CH 3
CH 3
OPTIMIZATION TECHNIQUES
Dear students, well come to the third chapter of the course Managerial Economics. This chapter
deals with the concept of optimizations. This chapter familiarizes you with the concepts of
differentiations, profit maximization conditions and techniques of solving constrained
optimization. At the end of the chapter there are self-test exercises designed to test your level of
understanding of the topics covered in this chapter. As usual we strongly advise you to attempt
them before you proceed to reading the next chapter.
Many problems in economics involve the determination of “optimal” solutions. For example, a
decision maker might wish to determine the level of output that would result in maximum profit.
The process of economic optimization essentially involves three steps: Defining the goals and
objectives of the firm, identifying the firm’s constraints and analyzing and evaluating all possible
alternatives available to the decision maker. In essence, economic optimization involves
maximizing or minimizing some objective function, which may or may not be subject to one or
more constraints.
3.2. Unconstrained Optimization
3.2.1. Profit Maximization: The First-Order Condition
We are now in a position to use the rules for taking first derivatives to find the level of output Q
that maximizes . Consider the total revenue and total cost functions:
( ) = = 18 ; since P = $18
TC (Q) = 6 + 33Q- 9Q2 + Q3
Teklebirhan A. (Asst. Prof) Page 1
= (18Q) - (6 + 33Q- 9Q2 + Q3) = -6 - 15Q + 9Q2 –Q3
The profit will be value of a function will be optimized (maximized or minimized) where the
slope of the function is equal to zero. In the present context, the first-order condition for profit
maximization is d /dQ = 0, thus
ax2 + bx + c = 0
Where a = -3, b = 18 and c = -15. Quadratic equations generally admit to two solutions, which
may be determined using the quadratic formula. The quadratic formula is given by the
expression:
The second-order conditions for a function with a maximum or minimum is taking the second
derivative of the function yields.
Table 3.1 First-order and second order conditions for functions of one independent variable
Then, the second order condition of the profit function start with the second derivative the profit
function
At Q1 = 5,
This satisfied the condition. Thus, as we have already seen, the firm can maximize his profit by
producing 5 units.
At Q2 = 1,
This not satisfied the condition. Thus, as we have already seen, the firm can’t maximize his
profit by producing 1 unit.
Therefore, the optimal level of output is 5 units of output to maximize his/her profit.
To determine the marginal effect of each variable, we take the first derivative of the function
with respect to each variable separately, treating independent the remaining variables as
constants. This process, known as taking partial derivatives, is denoted by replacing d with ∂.
Example
= − − …….…………………………..( )
=− − + …………………………….( )
To determine the values of the independent variables that maximize the objective function, we
simply set the first partial derivatives equal to zero and solve the resulting equations
simultaneously.
To determine the values of P and A that maximize the firm’s total sales, Q, set the first partial
derivatives in Equations (1) and (2) equal to zero.
80 - 4P - A = 0
-P - 6A+ 100 = 0
The above equations are the first-order conditions for a maximum. Solving these two linear
equations simultaneously in two unknowns yields (in thousands of dollars).
P = $16.54 A = $13.91
20y = 140
y=7
Substituting y = 7 into the constraint yields
x + 7 = 20
x = 13
Finally, substituting the values of x and y into the original TC function yields:
TC = 3(13)2 + 6(7)2 - (13) (7) = 507 + 294 - 91 = 710
2) The Lagrange multiplier method
Sometimes the substitution method may not be feasible because of more than one side constraint,
or because the objective function or side constraints are too complex for efficient solution. Here,
the Lagrange multiplier method can be used, which directly combines the objective function with
the side constraint(s).
Minimize: ( , ) = 3 + 6 −
Subject to: + = 20
Steps of Lagrange multiplier method
1. Set the constraint function
2. Form the lagrangian function by adding the constraint function after multiplication with
unknown factor
3. Take the partial derivatives and set them equal to zero
4. Solve the resulting equations simultaneous
Minimize: ( , ) = 3 + 6 −
Subject to: + = 20
=( , ) = + − + ( − − )
= = − − =
= − … … … … … … … … … .. ( )
= = − − =
= − … … … … … … … … . … … … .. ( )
= = − − = … … … … … … … … … .. ( )
= ……………………………………….( )
− − =
=
And = , =
Note that the values for x and y are the same as those obtained using the substitution method.
Interpretation: The value of X and Y that minimize the total cost are, 13 and 7 respectively,
and measures the change in the total cost if the constraint relaxed by one unit, say increased
from an output level of 20 units to 21 units, the firm’s total cost will increase by $ 71 Similarly,
if output is reduced from say 20 units to 19 units, total cost will be decreased by $71