W 21964
W 21964
Petra Moser
Prepared for the Annual Review of Economics. I wish to thank the editor Tim Bresnahan, as well
as Eric Hilt, Larry White, Megan MacGarvie, and Walker Hanlon for helpful comments and discussions.
Much of the research that I describe in this review has been supported by the National Science Foundation
through CAREER Grant 1151180, and through a Fellowship at the Center for Advanced Study (CASBS).
The views expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National
Bureau of Economic Research.
NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-
reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official
NBER publications.
© 2016 by Petra Moser. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may
be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source.
Patents and Innovation in Economic History
Petra Moser
NBER Working Paper No. 21964
February 2016
JEL No. K0,K21,L51,N0,O30,O31,O34
ABSTRACT
A strong tradition in economic history, which primarily relies on qualitative evidence and statistical
correlations, has emphasized the importance of patents as a primary driver of innovation. Recent improvements
in empirical methodology – through the creation of new data sets and advances in identification –
have produced research that challenges this traditional view. The findings of this literature provide
a more nuanced view of the effects of intellectual property, and suggest that when patent rights have
been too broad or strong, they have actually discouraged innovation. This paper summarizes the major
results from this research and presents open questions.
Petra Moser
Department of Economics
NYU Stern
44 West 4th Street
New York, NY 10012
and NBER
[email protected]
PETRA MOSER
Abstract:
A strong tradition in economic history, which primarily relies on qualitative evidence and
statistical correlations, has emphasized the importance of patents as a primary driver of
innovation. Recent improvements in empirical methodology – through the creation of new data
sets and advances in identification – have produced research that challenges this traditional view.
The findings of this literature provide a more nuanced view of the effects of intellectual property,
and suggest that when patent rights have been too broad or strong, they have actually
discouraged innovation. This paper summarizes the major results from this research and presents
open questions.
human welfare and economic growth. The creation of intellectual property institutions,
particularly patents, has been motivated by a desire to stimulate innovation, and support
economic growth. Yet the connections between patents and innovation are difficult to identify
empirically, and the predictions of economic theory are somewhat ambiguous. For example,
basic models of patent laws (in the spirit of Nordhaus 1969) predict that extensions in the length
of patents encourage innovation by granting inventors stronger property rights in their ideas. Yet
alternative models suggest that stronger patents can discourage innovation if they reduce the
payoffs to later innovators who rely on previous inventions as an input for their work (e.g.,
1
Prepared for the Annual Review of Economics. I wish to thank the editor Tim Bresnahan, as well as Eric Hilt,
Larry White, Megan MacGarvie, and Walker Hanlon for helpful comments and conversations. Much of the research
that I describe in this review has been supported by the National Science Foundation through CAREER Grant
1151180, and through a Fellowship at the Center for Advanced Study (CASBS).
Economic history plays an important role in research on patent policies because it
provides some of the best data, as well as credibly exogenous sources of policy variation. In the
nineteenth century, for example, several countries failed to adopt patent systems for significant
periods of time, or abolished existing patent laws for political reasons that were unrelated to
innovation. In addition, the world technology fairs of the nineteenth century (Moser 2005, 2011,
and 2012) create opportunities to examine innovations that were made within and outside of
patent systems across countries. The catalogs of these exhibitions enable researchers to observe
the rate and direction of technical change in countries without patents, as well as the rate at
which innovators use patents when they are available. Both are critical for understanding the
effects of patents laws on innovation, and represents a major advantage over much of the
The lens of history also allows researchers to examine changes in policy from a distance,
which often leads to a more complete understanding of different aspects of intellectual property
institutions. This is particularly useful because the design of a well-functioning patent system
depends on understanding the tradeoffs associated with many different components of patent
policy, including some that are exceedingly difficult to analyze with modern data. For example, a
key issue in international debates relates to compulsory licensing, which allows developing
countries to license foreign-owned patents to domestic firms - without the consent of foreign
patent owners. To devise effective policies to govern compulsory licensing, policy makers must
weigh the benefits of compulsory licensing for consumers and firms in developing countries
against the potential costs of reducing innovation incentives for foreign firms whose intellectual
1
Another example of such tradeoffs are patent pools, which allow competing firms to
combine their patents and license them as a bundle to outside non-member firms. Regulators
who decide whether or not to allow these arrangements must evaluate the benefits that pools
provide for their members against the potentially negative and dynamic effects of pools on future
innovation. Pools benefit members and consumers by minimizing litigation risks and facilitating
the commercializations of inventions for which competing firms own mutually overlapping
patent rights. Yet they may also discourage the creation of new technologies by allowing pool
members to cooperate (instead of competing to improve). Moreover, the existence of a pool may
increase litigation risks for outside firms, which makes it harder for them to compete with the
pool. These effects have thus far been ignored by theoretical models, but they feature
mechanisms, such as secrecy, which inventors can use instead of patents. With a few notable
exceptions (such as Anton and Yao 2004) theories of intellectual property rights have ignored
these alternatives. Yet, their existence allows inventors to opt out of the patent system, which
means that changes in patent policies will not have the predicted effects. In part, economic
analyses have ignored alternative mechanisms, such as secrecy, because they are intrinsically
more difficult to observe. This makes it difficult to evaluate their importance, even though we
know intuitively that they exist. Notably, data from world technology fairs indicate that,
historically, the great majority of innovations have been created outside of the patent systems
2
The origins of intellectual property rights reach back as far as 1474 when the Venetian
Republic begun to offer exclusive rights to entrepreneurs who had invented - or imported – a
new technology. The Venetian law was purposefully agnostic about the source of an innovation;
Venetian rulers were happy to attract skilled artisans with new inventions, whether they had
created that invention or not. Other European countries introduced modified versions of the
Venetian system, hoping to promote economic development. But from the beginning, this system
proved vulnerable to exploitation (David 1994, p. 134). For example, British monarchs up to
King James I used the grant of royal monopolies on technical inventions as a mechanism to
extract rents that financed wars or courtly estates. Britain’s Statute of Monopolies of 1624
replaced the royal monopolies with a system of legal property rights in ideas. North and Thomas
(1973) argue that the creation of this intellectual property institution helped trigger Britain’s
Industrial Revolution. Well-functioning property rights in ideas allow inventors to keep a large
enough share of the fruits of their labor, motivating them to invest in creating socially valuable
inventions.
This ideal motivated the creation of “the world’s first modern patent institution” (e.g.,
Sokoloff and Khan 2001, p. 235), the US patent law. Thus Article 1 of the US Constitution
instructs Congress to “promote the Progress of Science and useful Arts, by securing for limited
Times to Authors and Inventors to the exclusive Right to their respective Writings and
Discoveries.” In contrast with the early British system, the US patent system combined the twin
goals of creating inventions and encouraging their widespread adoption. Importantly, the United
States also introduced a system of patent examinations in 1836 (e.g. Khan 2005, p. 55). This
system charged patent examiners (ideally technical experts in their field) with the responsibility
3
to establish the novelty of each invention and – at least in principle – refuse patents for
European countries began to copy features of the US patent system after they observed
American innovations at the Crystal Palace fair in London in 1851. Until the Great Exhibition of
the Works of Industry of all Nations (as the Crystal Palace was officially called), European
observers had ridiculed the United States as a technological backwater. But soon after the fair
had opened, droves of visitors began to admire US innovations such as the McCormick grain
invention, Samuel Colt’s revolver, demonstrated the potential of the American system of
manufacturing, in which the components were made with such uniformity and precision that they
system of manufacturing (Rosenberg 1969, p. 2). In his 1855 report on New York’s own Crystal
Palace exhibition, which was held on the ground of the current Bryant Park between July 1853
and November 1854, Commissioner Joseph Withworth (1854, pp. 55-68) included a detailed
“It remains to say a few words, in conclusion, on the scale of fees. These are extremely
moderate in the case of citizens, and the privileges and protection afforded by letters patent
are most properly placed within the reach of all citizen inventors” (Withworth 1854, p. 67)
Since then, economic historians have credited low fees with encouraging broad-based innovation
in the United States (e.g., Khan and Sokoloff 1993; 1998; 2001, Lamoreaux and Sokoloff 1999;
Khan 2005).
Notably Withworth (1854, p. 67) also describes the dramatically higher fees that the US
4
“But foreigners labour under great disadvantages, being required, if British subjects, to pay
nearly seventeen times as much as a citizen ($500), if any other foreigner, ten times as much
as a citizen ($300).”
These fees are interesting for two reasons, which invite empirical analyses of their effects: First,
expensive fees probably discouraged foreigners from patenting their inventions in the United
States, which made it easier for US nationals to copy them. In spirit, this is reminiscent of
modern policies that weaken the patent rights of foreign inventors, such as compulsory licensing
(discussed below). Second, it is remarkable that the US system reserved the largest fees for
inventors from Britain, who were at the technology frontier. Taken together these featurs suggest
that the early US patent system may have encouraged economic development by reducing the
Following the pioneering analyses of hand-collected data in Schmookler (1962 and 1966),
and Sokoloff (1988), patent counts have become the standard proxy for innovation. In recent
years, the availability of electronic data sets, such as the NBER’s Patents and Citations dataset
for 1976 to 2002 (Jaffe, Hall, and Trajtenberg 2001) and optical character recognition (OCR)
files of US patents since 1920, has further contributed to the popularity of patents as a focus for
research. 2
Yet it is important to keep in mind that patents are an “imperfect, fallible measure” of the
particularly important for analyses of patent laws because we need to understand what types – if
2
See Moser and Voena (2012), for a detailed description of Google/USPTO patent data since 1920, Moser et al.
(2014) for inventor-level data, and Lampe and Moser (2016) for historical data on patent citations since 1920.
5
any – innovations would be made in the absence of patent laws. By construction, patent data fail
Studies of individual industries, such as Allen (1983) and Nuvolari (2004), have
addressed this issue by collecting independent measures of performance. That is, rather than
focusing on counts of patents or their citations, this research has attempted to directly measure
improvements of particular products. For example, Lampe and Moser (2010) use data on sewing
speeds to observe the rate of innovation in sewing machines. Similarly, Moser, Ohmstedt, and
Rhode (2014) compile data on advances in yields, and other biological characteristics of patented
corn hybrids, to measure the speed of biological innovation. Yet such performance measures are
impossible to construct in a manner that makes them comparable across industries. This feature
limits their use in empirical analysis of the direction of technical change, and other important
questions.
irrespective of their patent status - across sectors, across countries, and over time. Starting with
the Crystal Palace in London in 1851, the organizers of these fairs systematically collected and
displayed technologies from across the world (Moser 2003, 2005, 2011, and 2012). The scale of
the fairs was unprecedented, and remains unparalleled today. In 1851, the Crystal Palace, a
1,848-foot long greenhouse of cast-iron and glass, was the largest enclosed space on earth; it
housed 17,062 exhibitors from 40 countries; at a time when London had less than 2 million
inhabitants, more than 6 million tickets were sold. The American Centennial Exhibition in
Philadelphia in 1876 attracted more than 10 million visitors (Kroker 1975, p. 146). To see all
6
10,863 exhibits from 35 countries at the Centennial fair, a visitor had to walk the equivalent of a
marathon. Another important fair, the 1893 World’s Columbian Exposition in Chicago, covered
717 acres in Jackson Park by Lake Michigan; it attracted 27.5 million visitors. Finally, to host
the Panama-Pacific International Exposition in San Francisco in 1915, its organizers drained a
swampy part of the San Francisco Bay, which later became the Presidio. This fair welcomed
Exhibits were recorded in catalogues that helped visitors navigate the fairs. Many of these
catalogues became significant reference works for the current state of technology. For example,
Britain’s Official Catalogue of the great exhibition of the work of industry of all nations (1851)
became a “book of reference to the philosopher, merchant, and manufacturer” (Auerbach 1999, p.
94) to an exhibition that was a “veritable acting industrial encyclopaedia” (Tallis 1852, p. 234;
The Times, December 5, 1850). Catalogue entries include the exhibitor’s name, location, and a
406, Fourdrinier, E. N., 38 Barclay St., Sunderland, Patent safety apparatus, for preventing
loss of life and destruction of property when a rope or chain breaks in shafts of mines and
collieries.
In addition to the prize-winning reaper and Colt’s revolver, examples of exhibits included power-
As a means of quality control, exhibits were subject to a systematic and careful process of
selection. 3 Commissioners for the Crystal Palace Fair visited cities and rural areas to set up local
selection committees and to ensure broad-based representation (Bericht 1853, pp. 40 and 64,
Auerbach 1999, p. 55 and 87). National papers, such as the British Times, Economist, and Sun,
3
By comparison, selection processes at smaller regional fairs in the US and Britain and even at later world’s fairs
was substantially more haphazard (e.g., Khan 2014), and exhibits at these fairs may not be a good proxy for
innovation.
7
and the US Scientific American advertised the fairs in regular features (e.g., The Times,
November 14, 20, December 6, 9, and 30, 1850). In Britain, 65 local commissions formed more
than 300 sub-commissions (Auerbach 1999, p. 32). Local committees selected exhibits in the
first round; their submissions competed at the national level. Among these selections, national
committees chose the most promising innovations to represent their country in a hard-fought
international “contest of industries” (Kretschmer 1999, pp. 46-48; Auerbach 1999, pp. 68-69, 78
and 189). Less than 30 percent of applicants were admitted to the fair (Bericht 1853, pp. 50 and
117). After the fair, universities, scientists, and museums competed to purchase exhibits
A concern with exhibition data is that transportation costs may have influenced the
selection of exhibits and that exhibits from host countries were over-represented. For example,
three-fourths of the 13 acres in Machinery Hall were taken up with American machines in 1876,
including the colossal Corliss steam engine, which provided power to the fair (Andrews 1894, p.
73). The influence of transportation costs was mitigated because heavy, large, or fragile
inventions were presented by models. In 1851, for example, 88 of 194 British exhibits in “Civil
770-meter long chain suspension bridge across the Dnepr in Kiev (Rolt 1970, p. 157). Similarly,
T. Powell of Monmouthshire, Britain, exhibited a “Model for apparatus used for shipment of
coals from boats or waggons at Cardiff dock” at the Crystal Palace, and A.Watney of Llanelly,
4
Another potential source of bias stems from restrictions on exhibition space, which were set by the host country.
Anecdotal evidence, however, indicates that such restrictions may not have been binding. For example, when the US
commission to the Crystal Palace thought that US exhibitors would be short on exhibition space, it asked the British
commission for more room and was granted its request (Haltern 1971, p. 150). Floor plans for the Centennial
8
Many Important Innovations Occur Outside of the Patent System
innovation (e.g., Sokoloff and Lamoreaux 1999), exhibition data show that the majority of 19th-
century innovations occurred outside of the patent system. In 1851, for example, only 11 percent
of British exhibits were patented. Such low patenting rates are more consistent with alternative
explanations that emphasize a culture of entrepreneurship (Landes 1969), the free exchange of
knowledge (Allen 1983, Nuvolari 2004), and investments in science (Arora and Rosenberg 1998;
In addition to capturing innovation without patents, exhibition data also make it possible
to control for the quality of innovations through prizes that were granted to a small share of
exceptional inventions. These data raise a question for empirical and theoretical research: Are
inventors more or less likely to patent high-quality inventions? Existing theories of innovation
predict that firms are more likely to use secrecy if innovations are important. Patents require
disclosure, which is risky if patents cannot effectively prevent competitors from using a patented
invention (Anton and Yao 2004; Horstmann, MacDonald, and Slivinski 1985). Exhibition data,
however, show that high-quality exhibits were slightly more likely to be patented. In 1851, 15
percent of Britain’s prize-winning exhibits were patented, compared with 11 percent of average-
quality exhibits. Notably, the prize data also show that the large majority of prize-winning
exhibition show that 11 countries, including Germany, Britain, Spain, and Sweden, built additional exhibition space
on the Centennial grounds.
5
Low patenting rates are particularly remarkable considering that exhibition data may be biased towards recording
patented inventions, if inventors were reluctant to exhibit inventors that were protected by secrecy. To address this
problem, the U.K. government created a registration system to offer “Protection from Piracy to Persons exhibiting
new Inventions.” Only 600 exhibitors (less than 3.3 percent) took advantage of this system. Instead exhibitors
advertised the finished product, rather than the machines that had made it, to maintain secrecy surrounding the
machine. For example, Drewsen & Sons of Silkeborg, Jutland, exhibited “Specimens of paper, glazed by a machine
constructed by the exhibitor,” instead of their paper-making machine (Official Catalogue 1851, p. 210).
9
inventions were not patented, which calls into question the importance of patents as a driver of
high-quality invention.
The 19th century offers a unique setting to examine the effects of patent laws on
innovation because no other period had a comparable amount of exogenous variation in national
laws. In 1851, the statutory length of a patent varied from no protection in Denmark and
Switzerland to 14 years in Britain and the United States, and 15 years in Bavaria, Belgium, and
the Netherlands. Much of this variation was in place because countries had adopted patent laws
according to idiosyncratic allegiances of national rulers (Penrose 1951, p. 13). Another benefit of
the empirical setting is that it precedes the period of intense lobbying from interests that
Exhibition data show that the existence of patent laws was not a necessary condition for
high levels of innovation (Moser 2003). Crystal Palace data in Moser (2005, Table 1) include
11,610 exhibits from 12 Northern European countries in 1851. Two of these countries –
Switzerland and Denmark - offered no patent protection. Data for the Philadelphia Centennial
Exhibition cover 6,482 exhibits from 10 Northern European countries in 1876. Two of them –
Switzerland and the Netherlands - offered no patent protection, and 3 had short-lived patents.
Notably, the absence of patent protection did not prevent innovation in countries without patent
laws. In 1851, for example, Switzerland contributed 110 exhibits per one millions Swiss citizens,
which was two times the mean of the average country, and three times compared with the
median of 36 exhibits per 1 million people. Switzerland also won a disproportionate number of
prizes, with 47 per 1 million people, more than twice the mean value of 20 and more than 4 times
10
the median of 11. Switzerland continued to lead innovation in food processing (e.g., by
improving milk chocolate and ready-made meals), all before adopting a full-fledged patent
system in 1907.
Most economists understand intuitively that many important innovations - ranging from
19th century dyes and scientific instruments to Ford’s conveyer belt and the famously secrective
Coca Cola – were not patented. Yet, it is difficult to determine how important non-patenting is
quantitatively, and whether it varies across sectors and over time. 6 Exhibition data allow
researchers to measure such variation across industries, over time, and - importantly - across
patent systems.
In 1851, patent fees in Britain ranged between £100 and £120 in Britain “approximately 4
times per capita income in 1860” (Khan 2005, p. 31). In addition, inventors faced a cumbersome
process with legal fees and bribes (MacLeod 1988, p. 76; Dutton 1984). In Charles Dicken’s “A
Poor Man’s Tale of the Patent System” (1868, p. 228), the fictional inventor Old John complains:
“Look at the Home Secretary, the Attorney-General, the Patent Office, the Engrossing Clerk,
the Lord Chancellor, the Privy Seal, the Clerk of Patents, the Lord Chancellor’s Purse-bearer,
the Clerk of the Hanaper, the Deputy Clerk of the Hanaper, the Deputy Sealer, and the Deputy
Chaff-was. No man in England could get a patent for an Indian-rubber band or an iron hopp,
without feeing all of them. Some of them, over and over again”
By comparison, US patent fees were substantially lower. Moreover, inventors could submit their
patent applications by mail, which should have made it much easier for rural inventors to apply
6
The most complete evidence in modern settings come from survey data (Levin, Klevorick, Nelson, and Winter
1987; Cohen, Nelson, and Walsh 2000), which suggest that chemicals and pharmaceuticals relied strongly on
patents, while most other industries relied heavily on secrecy.
11
for a patent. Khan and Sokoloff (1998 and 2001) have credited the superior design of the US
patent system with encouraging the “democratization” of invention in the United States.
“The British system reflected its origin in royal privilege and effectively limited access to a
select class of patentees. In contrast, the United States established the world's first modern
patent institution, one that was consciously designed to stimulate participation in invention
across a wide spectrum of the population” (Khan and Sokoloff 1998, p. 295)
Yet exhibition data show that US patenting rates were only slightly higher than British patenting
rates; the difference was less than five percentage points (Moser 2012, p. 54). These results
challenge the view that the design of the US patent system played an important role in
stimulating high levels of innovation (Lamoreaux and Sokoloff 1998; Sokoloff and Khan 1998,
2001).
Location data for inventors, however, provide some suggestive evidence in favor of the
hypothesis that the US patent system helped democratize innovation. A first test compares
variation in patenting rates across urban and rural areas in Britain and the United States. With the
caveat that the data include only 574 observations across the United States, there are no
noticeable systematic differences in patenting rates across urban and rural areas in the United
States (Moser 2012, pp. 13-14, Table 4). By comparison, British patenting rates (for a sample of
more than 6,000 exhibits) were significantly higher in London, compared with rural rates. These
findings highlight the need for further analyses to examine the role of access costs in determining
A potential explanation for the low rates at which valuable innovations in the United
Sates were patented is that even though the costs of patent applications were low, the costs of
12
patent enforcement may have been substantial. Dutton (1984) observes that US courts were more
likely to uphold the patent rights of original inventors, while British courts tended to be more
anti-patent. Khan (2005) argues that this pro-patent attitude encouraged invention in the United
States. The US Patent Act of 1793 specified that “simply changing the form or proportion of any
machine…shall not be deemed a discovery.” It was, however, often left to the courts determine
the boundaries between the original inventor’s patent and the next invention that was sufficiently
novel to merit a new patent. Eli Whitney, for example, patented a saw gin in 1793 that could be
used to remove seeds from short staple upland varieties of cotton (Olmstedt and Rhode, 2008 p.
1130, Lakwete 2003, p. 67-68). Whitney’s patent remained subject to litigation until December
1807, one month after it had expired. The knowledge of such cases may have led inventors to
incorporate litigation risks into the expected costs of patenting, and avoid patents whenever
possible.
Litigation risks were particularly high when US courts enforced overly broad patents that
had been issued by the US Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO). In 1846, for example, the US
Patent and Trademark Office issued patent 4,750 to Elias Howe for an “Improvement in Sewing
Machines.” Howe’s patent was broad enough to cover most commercially viable sewing
machines at the time. Like a 21st-century “patent troll,” Howe used his patent to threaten
litigation, instead of commercializing his invention. In 1852, a District Court upheld Howe’s
patent, and he began to collect license fees of $25 per machine, roughly one-fifth the average
price of a sewing machine (Lampe and Moser 2014). When other firms sued based on their own
patents, production came to a halt during the 1851–1856 “sewing machine wars” (Bissell 1999, p.
84). By 1867, Howe had received $2 million in license fees (Parton, 1867), roughly $30 million
in 2014 dollars.
13
Patent Pools Discouraged Innovation
To resolve litigation, Elias Howe, the Singer Company, and two other manufacturers
formed the first patent pool, the Sewing Machine Combination in 1856. Like contemporary pools,
the Combination allowed its members to use each others’ patents, and license all pool patents
together as a bundle to outside firms. Litigation data confirm that the creation of a pool reduced
litigation risks for members (Lampe and Moser 2010, p. 900). The pool also reduced license fees
from $25 per machine for Howe’s patent to $5 for the bundle of patents for members and $15 for
outside firms. Patenting, however, declined after the pool formed and increased again only after
it dissolved in 1877, with the expiration of the last broad patent (Lampe and Moser 2010, p. 913).
A comparison with Britain’s sewing machine industry, which had no patent pool, suggests that
this decline in innovation was limited to the United States. In Britain, sewing machine patents
continued to increase gradually as a share of all patents until the early 1870s and experienced no
Did the decline in US patenting represent a decline in innovation? Here again the
difference between patents and innovation is important: Patenting may decline because inventors
no longer have to create “patent thickets” (Shapiro 2001) to protect themselves from litigiation.
With a little bit of detective work, economic history can answer this question. Articles on sewing
machines in 19th-century magazines, such as the Scientific American and the Lady’s Home
Journal, suggest that contemporary customers valued sewing machines that were light, quiet, and,
most importantly fast. Sewing speed is measured as the number of stitches per minute that a
machine could perform, and it is reported on contemporary trade cards and catalogues, which we
were able to access in the records of the Smithsonian Institution. These data indicate that
14
improvements in sewing speed slowed soon after the pool had been established and increased
again after it had dissolved (Lampe and Moser 2010, pp. 916–17).
The experience of the sewing machine industry also suggests another important policy
implication of patent pools for the direction of technical change. Data on patents and firm entry
indicate that the creation of a patent pool diverted innovation away from the pool technology
towards a substitute technology that was already understood to be inferior (Lampe and Moser
2014). As long as the pool created a significant wedge between license fees for members and
outsiders, outsiders entered with the substitute because they needed to avoid licensing and
litigation. Data on firm survivals show that firms that entered with the substitute were
significantly more likely to fail compared with other entrants, suggesting that the shift towards
Whether these results are generalizable to other industries and modern pools is an open
question. A companion study of pools that formed across a broad range of 20 industries in the
1930s, however, unambiguously confirms the decline in patenting (Lampe and Moser 2014). In
the absence of effective antitrust, dominant firms used a pool to further limit and discourage
competition by outside firms. We find that this reduction in competition was associated with a
These results highlight the need for additional empirical and theoretical analyses of patent
pools. Theoretical models of the price effects of pools are well developed (Shapiro 2001; Lerner
and Tirole 2004), but a pool’s effect on innovation is less well understood. Importantly, existing
theoretical models focus almost exclusively on pool members and ignore effects on outside firms.
Yet, outside firms account for more than 90 percent of all patents in industries with patent pools
(Lampe and Moser 2014), which suggests that ignoring them can bias theoretical predictions.
15
Compulsory Licensing Encouraged Innovation
which allows government agencies to license foreign-owned patents inventions to domestic firms
- without the consent of foreign patent owners. This policy is a central concern in international
debates. WTO rules allow developing countries to use it if negotiations with foreign patent
owners fail, and countries such as Brazil and Thailand have used compulsory licensing to
episodes of compulsory licensing create opportunities for empirical analysis. In 1917, the US
Trading with the Enemy Act (TWEA) empowered government agencies, such as the Chemical
Foundation, to license German-owned patents to US firms. The Act’s primary goal was to place
all enemy property, including patents, “beyond the control or influence of its former owners”
(Alien Property Custodian 1919, p. 13 and 17). By February 22, 1919, the U.S. Alien Property
Custodian (1919, p. 7), A. Mitchell Palmer announced that “practically all known enemy
property in the United States has been taken over by me.” In 1919, the US Chemical Foundation
In one of the first analyses of the USPTO/Google bulk data patent files, Moser and Voena
(2012, p. 404) show that compulsory licensing of German-owned patents in organic chemistry
led to a 20 percent increase in US invention for affected technologies. Their baseline estimates
compare changes in patent grants per year after 1918 for 336 technologies with compulsory
licensing with changes in patent grants for a control group of 7,248 technologies without
16
licensing in the same industry. Lee and Moser (2015) extend these results to an economy-wide
were differentially affected by compulsory licensing. Technology fixed effects (at the level of
USPTO subclasses) and year fixed effects, as well as technology-specific trends, control for
variation in the use of patents across technologies and over time. This approach makes it possible
Firms under threat of compulsory licensing today argue that it will weaken their
incentives to invest in R&D. The historical records, however, suggests the opposite. Baten,
Moser, and Bianchi (2015) collect and analyze firm-level data on German patents to examine
invention by German firms that were differentially affected by compulsory licensing under the
TWEA. This analysis indicates that compulsory licensing was associated with a 28 percent
increase in patenting by German inventors. Controlling for variation in the quality of patents
(through renewal data) indicates that some of the observed increase was due to an increase in
lower quality patents, possibly as firms built a “thicket” of strategic patents around technologies
that were now threatened by entry. But even with quality controls, we find that compulsory
Does this mean that intellectual property rights always hold back innovation? Probably
not, but to answer the question economists must understand when inventors use and don’t use
17
patents. Exhibition data reveal a great deal of variation in the use of patents across industries and
over time. In 1851, for example, fewer than 5 percent of Britain’s chemical exhibits were
compared with 20 percent of manufacturing machinery (Moser 2012, p. 46). The data also show
that – despite the most substantial differences in national patent systems – US inventors appear
to have relied on patents, and avoided them in the same industries as British inventors (Moser
2012 p. 58). Echoing results on low overall patenting rates in the United States, these findings
suggest that the institutional features of the US patent system did not significantly affect
patenting behavior.
What determines variation in the use of patents across industries? Qualitative evidence
points to variation in the effectiveness of secrecy, as an alternative to patents. With crude tools of
considerable efforts in industrial espionage until the late 19th century (Haber 1958, p. 83).
Secrecy was also effective in protecting improvements in scientific instruments, such as the
rectangular prisms of Swiss glassmakers and the optical instruments of Danish makers (Bericht I,
1852 pp. 813–19, 930–41). Scientific breakthroughs, such as Dmitrii Mendeleev’s publication of
the periodic table in 1869, increased the risks associated with the use of secrecy, as they
transformed chemical analysis in the second half of the 19th century (Haber, 1958, p. 81).
Exhibition data show that advances in methods of scientific analysis, which made it
possible for the first time to reverse-engineer many types of innovations, intensified inventors’
dependency on patents. At the world’s fairs of 1851 and 1876, 0 and 5 percent of US chemical
18
innovations were patented. By 1893 and 1915, 19 and 20 percent of US chemical innovations
were patented. At the same time, innovations in manufacturing machinery remained unaffected
by improvements in scientific methods, because they had always been easy to reverse-engineer.
Patenting rates for these innovations stayed roughly constant between 44 and 49 percent for
manufacturing machinery (Moser 2012, pp. 62-67). This suggests that the shift towards patenting
was due to the reduced effectiveness of secrecy in chemicals, rather than an economy-wide
Intellectual Property Rights for Living Organisms Have Not Encouraged Innovation
protection. Until 1930, living organisms could not be patented. In the aftermath of World War I,
however, concerns about food security motivated the passage 1930 US Plant Patent Act, which
created intellectual property rights for plants that propagate (asexually) through roots rather than
seeds. In support of the Act, plant breeders had argued that they needed intellectual property
rights to protect their investments in R&D because competitors could easily reproduce an
improved plant – which had taken years to develop - by taking a cutting. Stark Brothers Nursery
for example, had built a cage with a burglar alarm to prevent competitors from taking cuttings of
their improved Golden Delicious apple (Moser and Rhode 2012). Responding to these arguments,
Data on US plant patent grants, however, show that nearly half of all US plant patent
grants beween 1930 and 1970 were for were roses (Moser and Rhode 2012, pp. 418–420). Had
19
rose breeding industry? Until World War II, US nurseries were dependant on imported nursery
stock from Europe. In the 1940s commercial nurseries began to build their own mass
develop a new rose, and most attempts to create new roses fail; fewer than 1 in 1,000 seedlings
typically lead to a commercially successful new rose (Robb 1964, p. 389). Yet, as soon as a
breeder succeeds in developing a new rose, competitors can propagate it by stealing cuttings.
registration records for newly-created rose varieties between 1916 and 1970. Matching
registration records with plant patents shows that less than 20 percent of newly registered roses
after 1930 were protected by a plant patent (Moser and Rhode 2012, pp. 429-434), again
Registration data also indicate that US breeders created fewer new roses after 1931. In
fact, lineage data show that most roses that are commercially successful today are descendants of
roses that public-sector, rather than private-sector, plant scientists developed before the creation
of plant patents. These results indicate that plant patent played no significant role in encouraging
innovation in rose breeding, and they highlight the need for analyses of other sectors.
If patents are important in some industries (such as manufacturing machinery) but not in
others (such as scientific instruments or chemicals in the 19th century), changes in patent laws
may influence the direction if not the level of technical change (Moser 2005). These patterns are
borne out in exhibition data: Countries without patent laws contribute as many exhibits and prize
20
winners as countries with patent law. But their innovations are disproportionately focused on
industries in which secrecy is effective, so that inventors are less dependent on patents. At the
Crystal Palace, one-fourth of exhibits from countries without patent laws were scientific
instruments, compared with one-seventh of exhibits from other countries (Figure 2; Moser 2005).
After the Netherlands abolished its patent protection – as a result of a political victory of
the free-trade party in 1869 – Dutch innovations shifted towards food processing, another
industry in which secrecy was effective. Between 1851 and 1876, the share of Dutch innovations
in food processing increased from 11 to 37 percent (Moser 2005). Many other innovations in this
industry, including milk chocolate, baby foods, and ready-made soups, were made in Switzerland
and the Netherlands when neither country had a patent law (Schiff 1971, pp. 52–58).
The case of margarine illustrates the effectiveness of secrecy compared with patents. The
French chemist Mège Mouriès disclosed the process of producing margarine to the Dutch
entrepreneurs Jurgens and van den Bergh, believing that he was protected by a patent. In 1871,
however, while the Netherlands did not have patent laws, Jurgens and van den Bergh began to
manufacture margarine there. After the partners argued and split, van den Bergh independently
improved the taste of margarine, and Jurgens failed to reverse-engineer van den Bergh’s
21
One important area for future analyses relates to the role that intellectual property rights
play in determining the geography of innovation. Can variation in the use of patents help to
explain why some regions – within the same country and the same patent system – are more
Accounts of innovation in Britain and the United States indicate that knowledge sharing
without patents laid the foundations for innovation and technical change (Allen 1983; Nuvolari
2004; Thomson 2009). For example, technical performance in the Cleveland (UK) iron-smelting
district improved rapidly between 1850 and 1875, as iron producers shared technical details
about the construction and performances of blast furnaces (Allen 1983). Yet these benefits
Anecdotal evidence suggests that the ability to protect ideas through intellectual property
rights encourages inventors to talk about them, and allow future generations of inventors to build
on their ideas. Many inventors, such as Mège Mouriès, were more willing to disclose technical
information when they felt protected by patents. The British inventor Robert Ransome, for
example, only began to advertise his plough-shares in Norwich and East Anglia after he received
a patent in 1803 (MacLeod 1988, p. 100). Moreover, historical records suggest that, in the
absence of patent protection, artisans took fierce measures to prevent the knowledge of new
technologies from spreading to outsiders. Thus silk weavers in 17th-century Bologna hanged
Ugolino Menzani because he had shared the knowledge of a new silk twisting machine with
Thus the availability of intellectual property rights may encourage the diffusion of new
ideas, and thereby enable follow-on invention. Although encouraging the diffusion of new
22
technologies is one of the two key goals of the US patent system, there is little systematic
The shift towards patenting in chemicals (documented in Moser 2012), however, creates
an opportunity to examine whether a shift towards patenting can encourage the geographic
diffusion of innovative activity. In chemistry, inventors began to rely more on patents after a
series of scientific breakthroughs (including the creation of the periodic table) reduced the
effectiveness of secrecy. Geographic data on the location of origins of exhibits show that
experience a shift towards patenting) remained unchanged. Data from the US Decennial Census
between 1840 and 1920 also show that the geographic decentralization of chemical innovations
became less localized after 1876, chemical production remained relatively stable.
These results are consistent with the hypothesis that intellectual property rights can
encourage the diffusion of innovation, but more empirical evidence is needed to identify these
effects.
without the shortcomings of patents? One promising alternative are copyrights, which create
intellectual property rights that are substantially more narrow than patents. An extremely stylized
example helps to illustrate the difference in scope: A copyright for Giacomo Puccini’s Tosca
(1900) protects the specific score and libretto, whereas a patent could in principle protect the idea
23
of an opera about two unlucky artists in love. Because copyrights are so much narrower than
patents, they avoid many pitfalls of broad patents, which makes them an appealing alternative to
patents for software and many other fields. Moreover, the growing importance of digital content,
which is primarily protected through copyrights, highlights the need for understanding the effects
of copyrights. Yet – with a few notable exceptions, such as Oberholzer-Gee and Strumpf (2007),
In the case of copyrights, the key tradeoff is encouraging the creation of new cultural
goods and allowing for their use by consumers and other artists. Initial evidence suggests that
basic levels of copyright protection can encourage creativity and innovation. Starting from low
levels of existing protection, extensions in copyright length for Romantic Period authors raised
the price of books (Li, MacGarvie, and Moser 2014) and increased payments to authors, even
though most of the gains accrued to a small number of exceptionally popular authors, such as Sir
The introduction of copyrights also appears to have caused an increase in both the
quantity and the quality of operas in 19th century Italy. Italian states that came under Napoleon’s
rule before 1804 (when France adopted the code civil), adopted the French copyright law of 1793,
whereas Italian states that came under Napoleon’s rule after 1804 did not get copyrights. Data on
the quantity, popularity, and durability of new operas indicate that the introduction of copyrights
led to an increase in the quantity and quality of operas (Giorcelli and Moser 2015). These data
also show that copyright extensions beyond the life of the composer have no effects on creativity.
Copyrights, do, however, come at the cost of restricting access to existing works. These
costs may be especially high when copyrights extend beyond the life of the composer and are
extremely long, as they are in the United States and Europe today, where copyright length
24
approach 100 years. Broadly speaking, restrictions on access (and higher prices as a result of
copyrights) increase the costs of access to existing works, which build the foundation for future
and Moser (2015) exploit a historical event of copyright violations under the World War II Book
Replication Program (BRP).This program issued temporary, 6-month licenses for German-
owned copyrights to US publishers, who then reprinted exact copies of German science books
Citations data indicate that the BRP resulted in a significant increase in new books and
publications that built on German science books. A simple model of knowledge production
comparison of changes for mathematics and chemistry confirms this prediction: Notably, the
increase in citations was much more pronounced in mathematics – which was more dependent on
human capital – than in chemistry. Intuitively, US mathematicians who now had access to a copy
of Courant and Hilbert’s “Methods of Mathematical Physics” at their local university library,
relied only on their human capital to use methods of mathematical physics in their own research.
Chemists, however, were more likely to also require access to physical capital, in the form of
laboratory space, to use the knowledge in a BRP book in their own research.
Economic history offers unique data sets and a wealth of exogenous variation to analyze
the effects of intellectual property rights to innovation. For example, exhibits at 19th-century
world fairs offer a rare alternative (non-patent) measure of innovation to examine the effects of
25
patent laws at a time when several countries had not yet adopted patent laws or abolished them
for political reasons. These data indicate that the large majority of historical innovations occurred
outside of the patent system. Moreover, they reveal that countries without patent laws, such as
Switzerland and the Netherlands, were at least as innovative as countries with patent laws.
Comparisons across industries also show that the need for patents varies significantly across
industries and over time. This need for patents has been strongest when innovations were easy to
reverse-engineer, so that inventors could not (or no longer) rely on secrecy to protect their
More generally intellectual property rights appear to have been most beneficial when they
were narrow and short-lived. Compulsory licensing, for example, forces patent owners to license
their inventions to new firms, including potential competitors. This policy has encouraged
innovation - not only by the firms that benefit from improved access, but by the original owners
of licensed patents, who now face more competition. Similarly, patent pools that allow
competitors to combine their patents have discouraged innovation, in part by making it more
difficult for entrants to compete with incumbents that have formed a pool.
Interestingly, initial results on the effectiveness of copyrights suggest that basic levels of
copyrights (which are significantly more narrow than patents) can encourage creativity. But
these results also suggest that extensions in the length of copyrights trigger no additional boost in
creativity. Such extensions may in fact create significant welfare losses by discouraging the
diffusion of cultural goods. These effects are particularly severe for science, a field in which the
26
Many important questions and research opportunities remain. For example, what are the
effects of intellectual property rights on the diffusion of innovation? Can basic levels of property
rights help to ensure a broad-based participation in processes of creativity and innovation? And
are copyrights a useful alternative to patents? Historical analyses can shed light on these
questions – with the benefit of distance, new data sets, and careful empirical analyses.
Although the focus of this essay has been on intellectual property rights, the creation of
“economically valuable knowledge” (e.g., Griliches 1990) is also vitally dependent on human
must enable and encourage these individuals to invest in creativity and innovation. A small
number of existing studies suggest that basic levels of intellectual property rights can encourage
broad-based participation, e.g., by rural inventors (Khan 2005, Moser 2011) and by individuals
of modest means who depend on creative work for income (MacGarvie and Moser 2014). Given
the enormous welfare implications of getting the most talented individuals to participate in
Another topic for future research concerns interactions between intellectual property
rights and policies towards science and immigration. Economic history offers a wealth of settings
to examine these policies. For example, the United States received an unprecedented inflow of
German-Jewish scientists after the Nazi regime took power in 1933. These arrivals helped
transform chemical innovation: Research fields in which the United States received an émigré
experienced a 31 percent boost in domestic patenting (Moser, Voena, and Waldinger 2014). The
importance of émigrés is also confirmed in preliminary analyses of 19th century operas in Italy
(Giorcelli and Moser 2015), where a large share of the observed increase in creativity in states
27
Finally, the supply of scientists, inventors, and entrepreneurs is grounded in individual-
level differences, that are not typically amenable to economic research. Historical biographies
reveal exceptional traits of resilience and optimism among creative individuals, ranging from
Charles Goodyear (who developed vulcanized rubber) to Sir Walter Scott (the author of Ivanhoe).
Anecdotal evidence also suggests a link between certain types of mental disorders (such as
bipolar disorder) and creativity. Preliminary analyses confirm the existence of such links in
modern data, and suggest that they have responded positively to medical innovations (e.g., Biasi,
Dahl and Moser 2015). Like other research in this essay, these findings highlight the enormous
REFERENCES
Allen RC. 1983. Collective Invention. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 4:1-24
Alien Property Custodian. 1919. A Detailed Report by the Alien Property Custodian of all
Proceedings Had by Him under the Trading with the Enemy Act During the Calendar Year 1918,
and to the Close of Business on February 15, 1919. US Government Printing Office.
Andrews BE. 1894. History of the United States, Vol. 4. New York: C. Scribner’s.
Anton JJ, Yao DA. 2004. Little Patents and Big Secrets: Managing Intellectual Property. RAND
J. Econ. 35:1–22
Auerbach J. 1999. The Great Exhibition of 1851: A Nation on Display. New Haven: Yale
University Press
Baten J., Bianchi, N., & Moser, P. 2015. Does Compulsory Licensing Discourage Invention?
Evidence From German Patents After WWI (No. w21442). National Bureau of Economic
Research.
Bessen J. and Maskin P. 2009. Sequential Innovation, Patents and Innovation. RAND J. Econ.,
40: 4.
28
Belfanti C. 2004. Guilds, Patents, and the Circulation of Technical Knowledge: Northern Italy
during the Early Modern Age. Technol. Cult. 45: 569–89
Biasi, B., & Moser, P. 2015. The Impact of Access on Science Evidence from the WWII Book
Republication Program. Available at SSRN 2542879.
Bissell D. 1999. The First Conglomerate: 145 Years of the Singer Sewing Machine Company.
Brunswick, ME: Audenreed Press
Cohen WM, Nelson RR, Walsh JP. 2000. Protecting Their Intellectual Assets: Appropriability
Conditions and Why US Manufacturing Firms Patent (or Not). NBER Work. Pap. 7552
Dahl, M., Biasi B. and Moser P. 2015. Career Effects of Mental Health.
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2544251
David PA. 1994. The Evolution of Intellectual Property Institutions. In Economics in a Changing
World, Vol. 1, System Transformation: Eastern and Western Assessments, ed. A Aganbegyan, O
Bogomolov, M. Kaser. London: Palgrace Macmillan
Dickens C. 1868. Charles Dickens's works. Charles Dickens ed. [18 vols. of a 21 vol. set.
Wanting A child's history of England; Christmas stories; The mystery of Edwin Drood].
Dutton HI. 1984. The Patent System and Inventive Activity during the Industrial Revolution,
1750–1852. Manchester, UK: Manchester University Press
Giorcelli, Michela and Moser, Petra, Copyright and Creativity: Evidence from Italian Operas.
Working Paper. http://ssrn.com/abstract=2505776.
Haber LF. 1958. The Chemical Industry during the 19th Century: A Study of the Economic
Aspect of Applied Chemistry in Europe and North America. Oxford, UK: Oxford University
Press
Hall BH, Jaffe AB, Trajtenberg M. 2001. The NBER Patent Citation Data File: Lessons, Insights
and Methodological Tools. NBER Work. Pap. 8498
Haltern U. 1971. Die Londoner Weltausstellung von 1851. Ein Beitrag zur Geschichte der
burgerlich-industriellen Gesellschaft im 19. Jahrhundert. Munster: Aschendorff
29
Hounshell DA. 1985. From the American System to Mass Production, 1800–1932: The
Development of Manufacturing Technology in the United States. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins
University Press
Hounshell DA, and Smith JK. 1988. Science and Corporate Strategy: Du Pont R&D, 1902–1980.
Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press
Khan BZ, Sokoloff KL. 1993. Schemes of Practical Utility: Entrepreneurship and Innovation
among 'Great Inventors' in the United States, 1790-1865. J. Econ. Hist. 53:289–307
Khan BZ, Sokoloff KL. 1998. Patent Institutions, Industrial Organization and Early
Technological Change: Britain and the United States, 1790-1850. In Technological Revolutions
in Europe, ed. M Bergand, K Bruland, pp. 292–313. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar
Khan BZ, Sokoloff KL. 2001. History Lessons: The Early Development of Intellectual Property
Institutions in the United States. J. Econ. Perspect. 15:233–46
Khan BZ. 2005. The Democratization of Invention: Patents and Copyrights in American
Economic Development, 1790–1920. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Khan BZ. 2014. Inventing in the Shadow of the Patent System: Evidence from 19th-Century
Patents and Prizes for Technological Innovation, NBER Working Paper No. w20731.
Lakwete A. 2003. Inventing the Cotton Gin: Machine and Myth in Antebellum America.
Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Univeristy Press
Lamoreaux NR, Sokoloff KL. 1999. Inventors, Firms, and the Market for Technology in the Late
19th and Early Twentieth Centuries. In Learning by Doing in Markets, Firms and Countries, ed.
NR Lamoreaux, DMG Raff, and P Temin. Chicago: University of Chicago Press
Lampe R, Moser P. 2010. Do Patent Pools Encourage Innovation? Evidence from the 19th-
Century Sewing Machine Industry. J. Econ. Hist. 70:898-920
Lampe R, Moser P. 2016. Patent Pools, Competition and Innovation. Evidence from 20
Industries under the New Deal” Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, Volume 32.
Lampe R, Moser P. Patent Pools and Innovation in Substitute Technologies – Evidence from the
US Sewing Machine Industry” RAND Journal of Economics, 2014, Volume 44, Issue 4, pp. 757-
778.
30
Landes DS. 1969. The Unbound Prometheus: Technological Change and Industrial
Development in Western Europe from 1750 to the Present. Cambridge University Press
Lee S, Moser P. 2015. War as the Mother of Invention? Effects of the World War II War Powers
Acts on Innovation in the United States. Working Paper.
Lerner, J, Tirole J. 2004. Efficient Patent Pools. American Economic Review, 94(3): 691-711.
Levin RC, Klevorick AK, Nelson RR, Winter SG. 1987. Appropriating the Returns from
Industrial Research and Development. Brookings Pap. Eco. Ac. 18:783-832
Li X, MacGarvie M, Moser P. 2014. Dead Poets' Property - The Copyright Act of 1814 and the
Price of Books in the Romantic Period http://ssrn.com/abstract=2170447.
MacGarvie M. and Moser P. 2015. Copyright and the Profitability of Authorship. In Economic
Analysis of the Digital Economy. Goldfarb A, Greenstein SM and Tucker CE, University of
Chicago Press.
MacLeod C. 1988. Inventing the Industrial Revolution: The English Patent System, 1660-1800.
Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press
Moser P. 2003. How Do Patent Laws Influence Innovation? Evidence from Nineteenth-Century
World Fairs. NBER Work. Pap. 9909
Moser P. 2005. How do Patent Laws Influence Innovation? Evidence from 19th-century World’s
Fairs. Am. Econ. Rev. 95:1215-12
Moser P. 2011. Do Patents Weaken the Localization of Innovations? Evidence from World's
Fairs, 1851-1915. J. Econ. Hist. 71:363-82
Moser P. 2012. Innovation without Patents. Journal of Law and Economics 55(1): 43-74.
Moser P, Voena A, Waldinger, F. 2014. German-Jewish Émigrés and US Invention. Am. Econ.
Rev. 194:3222-55
Moser P, Rhode PW. 2012. Did Plant Patents Create the American Rose? In The Rate and
Direction of Inventive Activity Revisited, ed. J Lerner, S Stern. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press
Moser, P. Ohmstedt J. and Rhode PW. 2014. “Patent Citations and the Size of Innovation –
31
Evidence from Hybrid Corn” http://ssrn.com/abstract=1888191.
North DC, Thomas RP. 1973. The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
Nuvolari A. 2004. Collective Invention during the British Industrial Revolution: the Case of the
Cornish Pumping Engine. Cambridge J. Econ. 28:347-63
Oberholzer‐Gee, Felix, and Koleman Strumpf. 2007. "The effect of file sharing on record sales:
An empirical analysis." Journal of political economy 115.1: 1-42.
Olmstead AL, Rhode PW. 2008. Biological Innovation and Productivity Growth in the
Antebellum Cotton Economy. J. Econ. Hist. 68:1123-71
Penrose ET. 1951. The Economics of the International Patent System. Baltimore: John Hopkins
University Press
Reimers, I. 2014. Copyrights and Generic Entry in Book Publishing. Northeastern University,
mimeo.
Robb, Harry C., Jr. 1964. “Plant Patents.” In Encyclopaedia of Patent Practice and Invention
Management, 641– 55. New York: Reinhold
Royal Commission. 1851. Official Catalogue of the Great Exhibition of the Work of Industry
Rosenberg, Nathan. 1963. Technological Change in the Machine Tool Industry, 1840-1910. J.
Econ. Hist. 23:414-43
Schiff E. 1971. Industrialization without National Patents. Princeton: Princeton University Press
Shapiro, C. 2001. Navigating the patent thicket: Cross licenses, patent pools, and standard setting.
In Innovation Policy and the Economy, Volume 1 (pp. 119-150). MIT press.
32
Sokoloff K. 1988. Inventive Activity in Early Industrial America: Evidence from
Patent Records, 1790-1846. J. Econ. Hist. 48:813-50
Scotchmer, Suzanne. 1991. Standing on the Shoulders of Giants: Cumulative Research and the
Patent Law. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Volume 5, Issue 1, 29-41.
Tallis J. 1852. Illustrated London: in commemoration of the Great Exhibition of All Nations in
1851. London: John Tallis and Company
Thomson R. 2009. Structures of Change in the Mechanical Age: Technological Innovation in the
United States, 1790-1865. Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press
Waldfogel, J. 2012. Copyright research in the digital age: Moving from piracy to the supply of
new products. The American Economic Review, 102(3), 337-342.
Whitworth, J. 1854. New York Industrial Exhibition. Special Report. Volume 11. Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
33
Figure 1 – Shares of Exhibits in Scientific Instruments against Patent Length in 1851
0.30
0.27 Sw itzerland
0.25
0.23 Denmark
Share of instruments
0.20
0.15
0.14 Bavaria
0.10 0.08 Britain
0.10 Wuerttemb, 0.10 France
0.05 0.05 Prussia
0.04 Belgium
-
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16
Patent length
Sources: From Moser (2005). “Share of instruments” measures the proportion of a country’s
exhibits that occur in the industry class “scientific instruments.” Patent length measures the
maximum duration of a patent grant in 1851.
34