Topic2 Portfolio Theory
Topic2 Portfolio Theory
Bo Liu, Ph.D
Huron at Western
Returns
The return of a security is defined as the sum of the price change and any
income received over a period of time, divided by the price of the security
at the start of the time period.
Pt+1 + Xt+1
Rt+1 =
Pt
where Pt is the price and Xt is income received.
Measuring Returns
Rate of Return on Zero-Coupon Bonds:
100
r= −1
Price
APR n
1 + EAR = 1 +
n
APR n
1 + EAR = 1+
n
As n → ∞, use the limit:
APR n
lim 1 + = e APR
n→∞ n
Thus:
1 + EAR = e APR
For Continuous Compounding:
Compounding
Suppose an investment yields a net return of r % each period (e.g. annual)
for n periods (e.g. years). Then, we have
Rt+n = (1 + r )n
Example
The after-tax real rate falls by the tax rate times the inflation rate.
P1 − P0 + D1
HPR =
P0
HPR: Holding Period Return
P0 : Beginning price
P1 : Ending price
D1 : Dividend during period one
E (r ) = 0.0976 or 9.76%
σ = 0.1949
Risk premium: The difference between the expected HPR and the
risk-free rate.
Provides compensation for the risk of an investment.
Risk-free rate: The rate of interest that can be earned with certainty.
Commonly taken to be the rate on short-term T-bills.
The difference between the actual rate of return and the risk-free rate
is called excess return.
Risk aversion: Dictates the degree to which investors are willing to
commit funds to stocks.
Sharpe Ratio
RiskPremium
SharpeRatio =
SD(ExcessReturns)
Excess return: the difference between the actual return of a risky asset
and the actual risk-free rate.
Investor Types
Return of a Portfolio
Portfolio Example
Hence, the total variance takes into account the covariance σ12 between
the two securities.
Variance of a Portfolio
The derivation above is simply an application of the following formula
We can express the relationship of the returns between two assets by their
correlation coefficient
σij
ρij = .
σi σj
Bo Liu, Ph.D Financial Market Jan 20, 2025 32 / 68
Mean-Variance Portfolio Theory : Part I
Thus, the variance of the portfolio falls as N increases unless the average
variance increases.
As long as the variance of individual assets is bounded, for N → ∞, the
variance of the portfolio goes to 0.
N
X N X
X N
σP2 = (Xi2 σi2 ) + Xi Xj σij
i=1 i=1 j̸=i
N N N
1 X σi2 N − 1 X X σij
= +
N N N N(N − 1)
i=1 i=1 j̸=i
or
1 2 N −1
σP2 = σ̄i + σ̄ij
N N
Diversification Effect
Insights:
One might be interested in risk that reflects downside risk or the risk of
extreme losses.
One measure is the semivariance which only measures downward
deviations relative to a benchmark return.
Another such measure is value at risk. The x% VaR number tells us that
we will get a return below that number in x% of the cases.
Example: The 1% VaR is -0.05 means that with probability of 1% we will
get returns below −5%.
However, this measure does not tell us anything how large these losses
could be. The expected shortfall measures the expected losses
conditional on having losses in the VaR region of returns.
normality / fat tails
Question
We look at the case where there are only two securities D and E .
We assume that E [RD ] < E [RE ], σD < σE and a correlation coefficient
ρDE ∈ [0, 1].
Step 1: Investigate how the correlation of securities return matters for
portfolio characteristics.
σP = [wD2 σD
2
+ (1 − wD )2 σE2 + 2wD (1 − wD )σD σE ρDE ]1/2
We have
σP2 = wD2 σD
2
+ wE2 σE2 + 2wD wE σD σE ρDE
For ρDE = 1, the variance simplifies to:
σP = wD σD + (1 − wD )σE
If we have,
σP − σE
wD =
σD − σE
The expected portfolio return is a linear function of the portfolio standard
deviation
Insights
When short sales are not allowed, we can reduce the variance relative
to the original securities whenever ρ is NOT too much positively
correlated.
When short sales are allowed, we can always (weakly) reduce the
variance relative to the original securities.
Given a set of assets, by adjusting the weights, we can determine all
possible combinations of expected return and standard deviation for
the portfolio.
If ρ = +1 or ρ = −1, the expected portfolio return is a linear function
of the portfolio standard.
Otherwise, quadratic function.
We can extend our arguments to other, more complicated portfolios
by realizing that we can treat a portfolio just like a security.
The Opportunity Set of the Debt and Equity Funds and Two
Feasible CALs
E (rp ) − rf
Sp =
σp
Portfolio A:
E (rA ) − rf
SA = = 0.34
σA
Portfolio B:
E (rB ) − rf
SB = = 0.38
σB
Objective: Find the weights wD and wE that maximize the slope of the
CAL (Sharpe ratio):
E (rp ) − rf
Sp =
σp
For a portfolio with two risky assets, the expected return and standard
deviation are:
E (rp ) = wD E (rD ) + wE E (rE )
1/2
σp = wD2 σD2
+ wE2 σE2 + 2wD wE Cov(rD , rE )
E (rp ) − rf
max Sp =
wi σp
wE = 1 − wD
E (rp ) − rf
Sp =
σp
11% − 5%
Sp = = 0.42
14.2%
Optimal Allocation to P:
A=4
E (rp ) − rf
y=
Aσp2
11% − 5%
y= = 0.7439
4 × (14.2%)2
Overall Portfolio:
σp = 14.2%, rf = 5%
E (roverall ) = y × E (rp ) + (1 − y ) × rf
E (roverall ) = 0.7439×11%+0.2561×5% = 9.46%
σoverall = y × σp = 0.7439 × 14.2% = 10.56%
E (roverall ) − rf 9.46% − 5%
Soverall = = = 0.42
σoverall 10.56%
Security Selection:
Determine the risk-return opportunities available
Minimum-variance frontier of risky assets
All portfolios that lie on the minimum-variance frontier from the global
minimum-variance portfolio and upward provide the best risk-return
combinations
Efficient frontier of risky assets is the portion of the frontier that lies
above the global minimum-variance portfolio
Search for the CAL with the highest reward-to-variability ratio
Everyone invests in P, regardless of their degree of risk aversion
More risk-averse investors put less into P
Less risk-averse investors put more in P
Suppose we take the universe of all securities that are available for
investment.
We can derive what is called the efficient frontier.
It is guided by the following considerations.
Risk-averse investors prefer higher returns for the same variance.
Risk-averse investors prefer lower variance for the same return.
Risk-averse investors prefer diversified portfolios since they lower the
variance.
Only portfolios with returns and variance above a global minimum
variance portfolio are relevant.
This implies that the efficient frontier needs to be an increasing, concave
locus in the return-risk space.
Investors can borrow or lend at the risk-free rate RF and invest in a risky
portfolio P to form a portfolio C .
We then have
a portfolio mean return E [RC ] = (1 − y )RF + yE [RP ]
a portfolio standard deviation σC = y σP .
Hence:
σC σC
E [RC ] = 1 − RF + E [RP ]
σP σP
If y ∈ [0, 1], the investor lends (invests) some of its fund at the risk-free
rate.
If y > 1, the investor borrows at the risk-free rate to invest more than his
funds in the risky security.
Define the average variance and average covariance of the securities as:
n
2 1X 2
σ̄ = σi
n
i=1
n
1 XX
Cov = Cov(ri , rj )
n(n − 1)
i=1 j̸=i