Problem Set 1
Information Economics (Ec 515) · George Georgiadis
Due in Lingfeng Que’s mailbox (Room 436, 270 Bay State Road), or by e-mail to [email protected] at 12:30, Monday,
September 22
Problem 1.
Consider the following “portfolio choice” problem. The investor has initial wealth w and utility u ( x ) =
ln ( x ). There is a safe asset (such as a US government bond) that has net real return of zero. There is also a
risky asset with a random net return that has only two possible returns, R1 with probability q and R0 with
probability 1 q. Let A be the amount invested in the risky asset, so that w A is invested in the safe asset.
1. Find A as a function of w. Does the investor put more or less of his portfolio into the risky asset as his
wealth increases?
2. Another investor has the utility function u ( x ) = e x. How does her investment in the risky asset
change with wealth?
u00 ( x )
3. Find the coefficients of absolute risk aversion r ( x ) = u0 ( x )
for the two investors. How do they
depend on wealth? How does this account for the qualitative difference in the answers you obtain in
parts (1) and (2)?
Problem 2.
You have an opportunity to place a bet on the outcome of an upcoming race involving a certain female horse
named Bayes: if you bet x dollars and Bayes wins, you will have w0 + x, while if she loses you will have
w0 x, where w0 is your initial wealth.
1. Suppose that you believe the horse will win with probability p and that your utility for wealth w is
ln (w). Find your optimal bet as a function of p and w0 .
2. You know little about horse racing, only that racehorses are either winners or average, that winners
win 90% of their races, and that average horses win only 10% of their races. After all the buzz you’ve
been hearing, you are 90% sure that Bayes is a winner. What fraction of your wealth do you plan to
bet?
3. As you approach the betting window at the track, you happen to run into your uncle. He knows rather
a lot about horse racing: he correctly identifies a horse’s true quality 95% of the time. You relay your
excitement about Bayes. “Don’t believe the hype,” he states. “That Bayes mare is only an average
horse.” What do you bet now (assume that the rules of the track permit you to receive money only if
the horse wins)?
1
Problem 3.
If an individual devotes a units of effort in preventative care, then the probability of an accident is 1 a
(thus, effort can only assume values in [0, 1]). Each individual is an expected utility maximizer with utility
function p ln ( x ) + (1−p) ln (y) a2 , where p is the probability of an accident, x is wealth if there is an
accident, and y is wealth if there is no accident. If there is no insurance, then x = 50, while y = 150.
1. Suppose first there is no market for insurance. What level of a would the typical individual choose?
What would her expected utility be?
2. Assume that a is verifiable. What relationship do you expect to prevail between x and y in a competi-
tive insurance market? What relationship do you then expect to prevail between x and a?
3. Derive the value of a, x and y that maximize the typical customer’s expected utility. What is the value
of this maximized expected utility?
4. Suppose that a is not verifiable. What would happen (i.e., what would the level of a and expected
utility be) if the same contract (i.e., same x and y values) as in (3) were offered by competitive firms?
Do you expect this would be an equilibrium?
5. Under the non-verifiability assumption, what relationship must prevail between x, y, and a? Use this
relationship along with the assumption of perfect competition to derive a relationship between x and
a that contracts offered by insurers must have. Finally, find the level of a that maximizes the expected
utility of the typical consumer, and find that level of expected utility.
6. Summarize your answers by ranking the levels of a and the expected utilities for each of the cases in
(1), (3), (4) and (5). What do you notice?
Problem 4.
An agent can work for a principal. The agent’s effort, a affects current profits, q1 = a + # q1 , and future
profits, q2 = a + # q2 , where # qt are random shocks, and they are i.i.d with normal distribution N (0, sq2 ).
The agent retires at the end of the first period, and his compensation cannot be based on q2 . However, his
compensation can depend on the stock price P = 2a + # P , where # P ⇠ N (0, sP2 ). The agent’s utility function
is exponential and equal to h i
2
h t c a2
e
where t is the agent’s income, while his reservation utility is t̄.1 The principal chooses the agent’s compen-
sation contract t = w + f q1 + sP to maximize her expected profit, while accounting for the agent’s IR and
IC constraints.
1. Derive the optimal compensation contract t = w + f q1 + sP.
2. Discuss how it depends on sP2 and on its relation with sq2 . Offer some intuition?
2
h t c a2 )
1 Reservation utility t̄ means that the agent’s IR constraint requires that E e e h t̄ .
2
Problem 5.
Two agents can work for a principal. The output of agent i (i = 1, 2), is qi = ai + # i , where ai is agent i’s
effort level and # i is a random shock. The # i ’s are independent of each other and normally distributed with
mean 0 and variance s2 . In addition to choosing a2 , agent 2 can engage in a second activity b2 . This activity
does not affect output directly, but rather reduces the effort cost of agent 1. The interpretation is that agent
2 can help agent 1 (but not the other way around). The effort cost functions of the agents are
1
y1 ( a1 , b2 ) = (a b2 )2
2 1
and
1 2
y2 ( a2 , b2 ) = a + b22 .
2 2
Agent 1 chooses her effort level a1 only after she has observed the level of help b2 . Agent i’s utility function
is exponential and equal to
h (wi yi ( ai ,b2 ))]
e[
where wi is the agent’s income. The agent’s reservation utility is 1, which corresponds to a reservation
wage of 0. The principal is risk neutral and is restricted to linear incentive schemes. The incentive scheme
for agent i is
wi = z i + v i q i + u i q j
1. Assume that a1 , a2 , and b2 are observable. Solve the principal’s problem by maximizing the total ex-
pected surplus with respect to a1 , a2 , and b2 . Explain intuitively why a1 > a2 .
2. Assume from now on that a1 , a2 , and b2 are not observable. Solve again the principal’s problem. Ex-
plain intuitively why u1 = 0.
3. Assume that the principal cannot distinguish whether a unit of output was produced by agent 1 or
agent 2. The agents can thus engage in arbitrage, claiming that all output was produced by one of them.
Assume that they will do so whenever it increases the sum of their wages. Explain why the incentive
scheme in part 2 above leads to arbitrage. What additional constraint does arbitrage impose on the
principal’s problem? Solve this problem, and explain intuitively why u1 > 0.