Personal Income
Personal Income
1
2 Introduction
the right tail. Thus, the combined personal tax structure tends to
be proportional with respect to income and, consequently, does
not per se contribute significantly to income redistribution.
Transfers, on the other hand, significantly improve the income
position of persons in the lower tail of the pretransfer income
distribution, but they also contribute importantly to the upper
tail.
Using an income concept which comes close to being consump-
tion minus taxes plus changes in net worth, he found a 13 percent
reduction in the Gini coefficient due to the combined influence of
taxes and transfers.
In his early work on tax burdens, Musgrave had been forced to
work with aggregated data, which precluded estimation of the tax
burden for subpopulations. Using the microdata developed from
the tax and survey data mentioned above, Okner was able to
demonstrate that there are substantial differences in the effect of
tax-transfer systems on subpopulations. For instance, where he
found a 13 percent reduction in the Gini coefficient for all
families, a 30 percent reduction for families with a head age 65 or
over was discovered.
In Chapter 4, Harold Watts and Jon Peck use the MERGE File
to simulate the redistributive consequences of a number of
variants of a tax function combining a constant marginal rate and
a fixed credit. They compare the before and after
set of six "family" types. The family typology, obviously selected
for its relevance to the problem of welfare reform, consisted of:
1. aged individuals;
2. families with aged heads;
3. families with female heads;
4. nonaged individuals;
5. families with nonaged male heads and 2 to 5 members; and
6. families with nonaged male heads and 6 or more members.
The authors examine the before and after tax, income status of
these units, and more interestingly, the before and after tax
distribution of the welfare ratio (income/poverty threshold).
They conclude that the extant tax structure is differentially
beneficial to the aged and to 'female-headed units, and that
Introduction S
income. The second set of data were collected from about 1 ,400
respondents in four interviews spaced approximately a year apart.
The third data set was the Panel Study of Income Dynamics, a
panel study now in its fifth year and still going on. The authors
find that the unit of analysis and the concept of income have
greater influence on the size distribution than does the length of
the accounting period. In terms of the influence of other factors
on income stability, occupation, age, and race—in that order—were
found to be important.
There were no formal discussants in the session from which
these papers came, but each participant was asked to provide,
within the time allotted to him, such observations upon the papers
of the other participants as he felt would be useful. Martin David
provided a set of comments reflecting on his own joint effort with
Roger Miller and on the other two papers presented in this part.
David's comments are included as Chapter 8.
The three chapters of Part IV are concerned with the
distribution of wealth. Lee Soltow presents estimates of the
distribution of wealth, income, and social class of men in large
northern cities in 1860 (Chapter 9); A. B. Atkinson writes of the
distribution of wealth in England in 1968; and James Smith
presents a study of the distribution of wealth in Washington, D.C.,
in 1967.
The Soltow piece starts with the microdata of the 1860 Census
and incorporates it into a model which permits one to predict the
probability of escape from a state of propertylessness—a state
which was not as uncommon as one might suspect. According to
Soltow's data, slightly over half of the adult males were without
assets; and according to his model, the probability of remaining in
a propertyless condition in a given year was .96.
Soltow also presents a model which employs a Pareto-
rectangular income distribution and a conventional savings func-
tion to determine the 1860 wealth distribution.
Atkinson (Chapter 10) provides the latest available statistics of
the distribution of wealth in Britain. He uses the estate multiplier
method of estimating the number of wealth holders and their asset
holdings in 1968.
His paper is particularly valuable not simply because it extends
a long series of wealth estimates for Britain which have been made
using the estate multiplier method, but because it examines the
sensitivity of the estimates to a methodology which has been
Introduction 7