Course Title: Economics For Decision Making Module-3 (09 Hours) Cost Analysis & Production Analysis
Course Title: Economics For Decision Making Module-3 (09 Hours) Cost Analysis & Production Analysis
Module-3(09 Hours)
Cost Analysis & Production Analysis:
Concepts of Production, production function with one variable input - Law of
Variable Proportion, Laws of returns to scale, Indifference Curves, ISO-Quants
& ISO-Cost line, Economies of scale, Diseconomies of scale. Types of cost, Cost
curves, Cost – Output Relationship in the short run and in the long run, Long-
Run Average Cost (LAC) curve
Break Even Analysis:Meaning, Assumptions, Determination of BEA,
Limitations, Margin of safety, Uses of BEA In Managerial decisions (Theory and
simple problems).
Concepts of Production
The concept of production in economics and business refers to the process of
transforming inputs into outputs, typically goods and services, that are useful for
meeting human needs and wants. It is central to all forms of economic activity,
whether on the individual, corporate, or national level.
These are the essential inputs required to produce goods and services:
Q=f(L)Q = f(L)Q=f(L)
where:
The specific form of the production function can vary depending on the context
and the nature of the relationship between input and output. A commonly used
functional form is the Cobb-Douglas production function, which is often written
as:
Q=ALαQ = A L^\alphaQ=ALα
where:
In this case:
A key feature of many production functions with one variable input is the law of
diminishing marginal returns, which states that as the amount of input (e.g.,
labor) increases, while other factors remain constant, the additional output
(marginal product) produced by an additional unit of input eventually decreases.
Mathematically, the marginal product of labor is the derivative of the production
function with respect to LLL:
MPL=dQdLMP_L = \frac{dQ}{dL}MPL=dLdQ
Example
Q=10L0.5Q = 10 L^{0.5}Q=10L0.5
In this case:
A=10A = 10A=10,
α=0.5\alpha = 0.5α=0.5.
Conclusion
A production function with one variable input describes how output changes as a
single input changes, and it can exhibit different behaviors depending on the
functional form and the returns to the input. A common example is the Cobb-
Douglas function, which shows diminishing returns when the exponent α\alphaα is
between 0 and 1.
Explanation:
The law states that if the quantity of one factor of production (like labor or capital)
is increased while all other factors remain fixed, the resulting increase in output
will initially increase at an increasing rate, but after a certain point, the output will
increase at a decreasing rate. Eventually, further increases in the variable input will
result in a decrease in output.
This law is typically observed in the short run, where at least one factor (such as
capital or land) is fixed, and only the quantity of the variable input (such as labor)
can be changed.
Key Points:
Diminishing Returns: The core idea behind the Law of Variable Proportion
is that beyond a certain level, additional units of the variable input lead to
smaller and smaller increases in output, and eventually may even reduce
total output.
Short-Run Analysis: This law applies primarily in the short run, when at
least one factor is fixed and cannot be changed.
Real-World Examples: A common example would be a factory where the
amount of machinery is fixed, and additional workers are hired. Initially,
more workers will result in higher productivity, but eventually, the factory
space and equipment will be fully utilized, and adding more workers will
lead to overcrowding and inefficiency.
Graphical Representation:
The law can be graphically represented by plotting total output against the quantity
of the variable input:
Importance:
Understanding the Law of Variable Proportion helps firms in deciding how much
of a variable input to use and when it might be inefficient to add more resources. It
is a crucial concept for businesses to optimize production in the short run.
In this example, the land is the fixed factor and labour is the variable factor. The table
shows the different amounts of output when you apply different units of labour to one
acre of land which needs fixing.
The following diagram explains the law of variable proportions. In order to make a
simple presentation, we draw a Total Physical Product (TPP) curve and a Marginal
Physical Product (MPP) curve as smooth curves against the variable input (labour).
Changes in output when all factors change in the same proportion are referred to as
the law of return to scale. This law applies only in the long run when no factor is
fixed, and all factors are increased in the same proportion to boost production.
These laws are essential for understanding cost structures and optimal production
scales in economics and business. They also explain why firms and industries
might either benefit or suffer from growth in size.
Unit of Unit of % increase in Total % increase in Stages
Labour capital labour and capital production TP
1 3 – 10 – increasing
2 6 100% 30 200%
3 9 50% 60 100%
Reasons
It describes a condition in which all of the factors of production are increased at the
same time, resulting in a steady growth in output. For example, if inputs are raised
by 10%, the output is also increased by 10%.
Reasons
As the firm’s production grows, it reaches a point where all of the economy’s
resources have been fully utilised, and output equals input.
When all of the production factors are increased simultaneously, output grows at a
slower rate. For example, if inputs are raised by 10%, the output will be increased
by 5%.
Reasons
The following are the returns to scale assumptions: Capital and labour are the only
two variables of production used by the company. In a fixed proportion, labour and
capital are integrated. Factor prices do not fluctuate, and the State of technology
remains the same
Indifference curves are a key concept in microeconomics that represent the
different combinations of two goods or services that give a consumer the same
level of satisfaction or utility. Essentially, they show the trade-offs a consumer is
willing to make between two goods while maintaining the same level of overall
happiness.
The slope of an indifference curve at any given point is known as the Marginal
Rate of Substitution (MRS), which represents how much of one good the
consumer is willing to give up in exchange for one more unit of the other good,
without changing the level of satisfaction.
MRS = ΔY / ΔX, where Y is the quantity of one good and X is the quantity
of the other good.
As you move down the curve, MRS typically decreases, reflecting
diminishing marginal utility—the more of one good you have, the less you're
willing to give up of the other good to get even more of it.
Examples:
Perfect Substitutes: If two goods are perfect substitutes (e.g., two brands of
identical bottled water), the indifference curve would be a straight line with
a constant slope because the consumer is always willing to trade one good
for the other at a fixed rate.
Perfect Complements: If two goods are perfect complements (e.g., left and
right shoes), the indifference curve would be a right-angle shape. The
consumer needs the goods in fixed proportions, and increasing one good
without increasing the other does not improve utility.
Applications:
An isoquant (short for "iso-product curve") represents all the combinations of two
inputs (typically labor and capital) that result in the same level of output for a firm.
In other words, it shows different ways a firm can combine inputs to produce a
fixed quantity of output.
Shape: Isoquants are typically downward sloping and convex to the origin.
This reflects the principle of diminishing marginal returns to input
substitution: as more of one input is used (holding the other input constant),
the additional output produced by each additional unit of the input decreases.
Substitution between Inputs: The rate at which one input can be
substituted for another while maintaining the same output level is called the
marginal rate of technical substitution (MRTS).
Example: An isoquant might show combinations of labor (L) and capital
(K) that result in producing 100 units of output, like (L=5, K=3) or (L=3,
K=6), etc.
Characteristics of isoquants:
2. ISO-COST LINE
An iso-cost line represents all the combinations of two inputs (typically labor and
capital) that can be purchased for a given total cost. This line shows the different
combinations of inputs a firm can afford given its budget or cost constraint.
The iso-cost line is derived from the firm's total cost and the prices of the two
inputs:
C=wL+rKC = wL + rKC=wL+rK
where:
The point at which an isoquant is tangent to an iso-cost line represents the optimal
combination of inputs (labor and capital) that minimizes cost for a given level of
output. At this point, the firm is said to be cost-efficient, as it is using its resources
in the most economical way.
This tangency condition can be expressed in terms of the marginal rate of technical
substitution (MRTS) and the ratio of input prices:
MRTS=wrMRTS = \frac{w}{r}MRTS=rw
where:
MRTS is the rate at which the firm can substitute labor for capital while
maintaining the same output.
wr\frac{w}{r}rw is the rate at which labor can be traded for capital in the
market based on their prices.
MRTS=wr\text{MRTS} = \frac{w}{r}MRTS=rw
This ensures that the firm is minimizing its costs while producing a given level of
output.
Summary:
Economies of scale refer to the cost advantages that a business obtains due to the
expansion of its production. As the scale of production increases, the average cost
per unit of output typically decreases. This happens because fixed costs are spread
over a larger number of goods or services, and operational efficiencies can be
achieved as production volume rises.
These are cost reductions that occur within the company as it grows larger. Key
factors include:
Technical Economies: Larger firms can invest in more advanced and
efficient machinery or technology, which lowers production costs.
Managerial Economies: As a company grows, it can afford to hire
specialists, leading to more efficient management and operations.
Financial Economies: Bigger companies often have easier access to capital
and can secure financing at lower interest rates due to their reduced risk.
Marketing Economies: Larger firms can spread advertising and promotion
costs over a greater volume of sales, reducing the per-unit cost of marketing
efforts.
Purchasing Economies: Companies that buy raw materials in bulk can
often negotiate lower prices from suppliers due to their larger order volumes.
These arise from factors outside the firm, typically as the industry or market grows.
For example:
3. Diseconomies of Scale
While economies of scale reduce per-unit costs with expansion, there are also
diseconomies of scale, which occur when a company becomes too large and
inefficiencies begin to arise. These can include:
Economies of scale allow companies to reduce their costs as they expand, making
them more competitive in the market. However, companies need to carefully
balance growth, as excessive expansion could lead to diseconomies of scale, where
the cost per unit starts to rise due to inefficiencies.
1. Fixed Costs
These are costs that do not change with the level of output or production. They
remain constant regardless of how much or little a company produces.
2. Variable Costs
These costs vary directly with the level of production or business activity. The
more you produce, the higher the cost.
The sum of all the costs incurred in the production process, including both fixed
and variable costs.
The additional cost incurred from producing one more unit of output. This is
important for decision-making as it helps determine pricing and production levels.
The total cost per unit of output. It is calculated by dividing total cost by the
number of units produced.
Costs that have both fixed and variable components. A part of the cost is fixed, and
the rest varies with production levels.
Examples: A phone bill with a fixed monthly charge plus usage-based fees.
7. Opportunity Cost
The cost of forgoing the next best alternative when making a decision. It represents
the benefits that could have been obtained from choosing the next best alternative.
8. Explicit Costs
Direct, out-of-pocket expenses that are paid in cash, such as wages, rent, and
materials. These are actual costs that are easy to measure.
9. Implicit Costs
Indirect costs that represent the opportunity costs of using resources that the
company already owns or controls, rather than renting or selling them. These costs
do not involve direct cash payments.
Examples: The income the business owner could have earned if they
worked elsewhere, or the rent they could have earned by leasing property
owned by the business.
10. Sunk Costs
Costs that have already been incurred and cannot be recovered. These should not
affect future decisions because they cannot be changed, but they are often
emotionally difficult to ignore.
Costs that are directly attributable to the production of goods or services. These are
incurred as a result of manufacturing a product or providing a service.
Costs that are not directly linked to the production of goods or services but are
necessary for the business to operate. These include administrative, marketing, and
maintenance costs.
The point at which total revenue equals total cost, resulting in neither profit nor
loss. It’s the minimum sales level required to cover all fixed and variable costs.
Formula: Break-
even point (units)=Fixed CostsSelling Price per Unit−Variable Cost per Unit
\text{Break-even point (units)} = \frac{\text{Fixed Costs}}{\text{Selling
Price per Unit} - \text{Variable Cost per Unit}}Break-
even point (units)=Selling Price per Unit−Variable Cost per UnitFixed Costs
Costs that can be eliminated if a particular decision is made. These are usually
variable costs or some portion of fixed costs that can be avoided.
Costs that should not be incurred because they exceed the potential benefits of the
activity.
Cost curves are graphical representations of the costs incurred by a firm as they
produce goods or services. They are essential tools in microeconomics and help
analyze a firm's production efficiency, profitability, and pricing strategies. Below
are the primary types of cost curves:
Total Fixed Cost (TFC): Represents costs that do not change with output,
such as rent or salaries of permanent staff. The curve is a horizontal line.
Total Variable Cost (TVC): Varies with output level, such as costs of raw
materials. This curve usually starts at the origin and increases as output rises.
Total Cost (TC): Sum of TFC and TVC (TC=TFC+TVCTC = TFC +
TVCTC=TFC+TVC). It starts at the level of TFC and increases with TVC.
Marginal cost represents the additional cost of producing one more unit of
output (MC=ΔTC/ΔQMC = \Delta TC / \Delta QMC=ΔTC/ΔQ).
The MC curve typically has a U-shape because of initial efficiency gains
followed by diminishing marginal returns.
The cost-output relationship describes how production costs change with output
levels. This relationship is analyzed differently in the short run and the long run
due to differences in the flexibility of inputs.
In the short run, at least one factor of production (typically capital) is fixed. This
creates a distinction between fixed costs and variable costs. The relationship
between cost and output is influenced by the law of diminishing returns:
Fixed costs remain constant regardless of output level (e.g., rent, salaries of
permanent staff).
Average Fixed Cost (AFC) decreases as output increases, spreading the
fixed cost over more units.
Variable costs change with output levels (e.g., raw materials, energy).
Initially, variable costs increase at a decreasing rate (due to increasing
returns to the variable factor), but beyond a certain point, they rise at an
increasing rate (due to diminishing returns).
TC=FC+VCTC = FC + VCTC=FC+VC
The shape of the TC curve reflects the diminishing returns in the short run.
In the long run, all factors of production are variable, and firms can choose the
optimal scale of production. The cost-output relationship is determined by returns
to scale and economies of scale.
1. Economies of Scale:
2. Diseconomies of Scale:
Beyond a certain output level, average costs may rise due to coordination
issues, bureaucracy, and resource constraints, leading to an upward-sloping
LRAC curve.
4. Returns to Scale:
The Long-Run Average Cost (LAC) curve represents the lowest average cost at
which a firm can produce any given level of output when all inputs are variable. It
is a crucial concept in economics and reflects the firm's cost structure when it has
the flexibility to adjust all production factors, such as labor, capital, and
technology.
Graphical Representation:
Imagine the LAC curve as a smooth U-shaped line, with several smaller U-shaped
SAC curves tangent to it from below. Each tangent point represents the most
efficient level of output for that specific scale of operation.
Importance in Decision-Making:
Determining Optimal Plant Size: Helps firms choose the most cost-
efficient level of production.
Long-Term Planning: Guides investment decisions in capacity expansion
or technology adoption.
Market Competition: Firms with lower LACs are better positioned to
compete by offering lower prices.
Meaning
Assumptions of BEA
Determination of BEA
Limitations of BEA
The margin of safety represents the extent to which sales can drop before the
company reaches the break-even point. It is calculated as:
Simple Problem
Problem:
A company has the following information:
Solution:
1. BEP (Units):
2. Margin of Safety:
In this case, the company is operating below its break-even point, indicating a loss.
Module-4
Module-4(09 Hours)
Market Structure Analysis and Pricing Practices: Market Structure
Analysis:
Pricing Practices:
It explains the equilibrium of a firm and is the interaction of the demand faced by
the firm and its supply curve. The equilibrium condition differs under perfect
competition, monopoly, monopolistic competition, and oligopoly. Time element is
of great relevance in the theory of pricing since one of the two determinants of
price, namely supply depends on the time allowed to it for adjustment.
Market Structure
A market is the area where buyers and sellers contact each other and exchange
goods and services. Market structure is said to be the characteristics of the market.
Market structures are basically the number of firms in the market that produce
identical goods and services. Market structure influences the behavior of firms to a
great extent. The market structure affects the supply of different commodities in
the market.
Perfect Competition
Pricing Decisions
In the case of perishable commodity like fish, the supply is limited by the available
quantity on that day. It cannot be stored for the next market period and therefore
the whole of it must be sold away on the same day whatever the price may be.
The first, if price is very high the seller will be prepared to sell the whole stock.
The second level is set by a low price at which the seller would not sell any amount
in the present market period, but will hold back the whole stock for some better
time. The price below which the seller will refuse to sell is called the Reserve
Price.
Monopolistic Competition
There are large number of independent sellers and buyers in the market.
The relative market shares of all sellers are insignificant and more or less
equal. That is, seller-concentration in the market is almost non-existent.
There are neither any legal nor any economic barriers against the entry of
new firms into the market. New firms are free to enter the market and
existing firms are free to leave the market.
In other words, product differentiation is the only characteristic that
distinguishes monopolistic competition from perfect competition.
Monopoly
Monopoly is said to exist when one firm is the sole producer or seller of a product
which has no close substitutes. According to this definition, there must be a single
producer or seller of a product. If there are many producers producing a product,
either perfect competition or monopolistic competition will prevail depending upon
whether the product is homogeneous or differentiated.
On the other hand, when there are few producers, oligopoly is said to exist. A
second condition which is essential for a firm to be called monopolist is that no
close substitutes for the product of that firm should be available.
From above it follows that for the monopoly to exist, following things are essential
One and only one firm produces and sells a particular commodity or a
service.
There are no rivals or direct competitors of the firm.
No other seller can enter the market for whatever reasons legal, technical, or
economic.
Monopolist is a price maker. He tries to take the best of whatever demand
and cost conditions exist without the fear of new firms entering to compete
away his profits.
Since all of the firms sell the identical product, the individual sellers are not
distinctive. Buyers care solely about finding the seller with the lowest price.
In this context of “perfect competition”, all firms sell at an identical price that is
equal to their marginal costs and no individual firm possess any market power. If
any firm were to raise its price slightly above the market-determined price, it
would lose all of its customers and if a firm were to reduce its price slightly below
the market price, it would be swamped with customers who switch from the other
firms.
L =(P − MC) / P
Monopoly: Overview
A monopoly is a market structure where a single firm dominates the entire market
for a particular good or service. It has no direct competition, giving it significant
market power. Monopolies can arise due to factors such as government regulation,
natural barriers to entry, or exclusive control over resources.
Key Features of Monopoly
Monopolists determine price and output levels differently than firms in competitive
markets due to their market power.
1. Profit Maximization:
o The monopolist produces where MC = MR.
o The price is then set based on the demand curve at the profit-
maximizing quantity.
2. Inefficiency:
o Allocative inefficiency: Monopolists often produce less than socially
optimal levels, leading to higher prices (P > MC).
o Productive inefficiency: The monopolist may not produce at the
lowest possible cost.
3. Price Determination:
o The monopolist assesses demand elasticity. If demand is inelastic, the
firm can charge higher prices without significantly reducing sales
volume.
Price Discrimination in Monopoly
Advantages:
Disadvantages:
Oligopoly
In an oligopolistic market there are small number of firms so that sellers are
conscious of their interdependence. The competition is not perfect, yet the rivalry
among firms is high. Given that there are large number of possible reactions of
competitors, the behavior of firms may assume various forms. Thus there are
various models of oligopolistic behavior, each based on different reactions patterns
of rivals.
Oligopoly is a situation in which only a few firms are competing in the market for
a particular commodity. The distinguishing characteristics of oligopoly are such
that neither the theory of monopolistic competition nor the theory of monopoly can
explain the behavior of an oligopolistic firm.
Under oligopoly the number of competing firms being small, each firm
controls an important proportion of the total supply. Consequently, the effect
of a change in the price or output of one firm upon the sales of its rival firms
is noticeable and not insignificant. When any firm takes an action its rivals
will in all probability react to it. The behavior of oligopolistic firms is
interdependent and not independent or atomistic as is the case under perfect
or monopolistic competition.
Under oligopoly new entry is difficult. It is neither free nor barred. Hence
the condition of entry becomes an important factor determining the price or
output decisions of oligopolistic firms and preventing or limiting entry of an
important objective.
For Example − Aircraft manufacturing, in some countries: wireless
communication, media, and banking.
Features of Oligopoly
The kinked demand curve model, developed by Paul Sweezy, explains price
rigidity in oligopolies.
Key Points:
1. Price Above the Kink: If a firm increases its price, competitors will not
follow, leading to a significant loss in market share. This results in a more
elastic demand above the kink.
2. Price Below the Kink: If a firm lowers its price, competitors will follow to
maintain their market share. This results in a less elastic demand below the
kink.
3. Kink at the Current Price: The curve creates a kink at the current price
level, making firms reluctant to change prices as marginal costs may vary
without affecting the equilibrium price.
Diagram:
The demand curve has a kink, with a steeper slope below the kink and a
flatter slope above it.
The marginal revenue (MR) curve has a discontinuity below the kink.
Cartels
Features:
Price leadership is a form of implicit collusion where one firm (the leader) sets
the price, and other firms follow.
1. Dominant Price Leadership: A dominant firm sets the price, and smaller
firms follow.
2. Barometric Price Leadership: A firm perceived as an industry leader
adjusts prices based on market conditions, and others follow.
3. Collusive Price Leadership: Firms agree (implicitly or explicitly) to let one
firm lead.
Advantages:
Disadvantages:
Limits competition.
May lead to inefficiency.
These features, along with strategic interactions like cartels and price leadership,
make oligopoly a complex and dynamic market structure.
Skimming Price
Skimming price is known as short period device for pricing. Here, companies tend
to charge higher price in initial stages. Initial high helps to “Skim the Cream” of
the market as the demand for new product is likely to be less price elastic in the
early stages.
Penetration Price
Penetration price is also referred as stay out price policy since it prevents
competition to a great extent. In penetration pricing lowest price for the new
product is charged. This helps in prompt sales and keeping the competitors away
from the market. It is a long term pricing strategy and should be adopted with great
caution.
Multiple Products
As the name indicates multiple products signifies production of more than one
product. The traditional theory of price determination assumes that a firm produces
a single homogenous product. But firms in reality usually produce more than one
product and then there exists interrelationships between those products. Such
products are joint products or multi–products. In joint products the inputs are
common in the production process and in multi-products the inputs are
independent but have common overhead expenses. Following are the pricing
methods followed −
Explore our latest online courses and learn new skills at your own pace. Enroll
and become a certified expert to boost your career.
Full cost plus pricing is a price-setting method under which you add together the
direct material cost, direct labor cost, selling and administrative cost, and overhead
costs for a product and add to it a markup percentage in order to derive the price of
the product. The pricing formula is −
Pricing formula =
Total production costs − Selling and administration costs − Markup / Number
of units expected to sell
This method is most commonly used in situations where products and services are
provided based on the specific requirements of the customer. Thus, there is
reduced competitive pressure and no standardized product being provided. The
method may also be used to set long-term prices that are sufficiently high to ensure
a profit after all costs have been incurred.
The practice of setting the price of a product to equal the extra cost of producing an
extra unit of output is called marginal pricing in economics. By this policy, a
producer charges for each product unit sold, only the addition to total cost resulting
from materials and direct labor. Businesses often set prices close to marginal cost
during periods of poor sales.
For example, an item has a marginal cost of $2.00 and a normal selling price is
$3.00, the firm selling the item might wish to lower the price to $2.10 if demand
has waned. The business would choose this approach because the incremental
profit of 10 cents from the transaction is better than no sale at all.
Transfer Pricing
Dual Pricing
In simple words, different prices offered for the same product in different markets
is dual pricing. Different prices for same product are basically known as dual
pricing. The objective of dual pricing is to enter different markets or a new market
with one product offering lower prices in foreign county.
There are industry specific laws or norms which are needed to be followed for dual
pricing. Dual pricing strategy does not involve arbitrage. It is quite commonly
followed in developing countries where local citizens are offered the same
products at a lower price for which foreigners are paid more.
Airline Industry could be considered as a prime example of Dual Pricing.
Companies offer lower prices if tickets are booked well in advance. The demand of
this category of customers is elastic and varies inversely with price.
As the time passes the flight fares start increasing to get high prices from the
customers whose demands are inelastic. This is how companies charge different
fare for the same flight tickets. The differentiating factor here is the time of
booking and not nationality.
Price Effect
Price effect is the change in demand in accordance to the change in price, other
things remaining constant. Other things include − Taste and preference of the
consumer, income of the consumer, price of other goods which are assumed to be
constant. Following is the formula for price effect −
Price Effect =
Proportionate change in quantity demanded of X / Proportionate change in
price of X
Price effect is the summation of two effects, substitution effect and income effect
Substitution Effect
In this effect the consumer is compelled to choose a product that is less expensive
so that his satisfaction is maximized, as the normal income of the consumer is
fixed. It can be explained with the below examples −
Consumers will buy less expensive foods such as vegetables over meat.
Consumers could buy less amount of meat to keep expenses in control.
Income Effect
Normal goods − If there is a price fall, demand increases as real income increases
and vice versa.
Inferior goods − In case of inferior goods, demand increases due to an increase in
the real income.
3. Transfer Pricing