Unit 3 Decision Analysis Model
Unit 3 Decision Analysis Model
Decision Analysis
Learning Objectives
After completing this unit, students will be able to:
1. List the steps of the decision-making process.
2. Describe the types of decision-making
environments.
3. Make decisions under uncertainty.
4. Use probability values to make decisions under
risk.
5. Develop accurate and useful decision trees.
6. Revise probabilities using Bayesian analysis.
7. Use computers to solve basic decision-making
problems.
8. Understand the importance and use of utility theory
in decision making.
Decision Analysis 3-2
1
Unit Outline
3.1 Introduction
3.2 The Six Steps in Decision Making
3.3 Types of Decision-Making Environments
3.4 Decision Making under Uncertainty
3.5 Decision Making under Risk
3.6 Decision Trees
3.7 How Probability Values Are Estimated by
Bayesian Analysis
3.8 Utility Theory
3.1 Introduction
2
3.2 The Six Steps in Decision Making
3
Thompson Lumber Company
Step 4 – List the payoffs.
Identify conditional values for the profits
for large plant, small plant, and no
development for the two possible market
conditions.
Step 5 – Select the decision model.
This depends on the environment and
amount of risk and uncertainty.
Step 6 – Apply the model to the data.
Solution and analysis are then used to aid
in decision-making.
FAVORABLE UNFAVORABLE
ALTERNATIVE MARKET ($) MARKET ($)
Construct a large plant 200,000 –180,000
Do nothing 0 0
4
3.3 Types of Decision-Making
Environments
Type 1: Decision making under certainty
The decision maker knows with
certainty the consequences of every
alternative or decision choice.
5
Maximax
Used to find the alternative that maximizes the
maximum payoff.
Locate the maximum payoff for each alternative.
Select the alternative with the maximum number.
STATE OF NATURE
FAVORABLE UNFAVORABLE MAXIMUM IN
ALTERNATIVE MARKET ($) MARKET ($) A ROW ($)
Maximin
Used to find the alternative that maximizes
the minimum payoff.
Locate the minimum payoff for each alternative.
Select the alternative with the maximum
number.
STATE OF NATURE
FAVORABLE UNFAVORABLE MINIMUM IN
ALTERNATIVE MARKET ($) MARKET ($) A ROW ($)
Construct a small
100,000 –20,000 –20,000
plant
Do nothing 0 0 0
Maximin
Decision Analysis 3-12
6
Criterion of Realism (Hurwicz)
This is a weighted average compromise
between optimism and pessimism.
Select a coefficient of realism , with 0≤α≤1.
A value of 1 is perfectly optimistic, while a
value of 0 is perfectly pessimistic.
Compute the weighted averages for each
alternative.
Select the alternative with the highest value.
STATE OF NATURE
CRITERION
FAVORABLE UNFAVORABLE OF REALISM
ALTERNATIVE MARKET ($) MARKET ($) ( = 0.8) $
7
Equally Likely (Laplace)
Considers all the payoffs for each alternative
Find the average payoff for each alternative.
Select the alternative with the highest average.
STATE OF NATURE
FAVORABLE UNFAVORABLE ROW
ALTERNATIVE
MARKET ($) MARKET ($) AVERAGE ($)
Construct a small
100,000 –20,000 40,000
plant
Equally likely
Do nothing 0 0 0
Minimax Regret
Based on opportunity loss or regret, this is
the difference between the optimal profit and
actual payoff for a decision.
Create an opportunity loss table by determining
the opportunity loss from not choosing the best
alternative.
Opportunity loss is calculated by subtracting
each payoff in the column from the best payoff
in the column.
Find the maximum opportunity loss for each
alternative and pick the alternative with the
minimum number.
8
Minimax Regret
Determining Opportunity Losses for Thompson Lumber
STATE OF NATURE
200,000 – 0 0–0
Minimax Regret
Opportunity Loss Table for Thompson Lumber
STATE OF NATURE
FAVORABLE UNFAVORABLE
ALTERNATIVE MARKET ($) MARKET ($)
Construct a large plant 0 180,000
Do nothing 200,000 0
9
Minimax Regret
STATE OF NATURE
FAVORABLE UNFAVORABLE MAXIMUM IN
ALTERNATIVE MARKET ($) MARKET ($) A ROW ($)
Construct a large
0 180,000 180,000
plant
Construct a small
100,000 20,000 100,000
plant
Minimax
Do nothing 200,000 0 200,000
10
EMV for Thompson Lumber
Suppose each market outcome has a probability of
occurrence of 0.50.
Which alternative would give the highest EMV?
The calculations are:
STATE OF NATURE
FAVORABLE UNFAVORABLE
ALTERNATIVE MARKET ($) MARKET ($) EMV ($)
Construct a large
200,000 –180,000 10,000
plant
Construct a small
100,000 –20,000 40,000
plant
Do nothing 0 0 0
Probabilities 0.50 0.50
Largest EMV
11
Expected Value of Perfect
Information (EVPI)
EVPI places an upper bound on what you should
pay for additional information.
EVPI = EVwPI – Maximum EMV
12
Expected Value of Perfect
Information (EVPI)
Decision Table with Perfect Information
STATE OF NATURE
FAVORABLE UNFAVORABLE
ALTERNATIVE MARKET ($) MARKET ($) EMV ($)
Construct a large
200,000 -180,000
plant
Construct a small
100,000 -20,000
plant
Do nothing 0 0
With perfect
200,000 0
information
Probabilities 0.5 0.5
13
Expected Value of Perfect
Information (EVPI)
The maximum EMV without additional information is
$40,000.
EVPI = EVwPI – Maximum EMV
= $100,000 - $40,000
= $60,000
14
Expected Opportunity Loss
STATE OF NATURE
FAVORABLE UNFAVORABLE
ALTERNATIVE MARKET ($) MARKET ($) EOL
Construct a large plant 0 180,000
Construct a small
100,000 20,000
plant
Do nothing 200,000 0
Probabilities 0.50 0.50
Sensitivity Analysis
Sensitivity analysis examines how the decision
might change with different input data.
For the Thompson Lumber example:
15
Sensitivity Analysis
EMV(Large Plant) = $200,000P – $180,000)(1 – P)
= $200,000P – $180,000 + $180,000P
= $380,000P – $180,000
EMV(Small Plant) = $100,000P – $20,000)(1 – P)
= $100,000P – $20,000 + $20,000P
= $120,000P – $20,000
EMV(Do Nothing) = $0P + 0(1 – P)
= $0
Sensitivity Analysis
EMV Values
$300,000
–$200,000
16
Sensitivity Analysis
Point 1:
EMV(do nothing) = EMV(small plant)
20,000
0 $120,000 P $20,000 P 0.167
120,000
Point 2:
EMV(small plant) = EMV(large plant)
$120,000 P $20,000 $380,000 P $180,000
160,000
P 0.615
260,000
Sensitivity Analysis
EMV Values
$300,000
–$200,000
17
Using Excel
Input Data for the Thompson Lumber Problem
Using Excel QM
Using Excel
18
3.6 Decision Trees
Any problem that can be presented in a
decision table can also be graphically
represented in a decision tree.
Decision trees are most beneficial when a
sequence of decisions must be made.
All decision trees contain decision points
or nodes, from which one of several alternatives
may be chosen.
All decision trees contain state-of-nature
points or nodes, out of which one state of
nature will occur.
Five Steps of
Decision Tree Analysis
19
Structure of Decision Trees
Trees start from left to right.
Trees represent decisions and outcomes
in sequential order.
Squares represent decision nodes.
Circles represent states of nature nodes.
Lines or branches connect the decisions
nodes and the states of nature.
Favorable Market
A Decision Node
1
Unfavorable Market
Favorable Market
Construct
Small Plant
2
Unfavorable Market
20
Thompson’s Decision Tree
Payoffs
Favorable Market (0.5)
$200,000
1
Unfavorable Market (0.5)
–$180,000
$0
Decision Analysis 3-41
No Plant
No Plant
No Plant
21
Thompson’s Complex Decision Tree
22
Thompson’s Complex Decision Tree
First Decision Second Decision Payoffs
Point Point
$106,400 Favorable Market (0.78)
$190,000
Unfavorable Market (0.22)
$106,400
–$190,000
$63,600 Favorable Market (0.78)
Small $90,000
Unfavorable Market (0.22)
Plant –$30,000
No Plant
–$10,000
–$87,400 Favorable Market (0.27)
$190,000
Unfavorable Market (0.73)
–$190,000
$2,400 Favorable Market (0.27)
$2,400
Small $90,000
Unfavorable Market (0.73)
Plant –$30,000
No Plant
–$10,000
$49,200
23
Sensitivity Analysis
Sensitivity Analysis
p = probability of a favorable survey result
(1 – p) = probability of a negative survey result
EMV(node 1) = ($106,400)p +($2,400)(1 – p)
= $104,000p + $2,400
We are indifferent when the EMV of node 1 is the
same as the EMV of not conducting the survey,
$40,000
$104,000p + $2,400 = $40,000
$104,000p = $37,600
p = $37,600/$104,000 = 0.36
If p<0.36, do not conduct the survey. If p>0.36,
conduct the survey.
Decision Analysis 3-48
24
3.7 Bayesian Analysis
There are many ways of getting
probability data. It can be based on:
Management’s experience and intuition.
Historical data.
Computed from other data using Bayes’
theorem.
Bayes’ theorem incorporates initial
estimates and information about the
accuracy of the sources.
It also allows the revision of initial
estimates based on new information.
Decision Analysis 3-49
P (FM) = 0.50
P (UM) = 0.50
25
Calculating Revised Probabilities
Through discussions with experts Thompson has
learned the information in the table below.
He can use this information and Bayes’ theorem
to calculate posterior probabilities.
STATE OF NATURE
RESULT OF FAVORABLE MARKET UNFAVORABLE MARKET
SURVEY (FM) (UM)
Negative (predicts
unfavorable P (survey negative | FM) P (survey negative | UM)
market for = 0.30 = 0.80
product)
P ( B | A ) P ( A)
P( A | B)
P ( B | A) P ( A) P ( B | A ) P ( A )
where
A, B any two events
A complement of A
26
Calculating Revised Probabilities
(0.70)(0.50 ) 0.35
0.78
(0.70)(0.50 ) (0.20 )(0.50) 0.45
(0.20)(0.50 ) 0.10
0.22
(0.20)(0.50 ) (0.70 )(0.50) 0.45
27
Calculating Revised Probabilities
(0.30)(0.50 ) 0.15
0.27
(0.30)(0.50 ) (0.80 )(0.50) 0.55
(0.80)(0.50 ) 0.40
0.73
(0.80)(0.50 ) (0.30 )(0.50) 0.55
CONDITIONAL
PROBABILITY P(STATE OF
P(SURVEY NATURE |
STATE OF NEGATIVE | STATE PRIOR JOINT SURVEY
NATURE OF NATURE) PROBABILITY PROBABILITY NEGATIVE)
FM 0.30 X 0.50 = 0.15 0.15/0.55 = 0.27
28
Using Excel
Formulas Used for Bayes’ Calculations in Excel
Program 3.2A
Decision Analysis 3-57
Using Excel
Results of Bayes’ Calculations in Excel
29
Potential Problems Using
Survey Results
30
Utility Theory
Your Decision Tree for the Lottery Ticket
$2,000,000
Accept
Offer
$0
Heads
Reject (0.5)
Offer
Tails
(0.5)
EMV = $2,500,000
$5,000,000
Utility Theory
Utility assessment assigns the worst outcome a
utility of 0, and the best outcome, a utility of 1.
A standard gamble is used to determine utility
values.
When you are indifferent, your utility values are
equal.
31
Standard Gamble for Utility
Assessment
(p)
Best Outcome
Utility = 1
(1 – p) Worst Outcome
Utility = 0
Other Outcome
Utility = ?
Investment Example
Jane Dickson wants to construct a utility curve
revealing her preference for money between $0
and $10,000.
A utility curve plots the utility value versus the
monetary value.
An investment in a bank will result in $5,000.
An investment in real estate will result in $0 or
$10,000.
Unless there is an 80% chance of getting $10,000
from the real estate deal, Jane would prefer to
have her money in the bank.
So if p = 0.80, Jane is indifferent between the bank
or the real estate investment.
Decision Analysis 3-64
32
Investment Example
p = 0.80 $10,000
U($10,000) = 1.0
(1 – p) = 0.20 $0
U($0.00) = 0.0
$5,000
U($5,000) = p = 0.80
Investment Example
We can assess other utility values in the same way.
For Jane these are:
33
Utility Curve
1.0 –
U ($10,000) = 1.0
U ($7,000) = 0.90
0.9 –
0.8 –
U ($5,000) = 0.80
0.7 –
0.6 –
U ($3,000) = 0.50
Utility
0.5 –
0.4 –
0.3 –
0.2 –
0.1 –
U ($0) = 0
| | | | | | | | | | |
$0 $1,000 $3,000 $5,000 $7,000 $10,000
Monetary Value
Figure 3.9
Decision Analysis 3-67
Utility Curve
Jane’s utility curve is typical of a risk avoider.
She gets less utility from greater risk.
She avoids situations where high losses might occur.
As monetary value increases, her utility curve increases
at a slower rate.
34
Preferences for Risk
Risk
Utility Avoider
Risk
Seeker
Figure 3.10
Monetary Outcome
Decision Analysis 3-69
Utility as a
Decision-Making Criteria
35
Utility as a
Decision-Making Criteria
Utility as a
Decision-Making Criteria
Tack Lands
Point Down (0.55)
–$10,000
36
Utility as a
Decision-Making Criteria
1.00 –
0.75 –
Utility
0.50 –
0.30 –
0.25 –
0.15 –
0.05 –
Figure 3.12 0 |– | | | |
–$20,000 –$10,000 $0 $10,000 $20,000
Monetary Outcome
37
Utility as a
Decision-Making Criteria
Tack Lands
Point Down (0.55)
0.05
Don’t Play
0.15
Decision Analysis 3-75
38