Advanced Macroeconomics, 2024-2025: Intertemporal Choices Over Infinite Horizon Etienne Wasmer
Advanced Macroeconomics, 2024-2025: Intertemporal Choices Over Infinite Horizon Etienne Wasmer
Etienne Wasmer
NYUAD
February 9, 2025
1/53
Moving towards infinity (2) Ramsey - simplified
2/53
Ramsey - simplified
3/53
Notation: utility
4/53
Notation: utility, continued
5/53
Debt/savings in an infinite horizon
6/53
Transversality condition
7/53
Transversality condition
8/53
Maximization of the agent
subject to at+1 = at Rt + yt − ct
9/53
Maximization of the agent
10/53
Maximization of the agent
▶ Max Lagrangian
+∞
X
L= β t u(ct ) − λt [at+1 − at (1 + rt ) − yt + ct ]
t=0
β t u ′ (ct ) = λt
λt+1 (1 + rt+1 ) = λt
▶ Combine
β t u ′ (ct ) = λt
and
λt+1 (1 + rt+1 ) = λt
▶ Leads to:
β t u ′ (ct ) = β t+1 u ′ (ct+1 )(1 + rt+1 )
or the Euler equation:
12/53
Maximization of the agent: an intuition
▶ Now use:
at+1 = at Rt + yt − ct
▶ Implies:
13/53
Maximization of the agent
▶ From
one has
∂ct+1
= −Rt+1
∂ct
for a given at (predetermined) and at+2 (affected only later,
by ct+1 ) and income profile.
▶ Key: if I consume more today, I need to reduce my
consumption tomorrow by Rt+1 if I want to reach the same
net position at+2
14/53
Maximization of the agent
▶ Using
∂ct+1
= −Rt+1
∂ct
derive with respect to ct in the infinite sum:
▶ The ways of deriving the Euler equations are diverse and can
also be derived from a recursive formulation. See Sargent and
Ljunqvist (Fourth edition).
15/53
Maximization of the agent
T
X −yt + ct aT +1
a0 = +
t=0
R0 R1 ...Rt R0 R1 ...RT
16/53
Maximization of the agent
17/53
Maximization of the agent
+∞ +∞
" #
X
t
X −yt + ct
L= β u(ct ) + λ a0 −
R0 R1 ...Rt
t=0 t=0
1
β t u ′ (ct ) = λ
R0 R1 ...Rt
and for the next period, derivative with respect to ct+1 :
1
β t+1 u ′ (ct+1 ) = λ
R0 R1 ...Rt Rt+1
▶ Take the ratio and no surprise,
18/53
NB: Euler with uncertainty - class 1
u ′ (ct+1 )
βEt Rt+1 =1
u ′ (ct )
19/53
In the special case of the iso-elastic utility
▶ Uses the derivative of utility to get:
−θ
βRt+1 ct+1 = ct−θ
▶ Log linearize:
ct+1 − ct log (βR)
=
ct θ
▶ In continuous time:
c˙t log (βR)
=
ct θ
▶ The higher the desire to smooth (corresponding to a higher
θ), the lower the chosen growth of consumption.
▶ This superposes to the effect of conflicting forces between
preferences for the present β and market conditions about the
future R.
▶ What if βR = 1?
20/53
And with constant returns
21/53
This is true at any time period say t0
▶ Consumption rule :
∞
" #
X
−(t−t0 )
ct0 = µ at0 R + R yt
t=t0
22/53
Application: effect of income shocks
∂ct
= µR −T < µ
∂yt+T
23/53
Production side
24/53
A preview: the modified Golden rule
r ∗ = f ′ (k ∗ ) = n + δ
▶ Called Modified Golden Rule: now includes the preference for
the present of agents.
▶ Which raises the returns to capital
▶ That is, reduce accumulation of capital
▶ Because agents prefer consumption today to future (steady)
state-consumption.
25/53
Production side
26/53
Production side, continued
f ′ (kt ) = rt
wt = f (kt ) − kt f ′ (kt )
27/53
Production side, continued
yt = f (kt ) = wt + kt f ′ (kt )
28/53
Combine demand of the consumer and production
▶ Assets are simply the capital stock (assumed liquid, full resale
value, no depreciation):
at = kt
kt+1 − kt = f (kt ) − ct
ct = f (kt ) − (kt+1 − kt )
▶ Preferences of consumers:
29/53
Dynamic system
30/53
Steady-state
becomes:
1 = β(1 + r ∗ )
31/53
Steady-state
▶ From it,
f ′ (k ∗ ) = r = 1/β − 1
1
▶ We had a notation for β = where σ is a psychological
1+σ
discount factor (and 1 + σ was a MRS).
▶ So r ∗ = σ: the interest rate equals the psychological discount
factor, and
1 + r ∗ = MRS
Everything reconnects! When is consumption maximized? Is
this is a Golden rule ? (when g = n = 0: efficient
consumption?).
32/53
Steady-state with population growth
33/53
Intuition for why the formula contains n when it is
positive?
▶ Because now,
(1 + r ∗ )/(1 + n) = (1 + σ)
▶ And then
r ∗ = f ′ (k ∗ ) = σ + n
(first order approximation)
▶ Except, as in most textbooks, if utility discount also includes
population growth (σ becomes σ − n). Not our choice here. 34/53
Steady-state with population growth
r∗ = σ + n > n
35/53
Summary: steady-state consumption and capital
r ∗ = f ′ (k ∗ ) = σ
▶ If n > 0 then
r ∗ = f ′ (k ∗ ) = σ + n
36/53
Steady-state consumption and capital
r ∗ = f ′ (k ∗ ) = σ + n + δ
r ∗ = f ′ (k ∗ ) = n + δ
▶ Called Modified Golden Rule: now includes the preference for
the present of agents.
▶ Which raises the returns to capital
▶ That is, reduce accumulation of capital
▶ Because agents prefer consumption today to future (steady)
state-consumption.
37/53
Exercise
38/53
Steady-state consumption and capital
▶ Additional subtleties with technical progress g
▶ It enters in the modified Golden rule but as θg , that is, as in
the Golden rule only if θ = 1 (Cobb-Douglas utility).
▶ In that case:
r ∗ = f ′ (k ∗ ) = σ + n + δ + θg
k˙t = g (t, zt , kt )
41/53
More general method using optimization tools
42/53
More general method using optimization tools
∂H(t, kt , zt , µt )
=0
∂z
∂H(t, kt , zt , µt )
= −µ˙t
∂k
▶ It exists and is unique under some assumptions, typically of
(strict) concavity with respect to kt of H (actually its max
with respect to zt ).
▶ That’s (almost) all you need to know in continuous time
macro. A good and exhaustive presentation to it is Chapter 7 (pp 227-285) of Introduction to
Modern Economic Growth, MIT Press, by Daron Acemoglu.
43/53
Discounting in continuous time
1
▶ Start from β = if time period last 1.
1+σ
▶ If periods last an arbitrary small unit of time dt,
1
β= ≈ 1 − σdt
1 + σdt
▶ Continuous time: dt → 0. We usually weight utility by e −σt
▶ Why? When we go from t to t + dt, the discount is
e −σdt ≈ 1 − σdt
44/53
Application to our problem of optimal growth
45/53
Application to our problem of optimal growth
µt = u ′ (ct )e −σt
∂H(t, kt , ct , µt )
= µ(t) f ′ (kt ) − δ = −µ˙t
∂k
46/53
Application to our problem of optimal growth
−u ′′ (ct ) ′
ċt = f (kt ) − σ − δ
u ′ (ct )
47/53
Gets back to our dynamic equations
ċt f ′ (kt ) − σ − δ
=
ct θ
48/53
Dynamics, when σ > α, δ = n = 0
49/53
Dynamics, when σ > α, δ = n = 0
50/53
Definition of a saddle-path
51/53
Characterization of the steady-state consumption and
capital with a Cobb-Douglas and n, δ = 0
1. Consumption
(k ∗ )α = c ∗
2. Capital
α (k ∗ )α−1 = σ
▶ Combined:
σ ∗
c∗ = k
α
Philippe Weil’s presentation, pre-print of Macroeconomic Theory: A Primer
▶ NB: if n > 0:
σ+n ∗
k c∗ =
α
▶ NB2: if δ > 0: c ∗ no longer a simpler function of k ∗
52/53
Conclusion of the neo-classical growth model
53/53