An Option Theoretic Model For Ultimate Loss-Given-Default With Systematic Recovery Risk and Stochastic Returns On Defaulted Debt
An Option Theoretic Model For Ultimate Loss-Given-Default With Systematic Recovery Risk and Stochastic Returns On Defaulted Debt
1
Senior Financial Economist, Credit Risk Analysis Division, Department of Economic and International Affairs,
Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, One Independence Square, Suite 3144, Washington, DC 20024,
202-874-4728, [email protected]. The views expressed herein are those of the author and do not
necessarily represent a position taken by of the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency or the U.S.
Department of the Treasury.
2
This is equivalent to one minus the recovery rate, or dollar recovery as a proportion of par, or EAD assuming
all debt becomes due at default. We will speak in terms of LGD as opposed to recoveries with a view toward
credit risk management applications.
3
By default we mean either bankruptcy (Chapter 11) or other financial distress (payment default). In a banking
context, this defined as synonymous with respect to non-accrual on a discretionary or non-discretionary basis.
This is akin to the notion of default in Basel, but only proximate.
4
Note that this may be either the value of pre-petition instruments received valued at emergence from
bankruptcy, or the market values of new securities received in settlement of a bankruptcy proceeding or as the
result of a distressed restructuring.
5
Note that the former may viewed as a proxy to this, the pure economic notion.
6
In the context of bank loans, this is the cumulative net charge-off as a percent of book balance at default (the
net charge-off rate).
3. Theoretical model
The model that we propose is an extension of Black and Cox (1976). The baseline mode
features perpetual corporate debt, a continuous and a positive foreclosure boundary. The
former assumption removes the time dependence of the value of debt, thereby simplifying
the solution and comparative statics. The latter assumption allows us to study the
endogenous determination of the foreclosure boundary by the bank, as in Carey and Gordy
(2007). We extend the latter model by allowing the coupon on the loan to follow a stochastic
process, accounting for the effect of illiquidity. Note that in this framework, we assume no
restriction on asset sales, so that we do not consider strategic bankruptcy, as in Leland
(1994) and Leland and Toft (1996).
Let us assume a firm financed by equity and debt, normalized such that the total value of
perpetual debt is 1, divided such that there is a single loan with face value and a single
class of bonds with a face value of 1 . The loan is senior to that bond, and potentially has
covenants which permit foreclosure. The loan is entitled to a continuous coupon at a rate c,
which in the baseline model we take as a constant, but may evolve randomly. Equity
receives a continuous dividend, having a constant and a variable component, which we
denote as Vt , where Vt is the value of the firm’s assets at time t. We impose the
restriction that 0 r c , where r is the constant risk-free rate. The asset value of the firm,
net of coupons and dividends, follows a geometric Brownian motion with constant volatility :
dVt C
r dt dZt
Vt Vt
(3.1)
Where in (3.1) we denote the fixed cash outflows per unit time as:
C c 1 (3.2)
Where in (3.2), and are the continuous coupon rate on the bond and dividend yield on
equity, respectively. Default occurs at time t and is resolved after a fixed interval , at which
point dividend payments cease, but the loan coupon continues to accrue through the
settlement period. At the point of emergence, loan holders receive exp c ,Vt , or the
minimum of the legal claim or the value of the firm at emergence. We can value the loan at
resolution, under risk neutral measure, using the standard Merton (1974) formula. Denote the
total legal claim at default by:
D exp c 1 (3.3)
.
This follows from the assumption that the coupon c on the loan with face value continues
to accrue at the contractual rate throughout the resolution period , whereas the bond with
face value 1 does not.
7
Jarrow (2001) also has the advantage of isolating the liquidity premium embedded in defaultable bond
spreads.
dRt
t dt dZ t dWt (3.6)
Rt
d t t dt dBt (3.7)
Where the volatility parameter represents the sensitivity of recovery to the source of
uncertainty driving asset returns (or the “systematic factor”), implying that the instantaneous
1 dA dR
correlation between asset returns and recovery is given by Corrt t t . On
dt At Rt
the other hand, the volatility parameter represents the sensitivity of recovery to a source of
uncertainty that is particular to the return on collateral, also considered a “systematic factor”,
but independent of the asset return process. The third source of recovery uncertainty is given
by (3.7), where we model the instantaneous drift on the recovery by an Orhnstein-Uhlenbeck
mean-reverting process, with the speed of mean-reversion, the long-run mean, the
constant diffusion term, and Bt is a standard Weiner process having instantaneous
correlation with the source of randomness in the recovery process, given heuristically by
1
Corrt dBt , dWt . The motivation behind this specification is the overwhelming
dt
evidence that the mean LGD is stochastic.
Economic LGD on the loan is given by following expectation under physical measure:
LGDP Rt , t | , c, , , , , ,
exp c 2 2
1 Et min exp c , Rt exp t Z t Wt
2
z u2
1
having arguments to the Gaussian distribution function z e 2
du :
2 u
1 Rt 1 2
d ' log ˆ (3.10)
ˆ exp c 2
t
A well-known result (Bjerksund, 1991) is that the maturity-dependent volatility ˆ is given by:
2
2 1
ˆ 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 e 1 e 2
2
(3.11)
The recovery to the bondholders is the expectation of the minimum of the positive part of the
difference in the recovery and face value of the loan Rt exp c and the face value of
the bond B, which is structurally identical to a compound option valuation problem (Geske,
1977):
LGDBP Vt , Rt , t | , c, , , , , , ,
exp , 2 2
1
Et min B, max Rt exp t Z t Wt exp c, , 0
B 2
(3.12)
2 2
where Rt Rt exp t Z t Wt , is the value of recovery on the
2
collateral at the time of resolution. We can easily write down the closed-form solution for the
LGD on the bond according to the well-known formula for a compound option, where here
the “outer option” is a put, and the “inner option” is a call. Let R* be the critical level of
recovery such that the holder of the loan is just breaking even:
where is the time-to-resolution for the loan, which we assume to be prior to that for the
bond, B . Then the solution is given by:
exp b
LGDBP Rt , t | , c, , , , , , , , B 1 Rt , t | , c, , , , , , , , B
B
(3.14)
Rt , t | , c, , , , , , , , B
1 Rt 1 2
a log * t ˆ (3.16)
ˆ R 2
1 Rt 1 2
b log B t ˆ (3.17)
ˆ B B 2
We can extend this framework to arbitrary tranches of debt, such as for a subordinated issue,
in which case we follow the same procedure in order to arrive at an expression that involves
trivariate cumulative normal distributions. In general, a debt issue that is subordinated to the
dth degree results in a pricing formula that is a linear combination of d+1 variate Gaussian
distributions. These formulae become cumbersome very quickly, so for the sake of brevity
we refer the interested reader to Haug (2006) for further details.
4. Comparitive statics
In this section we discuss and analyze the sensitivity of ultimate LGD in to various key
parameters. In Figures 1 through 5 we examine the sensitivity of the ultimate LGD in the two-
factor model of Section 3, incorporating the optimal foreclosure boundary. In Figure 1, we
look at the ultimate LGD on the bond and the loan for three different settings of the factor
loading of the recovery rate process on the systematic factor in the firm value processes
( = 0.05, 0.45 and 0.9), while fixing other parameters at “reasonable” values motivated by
prior literature (drift in recovery = 0.08, face value of loan = 0.5, coupon rate on loan
c = 0.06, LGD side volatility = 0.3, volatility of recovery return drift process = 0.5, speed
of mean reversion in LGD return = 0.5, correlation between LGD side systematic factor
and random factor in recovery rate drift =0.3, and time-to-resolution =1). We observe that
ultimate LGD is monotonically decreasing at increasing rate in value of the firm at default,
that this increasing in the correlation between the PD and LGD side systematic factors, and
that this is also uniformly higher for bonds than for loans. In Figure 2 we show the ultimate
LGD as a function of the volatility in the recovery rate process attributable to the LGD side
systematic factor , fixing firm value at default at Vt = 0.5. We observe that ultimate LGD
increases at an increasing rate in this parameter, that for higher correlation between firm
asset value and recovery value return the LGD is higher and increases at a faster rate, and
that for bonds these curves lie above and increase at a faster rate. In Figure 3 we show the
ultimate LGD as a function of the volatility in the recovery rate process attributable to the
Loan-cor(R,V)=0.15
Loan-cor(R,V)=0.05
Loan-cor(R,V)=0.45
Bond-cor(R,V)=0.15
Bond-cor(R,V)=0.05
0.5
Bond-cor(R,V)=0.45
0.0
-0.5
-1.0
V_t
Stochastic Collateral & Drift Merton Model
LGD(nu|cor(R,V)={.05,.15,.45},V=.5,alpha=.08,lam=.5,c=.06,eta=.3,beta=.5,kap=.5,kce=.3,tau=1)
Figure 2: Ultimate Loss-Given-Default vs. Sensitivity of Recovery Process to LGD Side Systematic Factor
1.0
Loan-cor(R,V)=0.15
Loan-cor(R,V)=0.05
Loan-cor(R,V)=0.45
Bond-cor(R,V)=0.15
0.8
Bond-cor(R,V)=0.05
Bond-cor(R,V)=0.45
0.6
0.4
0.2
0.0
nu
Stochastic Collateral & Drift Merton Model
1.0
0.5
0.0
Loan-V=0.3
-0.5
Loan-V=0.5
Loan-V=0.8
Bond-V=0.3
Bond-V=0.5
-1.0
Bond-V=0.8
beta
Stochastic Collateral & Drift Merton Model
LGD(eta|cor(R,V)={.05,.15,.45},V=.5,alpha=.08,lam=.5,c=.06,beta=.5,kap=.5,nu=.5,kce=.3,tau=1)
Figure 4: Ultimate Loss-Given-Default vs. Volatility in the Drift of the Recovery Rate Process
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.4
Loan-cor(R,V)=0.15
Loan-cor(R,V)=0.05
0.2
Loan-cor(R,V)=0.45
Bond-cor(R,V)=0.15
Bond-cor(R,V)=0.05
0.0
Bond-cor(R,V)=0.45
eta
Stochastic Collateral & Drift Merton Model
LGD(kap|cor(R,V)={.05,.15,.45},V=.5,alpha=.08,lam=.5,c=.06,eta=.3,beta=.5,nu=.5,kce=.3,tau=1)
Loan-cor(R,V)=0.15
-0.5
Loan-cor(R,V)=0.05
Loan-cor(R,V)=0.45
Bond-cor(R,V)=0.15
Bond-cor(R,V)=0.05
-1.0
Bond-cor(R,V)=0.45
kappa
Stochastic Collateral & Drift Merton Model
i
E
time of emergence t as given by any of our models m, LGD P
s ,m θ
s ,m over the resolution
E D
period t i ,s t i ,s :
EtP LGDi , s ,t E
LGDi ,s ,t D i
LGDsP,m θ s ,m
1 ri,s
i t E
D i ,s i ,st D
(5.1)
where θ s ,m is the parameter vector for segment s under model m, expectation is taken with
respect to physical measure P, discounting is at risk adjusted rate appropriate to the
D
instrument ri , s and it is assumed that the time-to-resolution tiE,s tiD,s is known.
In order to account for the fact that we cannot observe expected recovery prices ex ante, as
only by coincidence would they coincide with expectations, we invoke market rationality to
postulate that for a segment homogenous with respect to recovery risk the difference
between expected and average realized recoveries should be small. We formulate this by
defining the normalized forecast error as:
LGDsP, m θ s ,m LGDi , s ,t E
i , s i
LGDi , s ,t D t t E
i,s
D
i,s
i
(5.2)
This is the forecast error as a proportion of the LGD implied by the market at default (a “unit-
free” measure of recovery uncertainty) and the square root of the time-to-resolution. This is a
mechanism to control for the likely increase in uncertainty with time-to-resolution, which
effectively puts more weight on longer resolutions, increasing the estimate of the loss-
severity. The idea behind this is that more information is revealed as the emergence point is
approached, hence a decrease in risk. Alternatively, we can analyze
LGDsP, m θ s ,m LGDi , s ,t E
i,s i
, the forecast error that is non-time adjusted, and argue that
LGDi , s ,t D
i
its standard error is proportional to tiE, s tiD, s , which is consistent with an economy in which
information is revealed uniformly and independently through time (Miu and Ozdemir, 2005).
Assuming that the errors i , s in (5.2) are standard normal,8 we may use full-information
maximum likelihood (FIML), by maximizing the log-likelihood (LL) function:
8
If the errors are i.i.d and from symmetric distributions, then we can still obtain consistent estimates through
ML, which has the interpretations as the quasi-ML estimator.
θ s ,m i 1
LGDi , s ,t D ti , s ti , s
E D
i
This turns out to be equivalent to minimizing the squared normalized forecast errors:
N LGDsP,m θ s ,m LGDi , s ,t E
2
Ns
s 1 2
arg min E arg min i , s , m
P
LGD s ,m i
θ s ,m
i 1 ti , s ti , s
D
LGDi , s ,t D θ s ,m i 1
i (5.4)
We may derive a measure of uncertainty of our estimate by the ML standard errors from the
Hessian matrix evaluated at the optimum:
1
2 LL 2
ˆˆ
Σ
θ s ,m θ s ,m
θ T
s ,m
θ s ,m θˆ s ,m
(5.5)
9
This an average of trading prices from 30 to 45 days following the default event. A set of dealers is polled
every day and the minimum /maximum quote is thrown out. This is done by experts at Moody’s.
Return on
1
Defaulted Debt 28.32% 3.47% 45.11% 19.57% 29.19% 3.44%
Bonds and Term Loans
2
LGD at Default 55.97% 0.96% 38.98% 3.29% 55.08% 0.93%
Discounted LGD
3 1072 51.43% 1.15% 59 33.89% 3.05% 1131 50.52% 1.10%
Time-to-
4
Resolution 1.7263 0.0433 0.0665 0.0333 1.6398 0.0425
Principal at
5
Default 207'581 9'043 416'751 65'675 218'493 9'323
Return on
1
Defaulted Debt 25.44% 3.75% 44.22% 21.90% 26.44% 3.74%
2
LGD at Default 57.03% 1.97% 37.02% 5.40% 55.96% 1.88%
Bonds
Discounted LGD
3 837 52.44% 1.30% 47 30.96% 3.00% 884 51.30% 1.25%
Time-to-
4
Resolution 1.8274 0.0486 0.0828 0.0415 1.7346 0.0424
Principal at
5
Default 214'893 11'148 432'061 72'727 226'439 11'347
Return on
1
Defaulted Debt 26.93% 7.74% 10.32% 4.61% 25.88% 7.26%
2
LGD at Default 54.37% 1.96% 33.35% 8.10% 53.03% 1.93%
Revolvers
Discounted LGD
3 250 52.03% 2.31% 17 33.33% 7.63% 267 50.84% 2.23%
Time-to-
4
Resolution 1.4089 0.0798 0.0027 0.0000 1.3194 0.0776
Principal at
5
Default 205'028 19'378 246'163 78'208 207'647 18'786
Return on 26.161 18.872
1
Defaulted Debt 32.57% 5.71% % % 32.21% 5.49%
2
LGD at Default 53.31% 9.90% 38.86% 7.22% 52.50% 3.21%
Loans
Discounted LGD
3 485 50.00% 1.68% 29 38.31% 5.79% 514 49.34% 2.25%
Time-to-
4
Resolution 1.3884 0.0605 0.0027 0.0000 1.3102 0.0816
Principal at
5
Default 193'647 11'336 291'939 78'628 199'192 16'088
Return on
1
Defaulted Debt 28.05% 3.17% 37.33% 15.29% 28.56% 3.11%
2
LGD at Default 55.66% 0.86% 37.72% 3.12% 54.69% 0.84%
Total
Discounted LGD
3 1322 51.55% 1.03% 76 33.76% 2.89% 1398 50.58% 0.99%
Time-to-
4
Resolution 1.6663 0.0384 0.0522 0.0260 1.5786 0.0376
Principal at
5
Default 207'099 8'194 378'593 54'302 216'422 8'351
1
Annualized return or yield on defaulted debt from the date of default (bankruptcy filing or
distressed renegotiation date) to the date of resolution (settlement of renegotiation or emergence
from Chapter 11). 2 Par minus the price of defaulted debt at the time of default (average 30-45
days after default) as a percent of par. 3 The ultimate dollar loss-given-default on the defaulted
debt instrument = 1 - (total recovery at emergence from bankruptcy or time of final settlement)/
(outstanding at default). Alternatively, this can be expressed as (outstanding at default - total
ultimate loss)/(outstanding at default). 4 The total instrument outstanding at default. 5 The time
in years from the instrument default date to the time of ultimate recovery.
Cash, Non-
Inventory, Unsecured
Accounts All Assets Current PPE &
Most & Other Total Total Total
Collateral Type Receivables & Real Assets & Second
Assets & Illiquid Unsecured Secured Collateral
& Estate Capital Lien
Equipment Collateral
Guarantees Stock
Average 66.81% 46.60% 51.95% 59.94% 55.02% 45.63% 46.25% 53.79% 53.31%
LGD at
Default1 Standard
Error 4.44% 11.79% 1.70% 5.27% 6.08% 5.07% 5.20% 1.47% 1.42%
Average 64.38% 56.03% 48.58% 50.62% 56.53% 30.70% 31.78% 50.51% 49.34%
Ultimate
LGD2 Standard
Error 5.09% 13.85% 1.91% 6.10% 6.88% 6.17% 5.20% 1.47% 1.42%
Return on Average 22.57% -5.80% 33.49% 35.68% 46.07% 22.39% 19.77% 33.03% 32.21%
Defaulted
Standard
Debt3
Error 18.20% 30.27% 6.89% 15.01% 27.64% 8.12% 7.93% 5.83% 5.49%
Average 61.50% 40.19% 36.02% 62.99% 61.24% 51.67% 50.73% 51.59% 51.57%
LGD at
Senior Secured Bonds
Default1 Standard
Error 36.50% 5.50% 5.03% 4.71% 11.63% 2.48% 23.79% 2.76% 2.74%
Average 76.81% 23.87% 36.67% 46.70% 60.32% 49.68% 50.15% 34.88% 35.04%
Ultimate
LGD2 Standard
Error 19.39% 3.90% 5.61% 5.71% 12.68% 3.19% 28.95% 2.96% 2.94%
Return on Average 23.86% 47.53% 35.03% 55.99% 14.33% 17.44% -27.66% 38.02% 36.63%
Defaulted
Standard
Debt3
Error 40.63% 7.18% 22.04% 20.10% 27.41% 6.34% 36.65% 9.05% 8.92%
Average 0.00% 0.00% 85.00% N/A 80.00% 55.83% 55.94% 56.63% 55.96%
Senior Unsecured Bonds
LGD at
Default1 Standard
Error N/A N/A N/A N/A N/A 1.42% 1.43% 10.36% 1.42%
Average 0.00% 0.00% 78.76% N/A 74.25% 48.33% 38.14% 32.03% 38.00%
Ultimate
LGD2 Standard
Error N/A N/A N/A N/A N/A 1.78% 1.79% 10.68% 1.77%
Return on Average 0.00% 0.00% 86.47% n 119.64% 23.40% 23.71% 25.62% 23.75%
Defaulted Standard
Debt3 Error N/A N/A N/A N/A N/A 4.80% 4.86% 22.61% 4.78%
Average 0.00% N/A 85.00% N/A 90.50% 58.09% 57.98% 83.46% 58.48%
Senior Subordinated Bonds
LGD at
Default1 Standard
Error N/A N/A N/A N/A N/A 2.48% 2.50% 4.58% 2.47%
Average N/A N/A 74.72% N/A 97.74% 54.51% 36.50% 40.47% 36.46%
Ultimate
LGD2 Standard
Error N/A N/A N/A N/A N/A 2.89% 2.90% 23.36% 2.87%
Return on Average 0.00% N/A 57.45% N/A -45.98% 33.57% 31.01% 150.30% 33.23%
Defaulted Standard
Debt3 Error N/A N/A N/A N/A N/A 10.44% 10.18% 147.62% 10.32%
Cash, Non-
Inventory, Unsecured
Accounts All Assets Current PPE &
Most & Other Total Total Total
Collateral Type Receivables & Real Assets & Second
Assets & Illiquid Unsecured Secured Collateral
& Estate Capital Lien
Equipment Collateral
Guarantees Stock
Average N/A 27.33% 0.00% N/A N/A 66.15% 66.58% 37.42% 65.81%
Junior Subordinated Bonds
LGD at
Default1 Standard
Error N/A N/A N/A N/A N/A 2.50% 2.48% 22.25% 2.50%
Average N/A 20.15% 0.00% N/A N/A 65.36% 33.62% 32.77% 33.54%
Ultimate
LGD2 Standard
Error N/A N/A N/A N/A N/A 3.06% 3.11% 18.92% 3.06%
Return on Average N/A 72.13% 0.00% N/A N/A 15.11% 15.74% 9.49% 15.59%
Defaulted
Standard
Debt3 Error N/A N/A N/A N/A N/A 10.93% 11.11% 31.36% 10.85%
Average 66.53% 41.57% 50.55% 61.56% 59.31% 57.41% 57.58% 53.40% 55.66%
LGD at
Default1 Standard
Total Instruments
Error 4.41% 6.18% 1.63% 3.39% 3.86% 1.09% 1.10% 1.28% 0.84%
Average 64.98% 32.93% 47.60% 48.58% 59.43% 51.46% 37.69% 36.13% 36.99%
Ultimate
LGD2 Standard
Error 4.90% 5.99% 1.82% 3.99% 4.28% 1.35% 1.37% 1.43% 0.99%
Return on Average 22.63% 33.17% 33.82% 46.22% 28.96% 24.12% 34.46% 23.63% 28.56%
Defaulted
Standard
Debt3 Error 17.36% 11.74% 6.56% 12.02% 13.90% 3.94% 3.97% 4.89% 3.11%
1 2
Par minus the price of defaulted debt at the time of default (average 30-45 days after default) as a percent of par. The
ultimate dollar loss-given-default on the defaulted debt instrument = 1 - (total recovery at emergence from bankruptcy or time
of final settlement)/(outstanding at default). Alternatively, this can be expressed as (outstanding at default - total ultimate
3
loss)/(outstanding at default). Annualized return or yield on defaulted debt from the date of default (bankruptcy filing or
distressed renegotiation date) to the date of resolution (settlement of renegotiation or emergence from Chapter 11).
10
Estimates for the baseline Merton structural model (BMSM) and for the Merton structural model with
stochastic drift (MSM-SD) are available upon request.
Table 3
Full information maximum likelihood estimation of option theoretic two-factor structural model of ultimate loss-given-default
with optimal foreclosure boundary, systematic recovery risk and random drift in the recovery process
(Moody's Ultimate Recovery Database 1987-2009)
Recovery Segment Parameter σ1 μ2 β3 ν4 σR5 πRβ6 πRν7 (βσ)0.5 κα8 α9 ηα10 ς11
Est.
Seniority Class
4.32% 18.63% 18.16% 36.83% 41.06% 19.55% 80.45% 12.82% 3.96% 37.08% 48.85% 20.88%
Revolving Credit / Term Loan
Std. Err. 0.5474% 0.9177% 0.7310% 1.3719% 0.4190% 0.0755% 4.2546% 3.2125% 0.9215%
Est. 5.47% 16.99% 16.54% 30.41% 34.62% 22.83% 77.17% 11.64% 4.40% 33.66% 44.43% 18.99%
Senior Secured Bonds
Std. Err. 0.5314% 0.8613% 0.6008% 1.3104% 0.7448% 0.0602% 3.5085% 2.6903% 0.8297%
Est. 6.82% 14.16% 13.82% 24.38% 28.02% 24.30% 75.70% 9.71% 5.50% 28.07% 37.04% 15.83%
Senior Unsecured Bonds
Std. Err. 0.5993% 1.0813% 1.3913% 1.9947% 0.6165% 0.0281% 2.8868% 2.2441% 0.6504%
Est. 8.19% 11.33% 12.02% 17.35% 21.11% 32.43% 67.57% 7.76% 4.42% 22.45% 29.68% 12.69%
Senior Subordinated Bonds
Std. Err. 0.6216% 1.0087% 1.0482% 1.0389% 0.9775% 0.0181% 2.0056% 2.0132% 1.0016%
Est. 9.05% 9.60% 10.24% 12.37% 16.06% 40.66% 59.34% 5.97% 3.34% 18.80% 18.69% 9.43%
Subordinated Bonds
Std. Err. 0.6192% 1.0721% 1.0128% 1.0771% 0.9142% 0.0106% 2.0488% 2.0014% 1.0142%
Statistics
subordinated bonds to 41.1% for senior loans. However, we see that the proportion of the
total recovery volatility attributable to systematic risk in collateral (firm) value, or the LGD
(PD) side, is increasing (decreasing) in seniority from 59.3% to 80.5% (40.7% to 19.6%) from
subordinated bonds to senior bank loans. Therefore, more senior instruments not only exhibit
greater recovery volatility than less senior instruments, but a larger component of this
volatility is driven by the collateral rather than the asset value process.
The next set of results concern the random drift in the recovery rate process. The MLE point
estimates of the parameter , the speed of the mean-reversion in, is hump-shaped in
seniority class, ranging from 3.3% subordinated bonds, to 5.5% for senior unsecured bonds,
to 4.0% for loans, respectively. Estimates of the parameter , the long-run mean of the
random drift in the recovery rate process, increase in seniority class from 18.8% for
subordinated bonds to 37.1% for senior bank loans. This monotonic increase in as we
move from lower to higher ranked instruments has the interpretation of greater expected
return of the recovery rate process inferred from lower ELGD (or greater expected recovery)
instruments as we move up in the hierarchy of the capital structure. We see that the volatility
of the random drift in the recovery rate process , increases in seniority class, ranging from
18.7% to 48.9% from subordinated bonds to senior loans, respectively. The monotonic
increase in as we move from lower to higher ranked instruments has the interpretation of
greater volatility in expected return of the recovery rate process inferred from lower ELGD (or
greater expected recovery) instruments as we move up in the hierarchy of the capital
structure. Finally, estimates of the parameter , the correlation of the random processes in
drift of and the level of the recovery rate process, increases in seniority class from 9.4% for
subordinated bonds to 20.9% for senior bank loans.
Finally with respect to parameter estimates, regarding the MLE point estimates of the
correlation between the default and recovery rate processes in the 2FSM-SR&RD, we
observe estimates are increasing in seniority class, ranging from 6.0% to 12.8% from
subordinated bonds to loans, respectively.
We conclude this section by discussing the quality of the estimates and model performance
measures. Across seniority classes, parameter estimates are all statistically significant, and
the magnitudes of such estimates are in general distinguishable across segments at
conventional significance levels. The likelihood ratio statistic indicates that we can reject the
7. Downturn LGD
In this section we explore the implications of our model with respect to downturn LGD in the
2FSM-SR&RD. This is a critical component of the quantification process in the Basel II
advanced IRB framework for regulatory capital. The Final Rule (FR) in the U.S. (OCC et al,
2007) requires banks that either wish, or are required, to qualify for treatment under the
advanced approach to estimate a downturn LGD. We paraphrase the FR, this is an LGD
estimated during an historical reference period during which default rates are elevated within
an institution’s loan portfolio.
In Figures 6 through 8 we plot the ratios of the downturn LGD to the expected LGD. This is
derived by conditioning on the 99.9th quantile of the PD side systematic factor in the 2FSM-
SR&RD. We show this for loans and bonds, as well as for different settings of key
parameters ( , or ) in each plot, with other parameters set to the MLE estimates.
We observe that the LGD mark-up for downturn is monotonically declining in ELGD, which is
indicative of lower tail risk in recovery for lower ELGD instruments. It is also greater than
unity in all cases, and approaches 1 as ELGD approaches 1. This multiple is higher for
bonds than for loans, as well as for either higher PD-LGD correlation , collateral
specific volatility or volatility in the drift of the recovery rate drift process ; although these
differences narrow for higher ELGD. For example, in Figure 6, we see that for loans having
11
In these tests we take the median LGD to be the cut-off that distinguishes between a high and low realized
LGD.
Figure 6: Ratio of Ultimate Downturn to Expected LGD vs. ELGD at 99.9th Percentile of PD-Side Systematic Factor Z
5
Loans/corr(R,V)=0.1
Loans/corr(R,V)=0.2
Loans/cor(R,V)=0.05
Bonds/corr(R,V)=0.1
Bonds/corr(R,V)=0.2
4
Bonds/cor(R,V)=0.05
DLGD/ELGD
3
2
1
ELGD
Stochastic Collateral & Drift Merton Model (Parameters Set to MLE Estimates for Loans & Bonds)
5
Loans/stdev(R|V)=0.1
Loans/stdev(R|V)=0.2
Loans/stdev(R|V)=0.05
Bonds/stdev(R|V)=0.1
Bonds/stdev(R|V)=0.2
4
Bonds/stdev(R|V)=0.05
DLGD/ELGD
3
2
1
ELGD
Stochastic Collateral & Drift Merton Model (Parameters Set to MLE Estimates for Loans & Bonds)
Figure 8: Ratio of Ultimate Downturn to Expected LGD vs. ELGD at 99.9th Percentile of PD-Side Systematic Factor Z
5
Loans/stdev(alpha)=0.1
Loans/stdev(alpha)=0.2
Loans/stdev(alpha)=0.05
Bonds/stdev(alpha)=0.1
Bonds/stdev(alpha)=0.2
4
Bonds/stdev(alpha)=0.05
DLGD/ELGD
3
2
1
ELGD
Stochastic Collateral & Drift Merton Model (Parameters Set to MLE Estimates for Loans & Bonds)
Before discussing the results, we briefly describe the two alternative frameworks for
predicting ultimate LGD that are to be compared to the 2FSM-SR&RD developed in this
paper. First, we implement a full-information maximum likelihood simultaneous equation
regression model (FIMLE-SEM) for ultimate LGD, which is an econometric model built upon
observations in URD at both the instrument and obligor level. FIMLE is used to model the
endogeneity of the relationship between LGD at the firm and instrument levels in an internally
consistent manner. This technique enables us to build a model that can help us understand
some of the structural determinants of LGD, and potentially improve our forecasts of LGD.
This model contains 199 observations from the URD™ with variables: long-term debt to
market value of equity, book value of assets quantile, intangibles to book value of assets,
interest coverage ratio, free cash flow to book value of assets, net income to net sales,
number of major creditor classes, percent secured debt, Altman Z-Score, debt vintage (time
since issued), Moody’s 12-month trailing speculative grade default rate, industry dummy,
filing district dummy and a pre-packaged bankruptcy dummy. Detailed discussion of the
results can be found in Jacobs and Karagozoglu (2011). The second alternative model we
consider addresses the problem of non-parametrically estimating a regression relationship, in
which there are several independent variables and in which the dependent variable is
Test
Model GBKDE4 2FSM-SR&RD5 FIMLE-SEM6
Statistic
Time 1 Year Ahead Prediction
th
Correlation2 5 Percentile 0.4206 0.5136 0.5803
th
95 Percentile 0.9095 0.9563 0.9987
2.0
Probability Density
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 1.2
Pearson Correlation
0
0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8
P-Value of HL Statistic
References
Acharya, V. V., Bharath, S. T, Srinivasan A., 2007, “Does industry-wide distress affect
defaulted firms? – evidence from creditor recoveries”. Journal of Political Economy, 85(3),
787-821.
Altman, E.I., 1968. “Financial ratios, discriminant analysis and the prediction of corporate
bankruptcy”, Journal of Finance, 23, 589-609.
Altman, E.I., R. Haldeman, Narayanan, P., 1977. “Zeta analysis: a new model to predict
corporate bankruptcies”, Journal of Banking and Finance, 1:1, July, 29-54.
Altman, E.I., Eberhart, A.,1994. “Do seniority provision protect bondholders’ investments?,
Journal of Portfolio Management”, Summer, 67-75.
Altman, E.I., Kishore, V.M, 1996. “Almost everything you wanted to know about recoveries
on defaulted bonds”, Financial Analysts Journal, Nov/Dec.
Altman, E.I., Resti, A, Sironi, A., 2001. “Analyzing and explaining default recovery rates”,
ISDA Research Report, London, December.
______, 2003. “Default recovery rates in credit risk modeling: a review of the literature and
empirical evidence”, Working paper, New York University Salomon Center, February.
Altman, E.I., Brady, B, Resti, A, Sironi, A 2005. “The link between default and recovery rates:
theory, empirical evidence and implications”, Journal of Business 78, 2203-2228.
Altman, E.I., 2006. “Default recovery rates and LGD in credit risk modeling and practice: an
updated review of the literature and empirical evidence”, Working paper, NYU Salomon
Center, November.
Araten, M., Jacobs, Jr., M. and Varshney, P, 2004. “Measuring loss-given-default on
commercial loans for the JP Morgan Chase wholesale bank: an 18 year internal study”, RMA
Journal, 86, 96-103.
Asarnow, Elliot and David Edwards, 1995, “Measuring loss on defaulted bank loans: a
24-year study”, Journal of Commercial Lending, Vol. 77, No.7, pp. 11-23.
Bakshi, G., Madan, D., Zhang, F., 2001. “Understanding the role of recovery in default risk
models: empirical comparisons and implied recovery rates”, Federal Reserve Board, Finance
and Economics Discussion Series #37.
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, 2003. The new Basel accord, Consultative
Document. Bank for International Settlements (BIS), April.
______, 2005. Guidance on paragraph 468 of the framework document. BIS, July.
______, 2006. International convergence on capital measurement and capital standards: a
revised framework. BIS, June.
Bjerksund, P., 1991. “Contingent claims evaluation when the convenience yield is stochastic:
analytical results”, Working paper, Norwegian School of Economics and Business
Administration.
Black, F. Scholes, M.,1973, “The pricing of options and corporate liabilities”, Journal of
Political Economy 81 (3): 637–654.