04 Handout Lecture - Complete
04 Handout Lecture - Complete
in continuous games
Nash equilibria in continuous games
• So far: games with a finite number of strategies.
• Next up: Games that allow for “many” strategies, i.e. games with a
continuous strategy set
• Examples:
• Pricing game – prices charged by firms
• Effort game – effort devoted to a project
Nash Equilibria in Continuous Games
How to find Nash Equilibria?
→ quantities 𝑞1 , 𝑞2 ∈ ℝ+
0
→ total supply 𝑄 = 𝑞1 + 𝑞2
To find an intersection we plug 𝑞𝑖𝐵𝑅 𝑞𝑗 into 𝑞𝑗𝐵𝑅 𝑞𝑖 and then solve for 𝑞𝑖 :
1 10 − 𝑞𝑖 − 𝑐
𝑞𝑖 = ⋅ 10 − −𝑐
2 2
∗ 10 − 𝑐
⇒ 𝑞𝑖 =
3
10−𝑐 10−𝑐
Since this is a symmetric game, we obtain that 𝑞1∗ , 𝑞2∗ = ( 3
, 3 ) is the
Nash equilibrium
Mixed Strategies
Mixed Strategies
• So far, we assumed that players make their choices with certainty…
(!) The set of mixed strategies includes the set of pure strategies:
A mixed strategy that assigns all probability to one pure strategy, e.g.
𝜎𝑖 = (0,1,0, … , 0) corresponds to playing pure strategy 𝑠2 with
probability 1.
Mixed strategies
Calculating the payoff of player 1 for strategy profile 𝜎 = ((1Τ2 , 1Τ2 ), (3Τ4 , 1Τ4 ))
Dominance and mixed strategies
We can generalize the definition of strictly and weakly dominated strategies to
games that allow for mixed strategies:
1. We say that for player i a strategy 𝜎𝑖 is strictly dominated by strategy 𝜎𝑖 ′ if
the payoff from strategy 𝜎𝑖 ′ is strictly greater than the payoff from strategy 𝜎𝑖
regardless of what the other players do:
𝑢𝑖 (𝜎𝑖 ′, 𝜎−𝑖 ) > 𝑢𝑖 (𝜎𝑖 , 𝜎−𝑖 ) for all 𝜎−𝑖 ∈ Δ𝑆−𝑖
• Notice that is suffices to check inequality (1) for every pure strategy
profile of other players. That is, is suffices to check
𝑢𝑖 (𝜎𝑖 ′, 𝑠−𝑖 ) > 𝑢𝑖 (𝜎𝑖 , 𝑠−𝑖 ) for all 𝑠−𝑖 ∈ 𝑆−𝑖 (2)
Dominance and mixed strategies
We can now apply the solution concepts of (iterated) deletion of strictly
dominated strategies to games that allow for mixed strategies.
𝐸[𝑢𝑖 𝜎𝑖 , 𝐿 ] = 𝛼 ∗ 6 + 1 − 𝛼 ∗ 2 = 2 + 4𝛼
𝐸[𝑢𝑖 𝜎𝑖 , 𝑅 ] = 𝛼 ∗ 3 + 1 − 𝛼 ∗ 5 = 5 − 5𝛼
• For D to be strictly dominated by σi it must hold that
2 + 4𝛼 > 5 and 5 − 5𝛼 > 1,
3 4
which is satisfied for all 𝛼 ∈ ,
4 5
.
Mixed Strategy Nash Equilibrium
Two familiar games Pl. 2
• Penalty shots / rock-paper-scissors: R P S
R 0, 0 -1, 1 1, -1
Pl. 1 P 1, -1 0, 0 -1, 1
S -1, 1 1, -1 0, 0
• Matching pennies:
Pl 2.
H T
H 1, -1 -1, 1
Pl. 1
T -1, 1 1, -1
1 1 1
Suppose player 2 plays 𝜎2∗ = , , i.e., H with probability and T with
2 2 2
1
probability .
2
Expected payoff of player 1 from playing
1 1
• H: 𝐸[𝑢1 𝐻, 𝜎2∗ ] = ∙ 1 + ∙ −1 = 0
2 2
1 1
• T: 𝐸[𝑢1 𝑇, 𝜎2∗ ] = ∙ −1 + ∙ 1 = 0
2 2
Hence, player 1 obtains the same payoff from playing H and playing T. That is,
1 1
he cannot improve upon strategy 𝜎1∗ = , by playing either H or T with a
2 2
higher probability ⟹ player 1 has no incentive to deviate.
Example 1: Matching pennies
• We know that this game has no Nash Pl 2.
equilibrium in pure strategies
• What about mixed-strategy Nash 1ൗ H 1ൗ2 T 1ൗ2
2
equilibria? H 1, -1 -1, 1
1 1 1 1 Pl. 1
• Guess: 𝜎1∗ , 𝜎2∗ = , , , is a NE 1ൗ T -1, 1 1, -1
2 2 2 2 2
1 1
We can replicate the argument to show that if player 1 plays 𝜎1∗ = , , then
2 2
player 2 has no incentive to deviate.
1 1 1 1
⟹ we have verified that 𝜎1∗ , 𝜎2∗ = , , , is a NE
2 2 2 2
Example: rock-paper-scissors
Pl. 2
R P S
R 0, 0 -1, 1 1, -1
Pl. 1 P 1, -1 0, 0 -1, 1
S -1, 1 1, -1 0, 0
• Guess:
1 1 1 1 1 1
𝜎1∗ , 𝜎2∗ = , , , , ,
3 3 3 3 3 3
Example 2: rock-paper-scissors Pl. 2
R P S
1 1 1 1 1 1
• Let’s verify that , , , , , R 0, 0 -1, 1 1, -1
3 3 3 3 3 3
is a Nash equilibrium:
Pl. 1 P 1, -1 0, 0 -1, 1
Consider player 1: S -1, 1 1, -1 0, 0
1 1 1
Payoff from playing “rock” if player 2 plays 𝜎2 ∗ = , ,
3 3 3
1 1 1
𝐸𝑈1 𝑅, 𝜎2 ∗ = ∙ 0 + ∙ −1 + ∙ 1 = 0
3 3 3
1 1 1
Payoff from playing “paper” if player 2 plays 𝜎2 ∗ = , ,
3 3 3
1 1 1
𝐸𝑈1 𝑃, 𝜎2 ∗ = ∙ 1 + ∙ 0 + ∙ (−1) = 0
3 3 3
1 1 1
Payoff from playing “scissors” if player 2 plays 𝜎2 ∗ = , ,
3 3 3
1 1 1
𝐸𝑈1 𝑆, 𝜎2 ∗ = ∙ −1 + ∙ 1 + ∙ 0 = 0
3 3 3
1 1 1
Expected payoff from playing 𝜎1 = 𝛼, 𝛽, 1 − 𝛼 − 𝛽 if player 2 plays 𝜎2 ∗ = , ,
3 3 3
𝐸𝑈1 𝜎1∗, 𝜎2 ∗ = 𝛼 ∙ 0 + 𝛽 ∙ 0 + (1 − 𝛼 − 𝛽) ∙ 0 = 0
⇒ Player 1 has not incentive to deviate (and by symmetry the same is true for player 2)
Mixed strategy Nash equilibrium
We have seen that it suffices to check that no player wants to deviate to
one of his pure strategies. We summarize this in the following fact:
Examples:
• Average height of a group
• Average scores in tests/exams
• Average marathon finishing times
• Batting averages in baseball
• Average points/rebounds in basketball
• ...
Mixed strategies & best responses
Important observation:
If a mixed strategy is a best response, then each of the pure strategies
involved in the mix must itself be a best response. In particular, each
must yield the same expected payoff.
Formal statement:
If a mixed strategy 𝜎𝑖 for player 𝑖 is a best response to a strategy profile
𝜎−𝑖 then each pure strategies 𝑠𝑖 with 𝑝𝑖 𝑠𝑖 > 0 must itself be a best
response. That is, it must hold that 𝐸𝑈𝑖 𝑠𝑖 , 𝜎−𝑖 ≥ 𝐸𝑈𝑖 𝑠𝑖 ′, 𝜎−𝑖 ∀𝑠𝑖 ′ ∈ 𝑆𝑖 .
This implies that
𝐸𝑈𝑖 𝑠𝑖 , 𝜎−𝑖 = 𝐸𝑈𝑖 𝑠𝑖 ′, 𝜎−𝑖 ∀𝑠𝑖 , 𝑠𝑖′ with 𝑝𝑖 𝑠𝑖 , 𝑝𝑖 𝑠𝑖 ′ > 0
Example 2: Battle of the sexes
Pl 2.
• We know that this game has two Nash
equilibria in pure strategies (O, O), (G, G) O G
• Are there any additional mixed-strategy O 3, 1 0, 0
Nash equilibria? How to find them? Pl. 1
G 0, 0 1, 3
In a mixed strategy equilibrium, any pure strategy in the mix must be a best-
response, which is the case if
1
𝐸𝑈1 𝑂 = 𝐸𝑈1 𝐺 ⟹ 𝑞 =
4
For player 1 to be indifferent between playing O and G, player 2 must mix
between O and G with probabilities 1Τ4 , 3Τ4 .
Example 2: Battle of the sexes Pl 2.
O G
• We know that in a Nash equilibrium, for
player 1 wanting to mix between O and G, O 3, 1 0, 0
player 2 must play 𝜎2 = 1Τ4 , 3Τ4 . Pl. 1
G 0, 0 1, 3
Suppose player 1 plays 𝜎1 = (𝑝, 1 − 𝑝), then player 2’s best-response is:
3
𝑂 𝑖𝑓 𝑝 ≥
𝐵𝑅2 𝑝, 1 − 𝑝 = 4
3
𝐺 𝑖𝑓 𝑝 ≤
4
We can illustrate this in a graph
Example 2: Battle of the sexes
Best-response functions:
𝐵𝑅2(𝑝)
We can see that this game has
three Nash equilibria equal to the
intersections points of the
best-response functions.
𝐵𝑅1 (𝑞)
(O, O): ( 1, 0 , (1, 0))
(G, G): ( 0, 1 , (0, 1))
and
𝜎1∗, 𝜎2∗ = ( .75, . 25 , .25, .75 )
Finding mixed-strategy Nash equilibria
• Use IDSDS first to reduce the strategies that you need to consider
when identifying mixed strategy Nash equilibria.