Mi Og
Mi Og
Josep Pijoan-Mas
1 Introduction
3 Optimality
4 Altruism
5 Social security
Outline
1 Introduction
3 Optimality
4 Altruism
5 Social security
Introduction The basic model Optimality Altruism SS
Introduction
● Yet, the model abstracts from two different and important issues:
a) Explain age profiles of economic variables: why is age a relevant state variable?
a) Some social security arrangements transfer resources between people of different ages
- Aggregate savings (and hence capital accumulation) or labor supply may be greatly affected.
A comment on optimality
● An important feature of the OG models is that they give ground for state intervention:
– The competitive equilibrium may not be Pareto optimal
● Contrary to the Ramsey model, households in OG economies may save too much.
– Steady state aggregate capital may be above the golden rule ⇒ welfare theorems fail
– Why? some trades between generations are not available in the decentralized economy
(Incomplete markets)
1 Introduction
3 Optimality
4 Altruism
5 Social security
Introduction The basic model Optimality Altruism SS
● Discrete time
● Households
– Simplest possible structure of overlapping generations: two periods
- People born into their young age, interact with current old people
- Next period, they become old and interact with the next young generation
- After that, they pass away
t
– The number of individuals born at time t is Nt , growing at rate n: Nt = N0 (1 + n)
– They own the production factors and rent them to firms
– They buy the final good from firms
● Firms
– Representative firm characterized by a neoclassical production function
– They rent capital and labor from households to produce the homogeneous final good
– They sell the final good to households
J. Pijoan-Mas Macroeconomics I (CEMFI 2024-2025) 5/62
Introduction The basic model Optimality Altruism SS
Optimization
c1t + st = wt
c2t+1 = (1 + rt+1 ) st
The FOC
● The first order condition will be:
⊳ The household chooses between current and future consumption in such a way that the
value of consuming an extra unit today, uc (c1t ), equals the discounted value of saving this
unit for old age and eating when old that unit and the interest rate earned.
This shows the parallel w/ the Euler equation of the Ramsey model in continuous time
st = s (wt , rt+1 )
→ Take the total differential of this equation w/ respect to the price of interest
→ This is “partial equilibrium”: change one price, keep the other fixed
Firm problem
● The representative firm operates a risk free technology that combines capital K and
labor L to produce output Y .
FK (Kt , Lt ) = rt + δ ⇒ fk (kt ) = rt + δ
FL (Kt , Lt ) = wt ⇒ f (kt ) − kt fk (kt ) = wt
1
where f (k) ≡ F (k, 1) = L F (K, L)
Equilibrium
Given s0 and the sequence of prices {rt+1 , wt }t=1 , the sequence {c1t , c2t , st }t=1
∞ ∞
1
satisfies the household problem.
2 Given a pair of prices {rt , wt }, the pair of allocations {Kt , Lt } solve the firm problem
for every t.
5 And the aggregate resource constraint is satisfied (which happens due to Walras law):
Yt = C1t + C2t + It
● This yields,
C1t + C2t + Kt+1 = Yt + (1 − δ) Kt
● Or also,
Yt − C1t − C2t = (Kt+1 − Kt ) + δKt
´¹¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¸¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¶ ´¹¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹¸ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¶
St It
Kt+1 = Nt st ∀t
states that next period’s productive capital is equal to the supply of assets by the
young.
● Take the optimality condition of household behavior and substitute prices for their
values in equilibrium:
● Then, the market clearing condition for capital will give us:
⊳ This equilibrium equation provides the law of motion for aggregate capital
– Note that, w/o specific funcitonal forms for u(c) and f (k), it is a fairly complicated object
● A steady state in this economy will be an equilibrium such that per worker capital is
constant over time, kt+1 = kt .
s (f (k ∗ ) − k ∗ fk (k ∗ ) , fk (k ∗ ) − δ)
k∗ = (1)
1+n
● Notice that the function s (⋅, ⋅) depends on the parameter β and on the parameters
that characterize the utility function.
● Therefore:
● The slope of the equilibrium law of motion for capital depends on the functional
forms of the utility function and the production function:
dkt+1 −sw kt fkk (kt )
=
dkt 1 + n − sr fkk (kt+1 )
– Hence,
→ A sufficient condition is that the income effect does not dominate (sr ≥ 0)
1+n
→ If the income effect dominates, sr < 0, and is large enough, sr < fkk
, we will have a negative slope
(⇒ oscillatory trajectories).
dkt+1
1> ∣ >0
dkt k∗
→ A necessary condition is that sr is not too small, that is to say, the income effect is not too large.
– From now one, we will work with the OG model under the constraint that this condition holds
Intuition
The equilibrium relationship,
● the market wage wt increases and since sw > 0 households want to save more and it
seems that we need kt+1 to increase in order to restore the equilibrium in the capital
markets.
● But, if kt+1 increases, firms must agree on it and therefore they will require rt+1 to fall
● Then, the final effect on kt+1 depends on the sign and size of sr .
J. Pijoan-Mas Macroeconomics I (CEMFI 2024-2025) 21/62
Outline
1 Introduction
3 Optimality
4 Altruism
5 Social security
Introduction The basic model Optimality Altruism SS
Optimality
– If the steady state capital in the decentralized allocation happens to be above the golden
rule we are in a situation known as dynamic inefficiency and a Pareto improvement is
possible.
● In the Ramsey and OG models we have the same notion of golden rule steady state
(because the aggregate resource constraint and the production function are the same)
k∗ = ( ∗
1−α β 1−α 1+n 1+β
) and fk (k ) = α
1+n 1+β 1−α β
● That is to say, if households are patient enough (β is large enough), they may reach a
situation in which there is over-accumulation of capital.
● Note that in the Ramsey model (∞-lived agents) the TVC would prevent this situation
from happening
– We do not have a TVC here
– Assume that the period length is 30 years and that the annual rate of population growth is
1%, depreciation rate 8% and capital share 28%.
– This inequality implies that if households annual subjective rate of discount is smaller than
1.16%, then we are in the non optimal case.
– Ramsey model
- If individuals ↓ s in every period, this allows them to ↑ c in every period
∗
(Indeed, if n = 0 the saving technology has a negative return at k > kg )
- Hence, k will diminish and the steady state will be at some k∗ < kg∗
– OG model
- if young ↓ s in every period, they ↑ c as young in every period but they ↓ c as old in every period
- The reduction of saving when young implies having less to eat as old
- A steady state k∗ > kg∗ is possible
● Is there any way that agents in the OG economy can trade and so benefit from the
available Pareto improvement?
⊳ This implies that each member of the old cohort receives Nt /Nt−1 = 1 + n units of
consumption.
● If instead of this transfer system, the young cohorts save with the available
technology, they obtain 1 + r units of consumption when old.
Solutions
● Bubbles → A fundamentally worthless asset crowds out capital (Tirole, ECTA 1985)
1 Introduction
3 Optimality
4 Altruism
5 Social security
Introduction The basic model Optimality Altruism SS
Altruism
● But bequests do take place in real life, and they are quantitatively important.
⊳ We are now going to introduce a well-defined notion of altruism into the OG model
J. Pijoan-Mas Macroeconomics I (CEMFI 2024-2025) 29/62
Introduction The basic model Optimality Altruism SS
Objective function
● Let’s consider that parents care about the welfare of their kids
So, an individual cares about his consumption today and tomorrow plus the welfare
that his kids will attain.
● This shows that caring about the children who cares about their own children makes
the current generation care about all future mankind
(albeit with a potentially different weight on future generations)
J. Pijoan-Mas Macroeconomics I (CEMFI 2024-2025) 30/62
Introduction The basic model Optimality Altruism SS
Optimization problem
● The budget constraints of the household problem are:
c1t + st = wt + bt
c2t+1 + (1 + n) bt+1 = (1 + rt+1 ) st
● Then, starting at some t, the optimization problem of the parents is to choose the
optimal paths of savings and bequests
⎧
⎪ ⎫
⎪
⎪∞ i i ⎪
max ∞ ⎨ ∑ γ (1 + n) [u( wt+i + bt+i − st+i ) + β u( (1 + rt+1+i ) st+i − (1 + n) bt+1+i )]⎬
{st+i ,bt+1+i }i=0 ⎪
⎪ ´¹¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¸¹¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¶ ´¹¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¸ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¹ ¶ ⎪
⎪
⎩ i=0 c1t+i c2t+1+i
⎭
s.t. bt+1+i ≥ 0 ∀i, and bt given
⊳ The first condition we already know it. The household allocates resources between
youth and old age such that the marginal value of a consumption unit is equalized
across periods.
⊳ The second condition is new. It says that the marginal value of a consumption unit
during the individual old age has to be equal to the marginal value of that unit if left
to the offspring.
– If the inequality constraint binds (λt+i > 0), then we will have:
which states that the household would be better off by reducing bequests and therefore
increasing his own consumption when old and decreasing the consumption of his offspring.
– But this transfer cannot be done due to the non-negativity constraint on bequests.
(λt+i > 0 ⇔ bt+1+i = 0)
⊳ The firm problem and the equilibrium conditions are identical to the basic OG model.
uc (c∗1 ) = β (1 + r∗ ) uc (c∗2 )
β ∗
βuc (c∗2 ) = γuc (c∗1 ) + λ
1+n
● Since γ (1 + n) < 1 ⇒ 1
γ
> (1 + n) we have
(1 + r∗ ) > (1 + n) ⇒ fk (k ∗ ) > δ + n = fk (kg∗ ) ⇒ k ∗ < kg∗
Therefore, there is no over-accumulation: the decentralized solution is Pareto-efficient
as in the Ramsey model
● If b∗ = 0 and λ∗ > 0,
1 1−γ
uc (c∗1 ) > γ (1 + r∗ ) uc (c∗1 ) ⇒ (1 + r∗ ) < ⇒ fk (k ∗ ) < +δ
γ γ
1) One where in equilibrium bequests are positive and the economy satisfies
satisfies the
intergenerational modified golden rule,
(where the discount factor is not given by the time discount β but by the weight of future generations γ )
2) Another where the transfers are zero and the steady state capital
capital is
is above
above the
intergenerational modified golden rule
3) Finally, also with zero transfers, we can have capital above, not only the modified golden
rule, but also above the golden rule itself yielding therefore dynamic inefficiency.
Infinitely-lived economy
Now, what if people care about their offspring as much as about themselves?
● Mathematically, we would have:
γ=β
1 1−β
⊳ If λ∗ = 0 and b∗ > 0 ⇒ (1 + r∗ ) = ⇔ fk (k ∗ ) = +δ
β β
1 1−β
⊳ If λ∗ > 0 and b∗ = 0 ⇒ (1 + r∗ ) < ⇔ fk (k ∗ ) < +δ
β β
● The case λ∗ = 0 is the discrete-time counterpart of the modified golden rule in the
infinitely-lived Ramsey problem seen earlier in the course.
● The case λ∗ > 0 and b∗ = 0 will never arise in the steady state of the Ramsey model.
The TVC prevents this from happening by restricting β(1 + n) < 1
1 Introduction
3 Optimality
4 Altruism
5 Social security
Introduction The basic model Optimality Altruism SS FF PAYG Transition
Social security
Introduction
● OG models are a very natural framework to study the effects on capital accumulation
of a welfare program such as the social security.
● In modern and rich societies, people live 20+ years after normal retirement age.
Life Expectancy at 65
(OECD Data)
Social security
Introduction
3. Fully funded social security. The state collects taxes from workers and saves the money to
be given back to people at retirement age.
4. Pay-as-you-go social security. The state collects taxes from current workers and uses these
resources to pay a pension to the current retirees.
● Further considerations:
– Lump sum payments or life annuities?
(What happens if you live for too long?)
(no administration costs and the same saving technology for the government)
c1t + st = wt − dt
c2t+1 = (1 + rt+1 ) st + (1 + rt+1 ) dt
Kt+1 = Nt st + Nt dt ⇒ kt+1 (1 + n) = st + dt
Kt+1 = Nt st ⇒ kt+1 (1 + n) = st
● They can be combined to get the same law of motion of kt+1 as a function of kt
Therefore, the kt+1 that solves the system without social security also solves the system
with a fully funded social security system.
● Both ways of saving (private and social security induced) yield the same return.
Therefore, the household is indifferent between them.
● The households undo through their private savings what the government does
through compulsory saving.
In particular,
dst
= −1
ddt
● Notice we have abstracted from distortionary taxation and uncertain lifetimes, which
might break this equivalence.
There is a case, however, in which the allocations with and without social security may
not be identical.
● If we impose a no-borrowing constraint (st ≥ 0) and the government sets dt too big
(larger than private savings without social security), then this substitution cannot be
performed.
⊳ The funded social security system may increase aggregate savings of the economy if
(a) households cannot borrow against future pensions and
(b) the government sets contributions larger than what households would have chosen in
absence of a public system.
A pay-as-you-go system
The transfer scheme
d1t Nt
d2t = = d1t (1 + n)
Nt−1
d1t+1 Nt+1
d2t+1 = = d1t+1 (1 + n)
Nt
d2t+1 d1t+1
= (1 + n)
d1t d1t
where (1 + n) = Nt+1
Nt
is the inverse of the dependency ratio at t.
J. Pijoan-Mas Macroeconomics I (CEMFI 2024-2025) 47/62
Introduction The basic model Optimality Altruism SS FF PAYG Transition
A pay-as-you-go system
The transfer scheme
● Let’s impose a steady state condition for the social security policy:
d1t+1 = d1t
● That is to say, in a two-period model, the fact that population grows means that at any
point in time there are more workers than retirees and therefore the social security
system can pay a positive return.
A pay-as-you-go system
The (inverse of the) dependency ratio in Spain
Working age population / 65+
7
Data (INE)
6
Projection (INE)
0
1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070
A pay-as-you-go system
The household problem
c1t + st = wt − dt
c2t+1 = (1 + rt+1 ) st + (1 + n) dt
A pay-as-you-go system
● The key equations are:
Kt+1 = Nt st ⇒ kt+1 (1 + n) = st
● This leads to a different law of motion for capital than the case w/o Social Security:
a) The return of the PAYG is different from the return of private savings
b) The capital market clearing condition is also different
J. Pijoan-Mas Macroeconomics I (CEMFI 2024-2025) 51/62
Introduction The basic model Optimality Altruism SS FF PAYG Transition
A pay-as-you-go system
How does dt affect private savings?
st = s (wt , rt+1 , dt )
⊳ As in the funded system, the pay-as-you-go pension system crowds out private savings
⊳ However, the size of the crowding out is not necessarily equal to one.
A pay-as-you-go system
The size of the crowding out
A pay-as-you-go system
Equilibrium capital
● Since public savings are independent from dt in the PAYG system, aggregate capital
will fall along with private savings:
Kt+1 = Nt st
and this will affect prices (wt and rt+1 ) and prices affect back to individual allocations.
A pay-as-you-go system
Steady state capital
● Following manipulations already familiar to us we have:
Kt+1 = Nt st ⇒ (1 + n) k ∗ = s [f (k ∗ ) − k ∗ fk (k ∗ ) , fk (k ∗ ) − δ, d∗ ]
– The condition for the denominator to be positive is the same as the one for having a locally
stable and non-oscillatory steady state.
⊳ Does the previous result mean that a movement from a pay-as-you-go Social Security
system to a fully funded system will increase aggregate capital in the economy?
1 The government has to honor the social security payments to the transitional generations
(which have been caught by surprise)
2 The government has to spread the burden of this transitional generation evenly across all
current and future cohorts.
● This suggests a policy line: issue public debt Bt to take care of the transitional
generations’ pensions and refinance it perpetually.
Bt = Nt−1 dt−1 (1 + n)
● Combining the market clearing condition for capital and the Euler equation we get,
⊳ Therefore, if we keep the contributions to the system unchanged dt−1 = dt these two
equations are the same whenever rt+1 = n
→ The transition from PAYG to FF does not change kt+1
1) If we are at the golden rule , the household choices are unchanged after the reform
because the return to the funded system is the same as the return to the PAYG system.
2) The aggregate capital of the economy is also unchanged because the higher savings by the
public sector are exactly compensated by the debt of the government: the debt of the social
security to the transitional generation.
⊳ Therefore, prices won’t change either and the economy will be unchanged.
● If rt+1 ≠ n, individuals will modify their consumption and saving, and this will affect
aggregate capital and prices due to second order effects.
1 + rt+1
kt+2 (1 + n) + dt−1 = st+1 + dt+1
1+n
⊳ Assuming again that dt−1 = dt = dt+1 , if we are at the golden rule, this equation is
exactly as in the previous period.
J. Pijoan-Mas Macroeconomics I (CEMFI 2024-2025) 60/62
Introduction The basic model Optimality Altruism SS FF PAYG Transition
⊳ In the golden rule the government can perpetually refinance its public debt: its rate
of growth (r ) equals the growth of aggregate output (n).
⇒ The debt to income ratio is constant and thus sustainable.
⇒ The economy does not change and stays in its steady state.
⊳ What would happen with public debt outside the golden rule?
– rt+1 < n [dynamic inefficient region] → The growth of output is larger than the growth of debt
⇒ The debt to gdp ratio goes to zero asymptotically (unless the government uses the fiscal space)
– rt+1 > n [below golden rule] → The growth of output is smaller than the growth of debt
⇒ The debt to gdp ratio explodes (unless the government raises taxes to run a primary balance)
⊳ A funded pensions system generates the same steady state allocations as an economy w/o
public pensions because households are indifferent between public and private savings
(unless the contributions are set too large)
⊳ An economy with a pay-as-you-go system displays in steady state lower aggregate capital
and therefore lower output than an equivalent economy with a funded system. Aggregate
consumption, however, might be larger.
⊳ Moving from a pay-as-you-go system towards a funded system does not necessarily imply
that aggregate capital will increase. The pay-as-you-go system contains an implicit debt that
becomes explicit when ending the system.