treatment effect
pling assumptions, however, are not natural when consider- is point identified. Their approach is not applicable in
ing states or counties as units of observation. observational settings where the treatment, such as RTC
Similar concerns about the sampling process arise if one laws, may be endogenous.
takes the unit of analysis to be an individual person and
considers state crime rates to aggregate individual crime A. Treatment Effects and the Selection Problem
counts across the population of a state. To draw inferences
in this setting, one must have prior information on the sam- Consider the problem of inferring the average treatment
pling process generating the individuals who populate a effect (ATE) of an RTC statute on the rate of commission
state. Random sampling from an infinite population, the of a specified crime in a specified year in a group of states
underlying assumption used in the partial identification lit- that share specified observed covariates:
erature, applies if one is willing to assume that the realized ATEdx ¼ E½Yd ð1ÞjX E½Yd ð0ÞjX: (1)
population of a state in a given year is a random sample of
persons drawn from a superpopulation of potential state Outcome Yd(1) denotes the crime rate if a state were to have
residents and that crimes are committed independently by an RTC statute in year d, Yd(0) denotes the analogous out-
members of the population. However, this random sampling come if the state were not to have an RTC statute, X denotes
assumption may not be credible because commission of the specified covariates, and d indicates the specified year.
crimes may involve complex social interactions that are not To define the ATE, we consider the fifty states plus
independent across individuals or over time. Moreover, it Washington, DC, to be the population and use the expecta-
may not be credible to suppose that the observed population tion operator E[|X] to denote an average across states with
of a state in a given year is a random sample from some covariates X. The unit of observation being a state, the aver-
superpopulation. age treatment effect measures how the crime rate would dif-
Suppose that despite these concerns, one is willing to fer if all states with covariates X were to have an RTC sta-
assume that a state population is a random sample drawn tute in year d versus the rate if all such states did not have
an RTC law. The ATE can vary with d and X. We follow
9
the literature by assuming that treatment response is indivi-
There is an ongoing debate about the appropriate method of estimating
standard errors for the linear models used in the RTC literature (see Aneja dualistic; that is, an RTC law in state j may affect crime in
et al., 2011, and National Research Council, 2005). Many researchers state j but not elsewhere. Thus, there are no spillover effects
report standard errors that allow for arbitrary correlation within a state or to other states.
county—so-called state/county clustered standard errors—while others do
not allow for such correlations. The NRC report explains that these clus- For each state j and year d, there are two potential out-
tered sampling standard errors are inappropriate in the standard linear comes, Yjd(1) and Yjd(0). The former outcome is counterfac-
panel data models (with fixed county effects) used in the literature. Our tual if state j did not have an RTC statute in year d, while
concerns are distinct from these issues. We find no basis for reporting
standard errors using any of the conventional methods, allowing for clus- the latter is counterfactual if the state did have an RTC sta-
tering or not. tute. The fact that the data reveal only one of the two
236 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS
mutually exclusive outcomes constitutes the selection prob- TABLE 1.—MURDER RATES PER 100,000 RESIDENTS BY YEAR AND STATE
lem. The observed crime rate is Yjd(Zjd) ¼ Yjd(1) Zjd þ Year Maryland Virginia
Yjd(0) (1 Zjd), where Zjd ¼ 1 if state j has an RTC statute 1988 9.63 7.75
in year d and Zjd ¼ 0 otherwise. We henceforth write 1990 11.55 8.81
Yjd ¼ Yjd(Zjd) for short.
This model relies on the invariance assumption that the not formalize what this means. Instead, they perform ana-
effect of RTC laws, y, is the same for all states and all lyses that use some invariance assumptions as if they are
years. While this homogeneity assumption is convenient truth and that entirely dismiss other assumptions. For exam-
and has substantial identifying power when combined with ple, DID estimation maintains assumption (5) but places no
certain other assumptions, there is little support for the restrictions on response levels.
notion that the effects of RTC laws are identical across A simple way to improve the credibility of empirical
states and time. In fact, the empirical literature provides research is to weaken invariance assumptions to assump-
some evidence to the contrary. Some researchers have con- tions of bounded variation. In this paper, we report empiri-
cluded that the effects of RTC laws vary over time and cal findings under bounded-variation assumptions that
across states (see Black & Nagin, 1988; National Research weaken assumptions (3), (4), and (5) for a specified treat-
Council, 2005; Aneja et al., 2011; Durlauf et al., 2016). ment t as follows:
The Virginia and Maryland crime rates displayed in fig-
ure 1 provide direct evidence that the invariance assump- Bounded time variation : Yjd ðtÞ Yje ðtÞ djðdeÞ (7)
tions in equations (3), (4), and (5) do not hold across all
years and states. Figure 1 displays the annual murder rates Bounded interstate variation : Yjd ðtÞ Ykd ðtÞ dð jkÞd
in Maryland and Virginia from 1970 to 2007. While neither (8)
state had an RTC statute prior to 1989, crime rates vary
over time and across states from 1970 to 1988. For exam-
ple, in 1988, the murder rate in Virginia was 1.89 less than Bounded DID variation :
the rate in Maryland in that year and 0.39 greater than the Yjd ðtÞ Yje ðtÞ ½Ykd ðtÞ Yke ðtÞ dð jkÞðdeÞ ; (9)
Virginia rate in 1987.12 Thus, the invariance assumptions
are violated in the years before Virginia adopted an RTC where ( j, k) are specified states, (d, e) are specified years,
statute, and the signs and magnitudes of these violations and (dj(de), d( jk)d, d( jk)(de)) are specified positive constants.
differ over time and across assumptions. Manski and Pepper (2013) observed that the bounds on
While all three of these invariance assumptions are counterfactual quantities implied by such bounded-variation
rejected in the pre-1989 period, the existing literature on assumptions are solutions to linear programming problems
the effects of RTC laws on crime consistently applies these and, hence, are relatively easy to compute. (See also Laf-
types of restrictions, especially variations of the DID model férs, 2015.)
in equation (5) or the related model in equation (6). In this To simplify the notation, we suppress the dependence of
setting, researchers implicitly assume that the invariance the d values on the treatment t. We also suppress for simpli-
restrictions apply when outcomes are counterfactual even city the logical requirement that crime rates must take non-
though they are rejected in periods where outcomes are negative values. This requirement does not bind in the
observed. This is hard to motivate, and the literature using empirical analyses that we report.
these invariance assumptions fails to do so. Likewise, the The bounded-time variation assumption restricts the
variety of alternative but related difference-in-difference absolute difference in treatment response in state j between
type approaches that point-identify the average treatment two years, say, 1988 and 1990, to be less than dj(de). Letting
effect in data from repeated cross sections—for example, dj(de) 0 weakens the traditional time invariance assump-
the propensity score and the synthetic control (see Abadie, tion by supposing that response may differ over time by no
Diamond, & Hainmueller, 2010) approaches—rely on more than dj(de). The larger the selected value of dj(de), the
invariance assumptions that are difficult to motivate in this weaker the assumption. Similarly, the bounded interstate
application. variation assumption restricts the contemporaneous abso-
lute difference at year d in response between two states,
say, Virginia and Maryland, to be less than d( jk)d. Letting
C. Bounded-Variation Assumptions d( jk)d 0 weakens the traditional invariance assumption by
supposing that response across the two states may differ by
The Assumptions. Invariance assumptions have a sharp- no more than d( jk)d. The larger the selected value of d( jk)d,
ness that often makes them suspect. Consider each of the the weaker the assumption.
three equalities (3), (4), and (5) that point-identify the These bounded-variation assumptions have identifying
impact of the RCT law in Virginia in 1990. Why should power because they imply that counterfactual state-year
any of them hold exactly? Why should the treatment effect crime rates are similar to observed rates in other states
be exactly constant across states and years as assumed in and years. The degree of similarity is determined by the
the linear model, equation (6)? Empirical researchers often bound parameters (dj(de), d( jk)d, d( jk)(de)). These assumptions
say that such assumptions are approximations, but they do resemble the smoothing assumptions made in kernel non-
12
parametric regression analysis, with d acting as the band-
Also notice that the time invariance assumption does not hold in
Maryland, where the murder rate increased from 9.63 in 1988 to 11.55 in width (aka tuning parameter). A fundamental difference is
1990. that the asymptotic theory for nonparametric regression
238 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS
FIGURE 2.—BOUNDS ON THE TREATMENT EFFECTS AS A FUNCTION OF d Bounded-variation assumptions can be easily adapted to
8 fit particular features of the application. For example, figure
6
1 reveals that crime rates in Maryland generally exceed the
4
2
contemporaneous crime rates in Virginia, even in the years
0 UB Time Invariance before 1989 when neither state had adopted an RTC statute.
TE
To simplify the presentation, the murder rates reported in this table are rounded to the nearest whole number (except for the 1990 murder rate in Virginia). Bounds highlighted in dark gray are infeasible. Bounds highlighted in light gray and bold identify the sign of the TE to
highly similar in 1990 and that (1988, 1990) are highly
UB
0.8
1.3
1.8
2.3
2.8
2.8
2.8
2.8
2.8
2.8
2.8
2.8
2.8
similar years in Virginia.
0.8
0.3
0.2
0.7
1.2
1.7
2.2
2.7
3.2
3.7
4.2
4.7
5.2
Second, the assumptions point-identify the TE for a variety
LB
6 of feasible values (i.e., dVA(1990,1988) þ d(MD,VA)1990 ¼ 4),
UB
0.8
1.3
1.8
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3
and they identify the sign of the TE for others. For example,
0.8 when dVA(1990,1988) ¼ d(MD,VA)1990 ¼ 2, the TE is identified
0.3
0.2
0.7
1.2
1.7
2.2
2.7
3.2
3.7
4.2
4.7
5.2
LB
5.5
0.8
0.3
nia in 1990.
The type of sensitivity analysis performed here,
0.7
0.7
0.7
0.7
0.7
0.7
0.7
0.7
0.7
0.7
0.7
0.7
0.7
UB
such rule exists: the data alone cannot identify the counter-
factual outcomes.
0.8
0.3
0.2
0.7
1.2
1.7
2.2
2.7
3.2
3.7
4.2
4.7
5.2
LB
2
3.2
3.2
3.2
3.2
3.2
3.2
3.2
3.2
3.2
3.2
3.2
3.2
3.2
UB
1.5
2.5
3.5
4.5
5.5
0
TABLE 3.—BOUNDED-VARIATION PARAMETERS 1972, and so forth), and then select the maximum
Interstate Time DID DID_0.75 of these values. Table 3 displays the minimum parameters
Murder 2.7 2.0 2.3 1.2
that ensure the bounded-variation assumptions are consis-
Rape 17 4 6 3 tent with the observed pre-1989 data on various crime rates.
Aggravated assault 324 39 60 34 For murder, the interstate variation parameter is at least 2.7,
Robbery 292 30 55 27
Auto theft 371 46 61 43 the time variation parameter needs to be at least 2.0, and
Burglary 496 206 136 67 the DID variation parameter at least 2.3. For robbery, the
Larceny 775 410 175 93 analogous parameters are 292, 30, and 55.13
These parameters are found by taking the maximum of the minimum parameter value for the models
to be consistent with the data in each year prior to 1989. The DID_0.75 parameter is the 0.75 quantile.
We use the parameter values displayed in table 3 as a
starting point for implementing the bounded-variation
assumptions in equations (7), (8), and (9). Of course,
tutes prior to 2007. In section IVD, we discuss and summar- whether these particular assumptions are valid is unknown,
ize the results. and one must invariably make judgments about the trade-
off between the strength and credibility of assumptions and
A. Selecting the Bound Parameters findings. Using these parameters as an anchor, one might
assess the sensitivity of findings by using some multiple of
In section III, we assessed how inferences vary across the maximum value or some quantile of the distribution.
different values of the bound parameters d. In this section, Table 3, for example, shows the 0.75 quantile of the mini-
we use observed data in Virginia and Maryland to develop mum valid parameters for the DID assumption (DID_0.75).
sensible data-based parameter values. In particular, we use In this case, the DID parameter for murder falls from 2.3 to
data prior to 1989, when Virginia did not have an RTC sta- 1.2, and for robbery it falls from 55 to 27.
tute, to determine the minimum parameter values that
would be required to make bounded-variation assumptions
consistent with the observed data. While this approach does
B. The Impact of a RTC Statute in Virginia
not ensure the validity of the bounded-variation assump-
tions, it provides what we believe to be a reasonable starting In this section, we use bounded-variation assumptions
point for our analysis. with the parameter values displayed in table 3 as a starting
To illustrate the idea, consider the murder rates for Mary- point for drawing inferences on the impact of an RTC law
land and Virginia in 1987 and 1988. The observed murder on crime in VA. Tables 4 and 5 display findings on the TE
rates vary over time and across states: the 1988 murder rate of an RTC statute in Virginia by year from 1990 to 2006
in Virginia is 7.75, and the rate in Maryland is 9.63, while and for seven different crimes. Each set of results applies a
the analogous rates for 1987 are 7.36 and 9.55, respectively. different assumption. Recall, as discussed in section III, that
Neither state had an RTC statute in these years, so these we do not report measures of sampling variability. Valid
data can be used to test whether invariance and bounded- standard errors reflecting uncertainty due to the sampling
variation assumptions are valid. In fact, the data are process would likely have an impact on some of the qualita-
inconsistent with the time invariance assumption (3), the tive conclusions about the effect of RTC laws on crime,
interstate invariance assumption (4), and the DID assump-
tion (5). 13
There are many other ways to generate plausible restrictions on the
While the invariance assumptions are inconsistent with bounded parameters using the pre-1989 data. For example, rather than
finding parameters based on the observed absolute differences, one could
the observed pre-1989 data, the bound parameters in compute separate bounds on the maximum positive difference and the
assumptions (7), (8), and (9) can be chosen to ensure inter- maximum negative difference. Assumption (10), where the difference in
nal consistency. The bounded interstate variation assump- the crime rates between Maryland and Virginia is assumed to be nonnega-
tive, is a variant on this idea. This approach weakly narrows one side of
tion in equation (8), for example, is valid in 1988 if the bounded parameters and thus will generally give tighter bounds on the
d(VA,MD)1988 1.88 (¼ 9.63 7.75). Likewise, the bounded average treatment effect. An alternative approach would be to compare
time variation assumption is consistent with the Virginia observed rates in both adjacent and nonadjacent years. This will weakly
increase the bound parameters, and thus generally give wider bounds on
1988 murder rate if dVA(1988,1987) 0.39 (¼ 7.75 7.36), the average treatment effect. For example, if we compare crime rates
and the DID assumption is valid if d(VA,MD)(1988,1987) separated by two years, the difference-in-difference parameter for murder
0.31. These restrictions on the bound parameters make the remains at 2.3, but the parameter on robbery increases from 55 to 75. If
we compare crime rates separated by ten years, the parameter for murder
bounded-variation assumptions consistent with the 1987 and increases to 3, and the parameter on robbery increases to 79.
1988 data. Moreover, one can refine or expand the analysis to introduce additional
Extending this approach to perform comparisons bounded-variation restrictions and refined measures of d. For example,
one might include other states or evaluate county crime rates. Likewise,
from 1970 to 1988, we find the minimum values of the one might consider the crime rate in Maryland after excluding Baltimore.
bound parameters required for the assumptions to be consis- These and other variations would allow one to apply additional moment
tent with the data prior to 1989. To do this, we compute the restrictions on the counterfactual outcomes and develop refined measures
of closeness, d. For this paper, we focus our analysis on two states, Virgi-
minimum valid parameter value for each pair of nia and Maryland, over multiple years. This focus keeps our task manage-
adjacent years from 1970 to 1988 (1970 to 1971, 1971 to able and results in transparent findings.
HOW DO RIGHT-TO-CARRY LAWS AFFECT CRIME RATES? 241
TABLE 4.—THE TE OF AN RTC LAW IN VIRGINIA GIVEN THE DID INVARIANCE MODEL, BY YEAR AND CRIME TYPE
Murder Rape Assault Robbery Auto Theft Burglary Larceny
1990 0.9 4.7 3.9 52.0 10.9 26.9 246.3
1991 0.6 5.9 11.1 81.1 22.1 12.9 45.4
1992 1.4 4.9 10.0 103.1 51.4 61.8 165.3
1993 2.6 1.9 11.5 105.4 29.3 105.4 206.9
1994 1.0 2.2 0.7 82.3 115.8 45.2 304.4
1995 2.4 5.1 9.5 104.0 56.3 102.4 499.7
1996 2.2 0.8 1.1 83.0 63.8 44.0 373.8
1997 0.7 1.5 28.6 23.7 49.0 7.1 285.8
1998 1.9 3.3 38.9 4.7 91.0 0.5 296.4
1999 1.4 5.1 48.6 26.1 139.7 2.0 222.5
2000 0.6 3.8 22.5 21.6 82.7 47.9 381.7
2001 1.3 7.7 23.5 32.4 36.8 28.7 231.6
2002 2.2 10.1 19.4 37.3 1.8 66.6 174.8
2003 2.0 9.9 33.9 37.6 48.2 53.9 65.8
2004 2.3 10.6 20.9 50.4 43.6 84.8 18.9
2005 2.0 10.7 45.8 29.8 29.2 112.4 39.1
2006 2.6 12.5 65.8 33.5 19.6 111.3 109.3
Treatment effects in bold identify the sign to be negative and in italics text are identified to be positive.
TABLE 5.—BOUNDS ON THE TE OF AN RTC LAW IN VIRGINIA GIVEN THE JOINT DID, INTERSTATE, AND
TIME-BOUNDED VARIATION MODELS (ASSUMPTIONS A, B, AND C), BY YEAR AND CRIME TYPE
Murder Rape Assault Robbery Auto Theft Burglary Larceny
LB UB LB UB LB UB LB UB LB UB LB UB LB UB
1990 2.0 0.0 7.9 1.4 38.0 13.1 79.2 24.7 53.6 10.9 94.3 81.9 153.2 291.6
1991 1.7 0.3 9.2 2.7 23.0 28.1 108.3 53.8 64.9 22.1 80.3 29.5 47.8 138.6
1992 2.6 0.6 8.2 1.7 44.1 7.0 130.4 75.9 94.1 51.4 129.2 104.5 258.5 72.1
1993 3.7 1.7 5.2 1.4 45.6 5.5 132.7 78.2 72.0 29.3 172.8 142.4 300.1 113.7
1994 2.1 0.2 5.4 1.1 34.8 16.3 109.6 55.1 158.6 115.8 112.6 172.5 397.6 211.3
1995 3.5 1.5 8.3 1.8 43.6 7.5 131.2 76.7 99.0 56.3 169.8 216.2 592.9 406.5
1996 3.4 1.4 4.1 0.1 33.0 18.1 110.2 55.7 106.5 63.8 111.4 223.9 467.0 280.7
1997 1.9 0.1 1.8 4.7 5.4 45.6 51.0 3.6 6.2 49.0 74.5 60.3 379.0 192.6
1998 3.0 1.1 0.1 6.6 4.8 55.9 32.0 22.5 48.2 91.0 67.9 67.0 389.6 203.3
1999 2.0 0.6 1.9 8.4 32.1 65.7 1.2 53.3 97.0 139.7 69.5 65.4 315.7 129.4
2000 1.7 0.3 0.5 7.0 13.5 5.5 5.7 48.8 40.0 82.7 19.6 115.3 474.8 288.5
2001 2.5 0.5 4.5 11.0 15.4 6.5 5.2 59.7 6.0 36.8 38.7 96.1 324.8 138.5
2002 2.4 1.4 6.9 13.4 15.0 2.3 10.1 64.6 44.5 1.8 0.8 134.0 267.9 81.6
2003 2.1 1.2 6.6 13.1 6.0 50.9 10.4 64.9 55.7 48.2 13.6 121.3 158.9 27.4
2004 2.5 1.5 7.4 13.9 3.3 38.0 23.2 77.7 65.7 43.6 17.4 152.2 74.2 112.1
2005 1.7 1.1 7.4 14.0 11.7 62.8 2.6 57.1 71.9 29.2 45.0 179.8 54.1 132.2
2006 2.5 1.8 9.2 15.8 31.8 82.9 6.2 60.7 23.1 19.6 43.9 178.7 202.4 16.1
Bounds highlighted in dark gray are infeasible. Bounds highlighted in light gray and bold identify the sign of the TE to be negative, and those in light gray and italics are identified to be positive.
especially for highlighted findings that are close to 0 and TE. To see this, add and subtract the DID parameters in
for rare crimes such as murder. table 3 to the findings in table 4. For example, the impact of
Table 4 presents results for all seven crimes and all years RTC laws on the 2000 murder rate is bounded between
under the DID invariance assumption. We use 1988 as the [0.6 2.3, 0.6 þ 2.3] ¼ [2.9, 1.7]. The bound on the
anchor year for the DID invariance assumption. Findings in impact on the 2005 burglary rate is [24, 248].
bold identify the TE to be negative while those in italics are The results from these two DID assumptions provide a
positive. For murder, the DID assumption findings are stark illustration of the trade-off between the strength of
strictly negative. For the other crimes, the findings are nega- assumptions and conclusions. The strong invariance form
tive in earlier years but tend to be positive in later years. of the DID assumption point-identifies the TE, but the
For example, the RTC statute is found to have increased the weaker bounded-variation form of this assumption gener-
2005 burglary rate by 112.4. ally does not identify even the sign of the TE.
These results, however, rely on a strict invariance Partial identification analysis jointly using variations of
assumption. If we use the parameter values in table 3 to assumptions (7), (8), and (9) allows us to bridge the gap
relax this invariance restriction to a bounded-variation DID between these two extremes by considering middle-ground
assumption, nearly all of the bounds except those for lar- assumptions that yield information on the sign of the TE.
ceny include 0. That is, under the bounded DID variation To do this, we continue to apply DID bounded-variation
assumption, we cannot generally identify the sign of the assumptions and also use bounded time and interstate varia-
242 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS
tion assumptions that seem well suited for this application. upper bound. Findings that are not highlighted do not iden-
In particular, we impose the following three assumptions: tify the sign of the TE. The results vary by crime and year.
We find that the RTC law in Virginia reduced murder and
A. j½Y VA,d (0) Y VA,e (0) ½Y MD,d (0) Y MD,e (0)j larceny rates in nearly every year but increased assaults
d(VA,MD)(de), where d(VA,MD)(de) ¼ DID_0.75 in after 1997. For other crimes, the sign of the bounds is gen-
table 3 for d [ [1990, 2006] and e ¼ 1988 erally negative in the 1990s but positive or indeterminate in
B. 0 Y M D , d (0) Y V A , d (0) d ( M D , V A ) d , where the 2000s.
d(MD,VA)d ¼ interstate in table 3 for d [ [1990, 2006] Interestingly, these results are generally inconsistent with
C. Y V A , d (0) Y V A , 8 8 (0) for d [ [1990, 1996]; the standard assumption that the TE does not vary over time
YVA,d(0) YVA,88(0) for d [ [1999, 2006] (see model [6]). To see this, note that under the assumption
that the TE is the same in every year, one can take the inter-
Assumption A is the DID bounded-variation assumption— section of the bounds from each year to derive a refined
assumption (9)—where the bound parameter equals the tighter bound. This is an instrumental variable bound, as
0.75 quantile of the distribution of the minimum bound defined in Manski (1990). Yet the intersection bounds are
parameters required for the assumptions to be consistent empty for all seven crimes; the lower bound exceeds the
with the data in each year prior to 1989 (see the DID_0.75 upper bound. For example, the lower and upper intersection
column in table 3). This assumption relaxes the strict bounds for robbery are 23.2 and 78.2. Thus, this bounded-
invariance assumption where d ¼ 0 but strengthens the variation assumption is inconsistent with the homogeneous
bounded-variation assumption using the DID parameters in treatment effect assumption in model (6).
table 3. Assumption B is the one-sided bounded interstate
variation assumption—assumption (10)—which restricts D. Discussion of Results
the crime rate in Virginia to be no greater than the crime
rate in Maryland. Finally, assumption C is a bounded time Our findings about the impact of RTC laws on crime are
variation assumption that operationalizes the idea that crime nuanced and not amenable to a simple punch-line conclu-
rates rose in the early 1990s and fell in the 2000s.14 sion. Inferences are sensitive to assumptions. Under the
We do not apply the bounded time variation assumption weakest assumptions, we cannot identify whether RTC laws
(7). This assumption is not flexible enough to account for increase or decrease crime. Under stronger assumptions, we
the large temporal changes in crime rates over 1970 to find that adoption of the RTC statute in Virginia has
2006. To identify the counterfactual crime rate that would reduced some crimes (e.g., murder), increased others, and
have occurred had Virginia not adopted a RTC law, the had ambiguous sign effects on others. For some crimes, the
time variation assumption in equation (7) adds and subtracts findings vary across years, indicating that the RTC law
dVA(d,88) to the observed crime rate in 1988. This bound reduced the crime rate in the 1990s but increased it in the
on the counterfactual crime rate does not depend on the 2000s.
year under consideration, d—the bound is the same for When the signs of the TE are identified for Virginia, the
1989 and 2006—even though there were significant magnitudes are generally large. For example, using the
changes in observed crime rates over this period. Thus, middle-ground DID assumption (see table 5), RTC laws are
while the bounded-variation parameter dVA(d,88) in table 3 found to reduce the Virginia murder rate in 1995 by at least
may be sensible when evaluating the counterfactual crime 16% (from 9.1 to 7.6), the rape rate by at least 6%, the rob-
rate in 1989, it is hard to defend when evaluating the rate in bery rate by at least 37%, and the larceny rate by at least
2006. In fact, if we add in the standard bounded time varia- 13%. In contrast, in 2005, RTC laws are found to reduce
tion assumption in equation (7), just over two out of every the murder rate by at least 15% but increase the rape rate by
five of the bounds are infeasible, with the lower bound at least 47%, the assault rate by at least 8%, the robbery rate
being above the upper bound. by at least 3%, and the burglary rate by at least 13%.
Table 5 displays the findings using these bounded-varia- These findings of heterogeneous effects across years may
tion assumptions. Findings highlighted in light gray identify partially explain why the findings obtained with homoge-
the sign of the treatment effect, with those in bold as nega- nous response assumptions like equation (6) are sensitive to
tive and those in italics as positive. Findings highlighted in the years of data included in the sample. Analyses per-
dark gray are infeasible, the lower bound being above the formed using more recent data tend to find that RTC laws
have negligible or even positive effects on violent crime,
whereas the same analyses performed using data through
14
In general, the bounds are not sensitive to the cutoff dates used for the early 1990s tend to find that RTC laws decrease violent
the bounded time variation assumption C. For example, changing the cut-
off years from 1996 to 1995 and 1999 to 2000 does not change any of the crime rates. (See Aneja et al., 2011, and National Research
qualitative conclusions. If we drop assumption C altogether, 10% of the Council 2005, tables 6-5 and 6-6.)
bounds are affected, but only a handful of the qualitative results change. Given that the effects vary over time and across crimes
In particular, without assumption C, the bounds for assault in 2003 and
2004 are not identified to be positive, and the bounds for burglary from and in many cases do not reveal the sign of the TE, it is dif-
1990 to 1993 are not identified to be negative. ficult to provide a simple assessment of the overall efficacy
HOW DO RIGHT-TO-CARRY LAWS AFFECT CRIME RATES? 243
of the RTC law in Virginia. One’s perspective will necessa- In this paper, we have not considered prospective analysis.
rily depend both on the assumption that seems most plausi- The literature on RTC laws, including this paper, may pro-
ble, if any, as well as how to weigh results that vary over vide policymakers useful retrospective information. It is not,
time and across crimes. Under the weaker assumptions, the per se, informative about prospective questions and, in parti-
bounds generally do not identify the sign of the TE and thus cular, about what would happen if an RTC statute were to be
provide little guidance about whether RTC laws increase or adopted in a state that does not currently have such a law.
decrease crime. Under the stronger DID invariance assump-
tion (table 4), RTC laws are found to have reduced crime in V. Conclusion: Incredible Certitude
the early 1990s and have mixed effects a decade later,
in the 2000s. Similar but less definitive results are found Given that research on RTC laws is often inconclusive,
under the middle-ground assumption used to generate the contradictory, and confusing, the research community has
results displayed in table 5. been largely marginalized in this important policy debate.
To assess the overall benefit of an RTC statute, one must Why? Researchers are rewarded for producing simple find-
somehow aggregate the effects across the different crimes. ings leading to definitive policy prescriptions (e.g., more
Obviously the decision of how to weight the effects for dif- guns leads to less crime), yet generating such findings
ferent crimes is a complex and subjective undertaking. A requires strong assumptions that cannot be persuasively
simple metric might be to count the aggregate change in defended. In this setting, researchers report findings with
crimes. In this case, using the results from table 5, one ‘‘incredible certitude’’ rather than expressing due caution
would conclude that RTC laws tended to decrease the num- (Manski, 2013). Drawing inferences about the effects of
ber of crimes in the 1990s but increase the total number of RTC laws, or gun policy more generally, is an inherently
crimes in the 2000s. difficult undertaking: conclusions are highly sensitive to the
Instead, one might adjust the raw counts for the fact that data and assumptions, the available data are limited, and a
some crimes are more costly to society than others. A num- wide range of assumptions, and thus conclusions are consis-
ber of researchers have sought to estimate the average costs tent with the data. Researchers combining data with differ-
of different crimes.15 By combining the effects of RTC laws ent maintained assumptions reach different logically valid
on crime rates with a set of cost estimates, one can compute conclusions yet fail to adequately express sensitivity of the
how the average costs of crime would change if an RTC findings to untestable assumptions.
statute were to be adopted in Virginia. While admittedly a For empirical research on complex policies such as gun
tenuous exercise, this might provide a rough snapshot of the laws, and RTC laws in particular, to be informative to the
aggregate impact of RTC laws on crime. policy debate, we believe it is critical that the discussion
A final complication in evaluating the impact of RTC move away from this paradigm of incredible certitude
laws arises because the results reported are retrospective, toward an honest portrayal of partial knowledge (Manski,
not prospective. The two forms of analysis differ in their 2013). Adequate expression of caution goes beyond using
objectives. Researchers performing retrospective analysis temperate language, replicating results under marginally
aim to learn past treatment effects in a study population, different assumptions, or reporting confidence intervals.
asking questions such as: What do we know about the Although helpful, these means of expressing caution do not
effects of RTC laws in Virginia from 1990 to 2006? A cen- go nearly far enough. Drawing inferences under a variety
tral objective of prospective analysis is to inform treatment of assumptions that are not credible does not resolve the
choice in a future population, asking questions of the form: problem. Adequate expression of caution requires formal
What would happen if a state were to adopt an RTC statute methods to perform empirical research under assumptions
in 2018? that are weak enough to be credible.
Prospective analysis is more difficult than retrospective In this paper, we develop and apply one such set of
analysis. Empirical evidence on treatment response is assumptions: bounded-variation assumptions. These assump-
entirely absent prospectively, but it is partially present ret- tions, which relax the traditional invariance assumptions
rospectively after the outcomes of realized treatments are applied in the literature, provide an intuitive, simple, and flex-
observed. Under a time-invariance assumption, as applied ible way to improve the credibility of empirical research,
in assumption (6), the answer is straightforward: the impact assess the sensitivity of inferences to different identifying
of RTC laws does not vary over time. Yet this assumption restrictions, and apply middle-ground assumptions that
is not tenable. One must address the forecasting problem sometimes identify the sign of the TE.
inherent in prospective inference. The results reveal the inherent trade-off between the
strength of assumptions and findings. Even under the stron-
15
As might be expected, there is a great deal of variation in these cost- gest invariance models, the TE of an RTC statute varies
of-crime estimates, but they all imply that murder is many times more across crimes, states, and time. Findings under the more
costly than any other crime. For example, McCollister, French, and Fang credible bounded-variation models suggest even greater
(2010) estimate that the average cost (in 2008 dollars) of a murder is
nearly $9 million, whereas the average cost of a rape, the next most costly degrees of ambiguity, with many results not identifying the
offense, is $241,000. sign of the TE and others varying over time and across
244 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS
states. Still, under these assumptions, we find that the RTC Duggan, Mark, ‘‘More Guns, More Crime,’’ Journal of Political Economy
109 (2001), 1086–1114.
law in Virginia reduced murder and larceny rates in nearly Durlauf, Steven. N., Salvador Navarro, and David A. Rivers, ‘‘Model
every year but increased assaults after 1997. For other Uncertainty and the Effect of Shall-Issue Right-to-Carry Laws on
crimes, the sign of the bounds is generally negative in the Crime,’’ European Economic Review 81 (2016), 32–67.
Imbens, Guido, and Charles F. Manski, ‘‘Confidence Intervals for Par-
1990s but positive or indeterminate in the 2000s. tially Identified Parameters,’’ Econometrica 72 (2004), 1845–
These results are informative but they are inconsistent 1857.
with the notion that RTC laws uniformly increase or Kaido, Hiroaki, Francesca Molinari, and Jorg Stoye, ‘‘Confidence Inter-
vals for Projections of Identified Parameters,’’ Department of Eco-
decrease crime. In this light, we do not report findings with nomics, Cornell University (2016).
incredible certitude: there are no simple conclusions. Still, Lafférs, Lukas, ‘‘Bounding Average Treatment Effects Using Linear Pro-
our findings may inform the policy debate by providing gramming,’’ cemmap working paper CWP70/15 (2015).
Lott, John R, More Guns, Less Crime: Understanding Crime and Gun-
credible information that constrains the resulting discussion Control Laws (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2010).
to lie within a set of bounds. Lott, John R., and David Mustard, ‘‘Crime, Deterrence and Right-to-
Carry Concealed Handguns,’’ Journal of Legal Studies 26 (1997),
REFERENCES 1–68.
Manski, Charles F., ‘‘Nonparametric Bounds on Treatment Effects,’’
Abadie, Alberto, Susan Athey, Guido Imbens, and Jeffrey Wooldridge, American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 80 (1990),
‘‘Finite Population Causal Standard Errors,’’ NBER working paper 319–323.
20325 (2014). ——— ‘‘Monotone Treatment Response,’’ Econometrica 65 (1997),
Abadie, Alberto, Alexis Diamond, and Jens Hainmueller, ‘‘Synthetic Con- 1311–1334.
trol Methods for Comparative Case Studies: Estimating the Effect ——— Identification for Prediction and Decision (Cambridge, MA: Har-
of California’s Tobacco Control Program,’’ Journal of the Ameri- vard University Press, 2007).
can Statistical Association 105 (2010), 493–505. ——— Public Policy in an Uncertain World: Analysis and Decisions
Aneja, Abhay, John J. Donohue, and Alexandria Zhang, ‘‘The Impact of (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2013).
Right-to-Carry Laws and the NRC Report: Lessons for the Empiri- Manski, Charles F., and John V. Pepper, ‘‘Monotone Instrumental Vari-
cal Evaluation of Law and Policy,’’ American Law and Economic ables: With an Application to the Returns to Schooling,’’ Econo-
Review 13 (2011), 565–632. metrica 68 (2000), 997–1010.
Black, Dan A., and Daniel S. Nagin, ‘‘Do Right-to-Carry Laws Deter Vio- ——— ‘‘Deterrence and the Death Penalty: Partial Identification Analysis
lent Crime?’’ Journal of Legal Studies 27 (1998), 209–219. Using Repeated Cross Sections,’’ Journal of Quantitative Crimin-
Chernozhukov, Victor, Han Hong, and Elie Tamer, ‘‘Estimation and Con- ology 29 (2013), 123–141.
fidence Regions for Parameter Sets in Econometric Models,’’ McCollister, Kathryn E., Michael T. French, and Hai Fang, ‘‘The Cost of
Econometrica 75 (2007), 1243–1284. Crime to Society: New Crime-Specific Estimates for Policy and
Chernozhukov, Victor, Simon Lee, and Adam Rosen, ‘‘Intersection Bounds: Program Evaluation,’’ Drug and Alcohol Dependence 102 (2010),
Estimation and Inference,’’ Econometrica 81 (2013), 668–737. 98–109.
Cochran, William G., Sampling Techniques (New York: Wiley, 1977). National Research Council, Firearms and Violence: A Critical Review,
Deaton, Angus, The Analysis of Household Surveys (Baltimore: Johns edited by C. Wellford, J. Pepper, and C. Petrie (Washington, DC:
Hopkins University Press, 1997). National Academy Press, 2005).
Donohue, John J., and Steven Levitt, ‘‘Guns, Violence, and the Efficiency Richardson, Amy, Michael G. Hudgens, Peter B. Gilbert, and Jason P.
of Illegal Markets,’’ American Economic Review 88 (1998), 463– Fine, ‘‘Nonparametric Bounds and Sensitivity Analysis of Treat-
467. ment Effects,’’ Statistical Science 29 (2014), 596–618.