Microeconomics Chapter 5
Microeconomics Chapter 5
A Scenario…
Suppose you are the owner/manager of a kiosk selling hotdogs. You estimate the following
weekly demand for your product:
In this chapter, we will focus on the sensitiveness of Qd against a change in P – called the
price elasticity of demand. This number is important as it affects our
decision on whether to cut or raise the price in order to maximize revenue.
Price elasticity of demand measures how the Quantity Demanded (Qd) of a good changes in
response to a change in its Price (P). Mathematically,
% change in Qd
Price elasticity of demand =
% change in P
© 2024 by Sunny HA
Elasticity and Its Application: Chapter 5 P. 2
∆Qd / QdA
Price Elasticity of Demand =
∆P / PA
–40 / 80
= = –1.5
+2 / 6
But put another way, if P changes from $8.0 (B) to $6.0 (A):
∆Qd / QdB
Price Elasticity of Demand =
∆P / PB
+40 / 40
= = –4.0
–2 / 8
Fig. 1 P
10.0
(–25%) Ed = –1.5 (–4.0)
PB 8.0 Ed = 2.33
B
PA 6.0
+33.3% A
4.0
2.0
Demand curve
So depending on where you start, the standard method in calculating % change would
give you different answers for elasticity.
In economic studies, to avoid assigning different elasticity values to the same interval of
a demand curve, we may use the midpoint method to calculate a % change:
∆Qd / (QdA+QdB)/2
Price Elasticity of Demand =
∆P / (PA+PB)/2
–40 / 60
= = –2.33
+2 / 7
Under the midpoint method, the calculated elasticity number would refer to the elasticity
over an interval on demand curve.
Note that the calculated price elasticity of demand is always a [ positive / negative ] number,
because P and Qd are inversely related. For ease of communication and to avoid confusion,
it’s customary to drop the minus sign, so having a price elasticity of demand of –4 is
considered [ greater / smaller ] than price elasticity of –1.5.
© 2024 by Sunny HA
Elasticity and Its Application: Chapter 5 P. 3
Inelastic Demand
When demand is inelastic (for example, P 10% => Qd 5% ), the calculated
price elasticity of demand is [ >1 / =1 / <1 ]. Graphically, an inelastic demand is usually
described by a steep demand curve (Fig. 2).
$7 $7
55% 55%
$4 $4
90 120 Qd 120 Qd
29% 0%
Elastic Demand
When demand is elastic (for example, P 10% => Qd 20% ), the calculated
price elasticity of demand is [ >1 / =1 / <1 ]. Graphically, an elastic demand is usually
described by a relatively flat demand curve (Fig. 4).
60 120 Qd Qd
66%
© 2024 by Sunny HA
Elasticity and Its Application: Chapter 5 P. 4
60 120 180 Qd
66.7%
It is most important to master the relationship between price elasticity and total revenue
(TR). Note the following situations:
If, for example, Elasticity over this range of the Raising the price over this range
demand curve is: would cause:
P +10% and Q –5% Inelastic TR to rise
P +10% and Q –20% Elastic TR to fall
P +10% and Q –10% Unit elastic TR unchanged
When demand curve is a straight line, its slope is a constant. But its price
elasticity is NOT a constant along the demand curve (even this is a straight line).
In general, demand tends to more [ elastic / inelastic ] over the upper portion of the
demand curve and more [ elastic / inelastic ] over the lower portion.
© 2024 by Sunny HA
Elasticity and Its Application: Chapter 5 P. 5
To illustrate this, we can calculate the point elasticity of demand (not covered in our
textbook). Recall figure 1 (the data from page 1):
10.0
9 Elastic (Ed > 1)
8.0 4
B 2.33
6.0 1.5
A 1
4.0 0.66 Inelastic (Ed < 1)
0.43
2.0 0.25
0.11
To calculate the elasticity value of different points (Px, Qdx) on a demand curve, we start
with the same equation:
% change in Qd
Price elasticity of demand =
% change in P
= ∆Qd / Qdx
∆P / Px
= ∆Qd Px
x
∆P Qdx
= 1 Px
x
slope Qdx
Because slope (of a straight line) is a constant, the reciprocal of a slope (1/slope) is also a
constant. In other words, the elasticity of a point (PA, QdA) on the demand curve is just the
ratio PA to QdA times a constant.
In the above demand curve, that constant (1/slope or ∆Qd / ∆P) is equal to 20 .
So, for example, the point elasticity of demand of Point A is:
20 x 6/80 = 1.5
Continuing these calculations will help us determine the point elasticity of all points on the
demand curve and for which part is elastic and which part is inelastic.
© 2024 by Sunny HA
Elasticity and Its Application: Chapter 5 P. 6
(1) The fast rule is to see how important the good is to the buyer – the higher
the importance, the more [ elastic / inelastic ] it is (e.g. MTR service); conversely, the
lower the importance, the more [ elastic / inelastic ] it is (e.g. hamburgers).
Note: The definition of “importance” is highly subjective, implying that the price
elasticity of a good is contingent upon the perspective of the decision maker. For
instance, the MTR service may be deemed important (inelastic) by students, but less
important (elastic) to other individuals.
Note: Points (2) and (3) below give you some idea on how “importance” may be
judged by individuals.
In addition to the price elasticity of demand, economists also study the responsiveness of Qd
to a change in (i) income, and (ii) price of related goods
% change in Qd
(i) Income elasticity of demand =
% change in Income
Note that among normal goods, income elasticities could vary greatly. For necessities,
their income elasticity tends to be [ smaller / larger ] (e.g. +10% in income => +8% in Qd;
so it’s calculated +0.8 for this necessity). For luxuries (also called “superior goods”) their
income elasticity tends to be [ smaller / larger ] (e.g. +10% in income => +33% in Qd;
so it’s calculated +3.3 for this luxury).
Conversely, an inferior good (Qd drops when income increases) would have a
[ positive / negative ] income elasticity (e.g. +10% in income => –25% in Qd; so
it’s calculated –2.5 for this inferior good).
Example: John’s income rises from $20,000 to $22,000 and the quantity of hamburger he
buys each week falls from 2 pounds to 1 pound.
–1 / 1.5
Income elasticity of demand = = –7.0
+2,000 / 21,000
The negative income elasticity indicates that hamburgers are an inferior good
for John.
Example: The price of apples rises from $1.0 per pound to $1.5 per pound. As a result, the
quantity of oranges demanded rises from 8,000 to 9,500 per week.
+1,500 / 8,750
Cross price elasticity of demand = = +0.43
+0.5 / 1.25
If the quantity demanded of one good increases as the price of another good increases
(a positive cross-price elasticity), then the two goods may be substitute
to each other.
If the quantity demanded of one good increases as the price of another good decreases
(a negative cross-price elasticity), then the two goods may be complement
to each other.
© 2024 by Sunny HA
Elasticity and Its Application: Chapter 5 P. 8
6. Elasticity of Supply
Price elasticity of supply (Es) measures how the Quantity Supplied (Qs) of a good changes in
response to a change in its Price (P). Mathematically,
% change in Qs
Price elasticity of supply (Es) =
% change in P
Example: The P of milk increases from $2.85 to $3.15 per gallon and the Qs rises from 9,000 to
11,000 gallons per month.
According to the law of supply (as there’s a positive relationship between P and Qs), the
calculated Es should always be positive.
Similar to the case of demand, five types of price elasticity of supply can be identified:
Inelastic Supply
If supply is inelastic (for example, P 10% => Qs6% ), then the calculated Es < 1 .
Graphically, an inelastic supply is usually described by a [ steep / relatively flat ] supply curve
with a positive horizontal intercept (Fig. 7).
+10% +10%
6% Qs +0% Qs
© 2024 by Sunny HA
Elasticity and Its Application: Chapter 5 P. 9
Elastic Supply
If supply is elastic (for example, P 5% => Qs20% ), then the calculated Es > 1 .
Graphically, an elastic supply is usually described by a [ steep / relatively flat ] supply curve
with a positive vertical intercept (Fig. 9).
+5% $5 S
+20% Qs Qs
P Fig .11: Unit elastic supply P Fig. 12: Supply curve with
varying elasticities
S S
Es<1
+10%
Es>1
+10% Qs Qs
© 2024 by Sunny HA
Elasticity and Its Application: Chapter 5 P. 10
The consideration behind is that: when output level is low, it would be relatively easy for
firms to increase output as they have excess capacity (supply tends to be elastic).
However, when the output becomes high, it becomes increasingly costly for firms to increase
output further (e.g. workers are paid extra for working overtime ; machines
require extra repairs for over-utilization). Therefore, it takes a much large price
increase to make firms willing to increase output further (supply tends to be inelastic).
(1) The fundamental rule is to see how flexible the sellers are in providing or
producing the good – the greater the flexibility, the more [ elastic / inelastic ] it is (e.g.
manufactured goods such as books, cars, and televisions); conversely, the lower the
flexibility, the more [ elastic / inelastic ] it is (e.g. beachfront property that is quite
limited in supply).
(2) Time horizon: Supply is usually more [ elastic / inelastic ] in the long run than in the short
run. The general reason is that, in short run, the Qs is not very responsive to P because
firms cannot easily adjust the size of their factory to make more of
a good. But over longer term, firms can build new factories or close old ones, making
output more responsive to price changes, indicating more elastic supply.
(1) Consider the market for wheat. A new hybrid of wheat was invented so production per
acre can be increased by 20%. However, this good news for farming had turned out to be
a bad news for farmers. Explain why.
* That is to say, demand for wheat is [ elastic / inelastic ] (having a steep demand
curve). This happens because wheat belongs to basic foodstuff and a necessity
to most people.
(Paradox of public policy: induce farmers not to plant too much in order to protect their
income)
© 2024 by Sunny HA
Elasticity and Its Application: Chapter 5 P. 11
P
S1 S2
P1
–TR
P2
D1
+TR
Q1 Q2 Q
Fig. 13
(2) Consider the market for drugs (e.g. cocaine, heroin). In recent months, the government
has strengthened police force to fight against drug traffickers. However, this drug
interdiction had rather increased the overall drug-related crimes. Explain why.
* Given the addictive nature of drugs, demand for drugs is likely [ elastic / inelastic ]
(having a steep demand curve). In other words, the rise in P will result in a [ bigger /
smaller ] percentage fall in Qd.
* Hence, Total Revenue (TR) will [ rise / fall ] (fig. 14); which may make drugs selling even
more profitable . On the other hand, the rise in P will make the drug
addicts more financially distressed ; so this may rather force them
to commit more crimes in order to get enough cash to support their habit.
P
S2 S1
P2
+TR
P1
–TR D1
Q2 Q1 Q
Fig. 14
© 2024 by Sunny HA
Elasticity and Its Application: Chapter 5 P. 12
(3) Consider the market for oil. In the 1970s and 1980s, OPEC (Organization of the Petroleum
Exporting Countries) reduced the amount of oil it was willing to supply to world
markets.
However, it was observed that the increase in price was much larger in the short run
than the long run. With the use of supply-and-demand diagrams, explain why.
P S2 S1 P
S2*
P2
S1*
P2*
P1 P1
D long run
D short run
Q2 Q1 Q Q2* Q1 Q
Fig. 15 Fig. 16
* In short run, demand for oil tends to be [ elastic / inelastic ] (demand curve tends to
be steeper) because consumers were hard to adjust their consumption habit. And in
short run, supply for oil is also inelastic (supply curve tends to be steep) because it
was hard to have new sellers to supply oil to the world market.
* Therefore, the decrease in supply had cause a larger increase in price (P1 P2) (Fig. 15)
* But in the long run, demand is more [ elastic / inelastic ] (demand curve becomes
flatter) because consumers can adjust to the higher price by reducing consumption or
finding other substitutes for use. Supply is also more elastic (supply curve
becomes flatter) because the higher price may attract new sellers to enter the
market.
* Therefore, even given the same amount of decrease in supply, the increase in price
may subside in the long run (P2 P2*) (Fig. 16).
© 2024 by Sunny HA