Final Book
Final Book
Meaning:
Definition:
OR
OR
Sustained economic growth can provide sufficient incomes for the local
labor force, profitable business opportunities for employers and tax revenues
for maintaining an infrastructure to support this continued growth. There is
no alternative to private sector investment as the engine for economic
growth, but there are many initiatives that you can support to encourage
investments where the community feels they are needed the most
Importance:
1. Job creation
Economic developers provide critical assistance and information
to companies that create jobs in our economy. We help to connect
new-to-market and existing companies with the resources and partners
they need to expand, such as Career Source Central Florida, utilities,
and county and city partners.
2. Industry diversification
A core part of economic development works to diversify the
economy, reducing a region’s vulnerability to a single industry. While
tourism plays an important role in creating jobs in the Orlando region,
economic development efforts help to grow industries outside of
tourism, including Innovative Technologies and Digital Media, Life
Sciences & Healthcare, Aviation, Aerospace & Defense, Advanced
Manufacturing, and Business Services.
4. Economy fortification
Economic development helps to protect the local economy from
economic downturns by attracting and expanding the region’s major
employers.
Economic Growth
Objectives
Developed Countries:
A developed country, industrialized country (or post-industrial
country), more developed country (MDC), or more economically
developed country (MEDC), is a sovereign state that has a developed
economy and advanced technological infrastructure relative to other less
industrialized nations. Most commonly, the criteria for evaluating the degree
of economic development are gross domestic product (GDP), gross national
product (GNP), the per capita income, level of industrialization, amount of
widespread infrastructure and general standard of living. [3] Which criteria are
to be used and which countries can be classified as being developed are
subjects of debate.
1. Has a high income per capita. Developed countries have high per
capita incomes each year. By having a high income per capita, the country’s
economic value will be boosted. Therefore, the amount of poverty can be
overcome.
2. Security Is Guaranteed. The level of security of developed countries is
more secure compared to developing countries. This is also a side effect of
sophisticated technology in developed countries. With sophisticated
technology, security facilities and weapons technology also develop for the
better.
3. Guaranteed Health. In addition to ensuring security, health in a
developed country is also guaranteed. This is characterized by a variety
of adequate health facilities, such as hospitals and medical staff who are
trained and reliable. Therefore, mortality rates in developed countries can be
suppressed and the life expectancy of the population can be high. In
addition, with adequate health facilities, population development in
developed countries can also be controlled.
4. Low unemployment rate. In developed countries, the unemployment
rate is relatively small because every citizen can get a job.
5. Mastering Science and Technology. The inhabitants of developed
countries tend to have mastered science and technology from which new
useful products such as the industrial pendant lights were introduced to the
market. Therefore, in their daily lives, they have also used sophisticated
technology and modern tools to facilitate their daily lives.
6. The level of exports is higher than imports. The level of exports in
developed countries is higher than the level of imports because of the
superior human resources and technology possessed.
• Low level of GNI per capita: The Gross National Product (GNP) per
capita or Gross National Income (GNI) per capita is often considered to be a
good index of the economic welfare of the people in a country. Judging
developing nations by this criterion one finds them in an extremely
miserable position. The GNI per capita in these countries is very low.
According to the estimates of the World Bank, in 2007 there were 43 low
income economies where the GNI per capita was estimated at $350 or even
less. This low level of GNI per capita is sufficient to reflect the plight of
common people in these countries.
Underdeveloped Countries
Characteristics:
Low Level of Income:
Underdeveloped countries are maintaining a very low level of income in
comparison to that of developed countries. The per capita incomes of these
groups of countries are extremely low if we compare it with that of
developed countries. Moreover, inequality in the distribution of income along
with this low level of income worsens the situation in these economies to a
disastrous level.
Mass Poverty:
Existence of chronic mass poverty is another characteristic of
underdeveloped economies. This problem of poverty arises not due to any
temporary economic maladjustment but arises mainly due to existence of
orthodox methods of production and social institutions. The degree of
poverty in these economies gradually increases due to increase in its size of
population, growing inequality in income and increasing price level.
Nearly 76.8 per cent of the world populations are living in those
underdeveloped or developing countries of the world, enjoying only 15.6 per
cent of total world GNP.’ Iii these countries, majority of the population are
living below the poverty line.
Agricultural Backwardness:
The underdeveloped countries are also suffering from agricultural
backwardness. Although being the most important sector, agricultural sector
in these countries remains totally underdeveloped. But what is more peculiar
is that these countries are depending too much on this agricultural sector.
Unemployment Problem:
Excessive population pressure and lack of alternative occupations have
resulted in huge unemployment and underemployment problem in these
underdeveloped countries. In the absence of growth of alternative
occupations both in the secondary and tertiary sector of these countries, this
increasing number of population is being thrown on land to eke out their
living from agricultural sector.
Lack of Industrialization:
Underdeveloped countries are characterized by lack of industrial
development. The pace of industrialisation in these countries is very slow
due to lack of capital formation, paucity in the supply of machinery and tools
and also due to lack of initiative and enterprise on the part of people of these
countries.
Mass Illiteracy:
Underdeveloped countries are mostly characterised by the existence of mass
illiteracy. Due to illiteracy the people in these countries are very much
superstitious and conservative which is again responsible for lack of initiative
and enterprise on the part of people of these countries.
GDP
Definition:
Gross Domestic Product (GDP) is the total market value of all
domestically produced final goods and services for a particular year. Its five
key factors are: market value, final goods and services, produced,
within a country, during a specific time period.
OR
GDP is the final value of the goods and services produced within the
geographic boundaries of a country during a specified period of time,
normally a year. GDP growth rate is an important indicator of the economic
performance of a country.
Only final goods and services count; GDP includes goods and
services purchased by final users. Intermediate goods purchased for
resale or for the production of another good or service are excluded, to
avoid double-counting. Their value is embodied in the value of the
goods purchased by the end user.
GDP is a flow variable; it measures the market value of production that
flows through the economy.
Financial transactions and income transfers (e.g., social security and
welfare payments) are excluded because they represent exchanges,
not productions, of goods and services. GDP counts transactions that
add to current production.
GDP counts only goods and services produced domestically, whether
by citizens or foreigners.
It includes only goods produced during the current period. Thus, sales
of used goods are not counted in GDP. However, sales commissions
count toward GDP because they involve services provided during the
period.
Measurement of GDP
1. Output Method:
This measures the monetary or market value of all the goods and
services produced within the borders of the country. In order to avoid a
distorted measure of GDP due to price level changes, GDP at constant prices
o real GDP is computed.
GDP (as per output method) = Real GDP (GDP at constant prices) –
Taxes + Subsidies.
2. Expenditure Method:
This measures the total expenditure incurred by all entities on goods
and services within the domestic boundaries of a country.
3. Income Method:
It measures the total income earned by the factors of production, that
is, labour and capital within the domestic boundaries of a country.
GDP (as per income method) = GDP at factor cost + Taxes –
Subsidies.
The GDP deflator is a price index that reveals the cost during the
current period of purchasing the items included in GDP relative to the cost
during a base year. Because the base year is assigned a value of 100, as the
GDP deflator takes on values greater than 100, it indicates that prices have
risen. It is a broader price index than the CPI since it is better at giving
an economy-wide measure of inflation. It is designed to measure the change
in the average price of the market basket of goods included in GDP. In
addition to consumer goods, the GDP deflator includes prices for capital
goods and other goods and services purchased by businesses and
governments. The GDP deflator also allows the basket of goods to change as
the composition of GDP changes, while the CPI is computed using a fixed
basket of goods.
We can use the GDP deflator together with nominal GDP to measure
the real GDP (GDP in dollars of constant purchasing power).
Real GDPi = Nominal GDPi x (GDP Deflator for base year/ GDP
Deflator for year i)
Included in GDP:
Final goods and services sold for money. Only sales of final
goods are counted, because the transaction concerning a good used
to make the final good (for example, the purchase of wood used to
build a chair) is already incorporated in the final good total value (price
at which the chair is sold).
Unpaid work: work performed within the family, volunteer work, etc.
Non-monetary compensated work
Goods not produced for sale in the marketplace
Bartered goods and services
Black market
Illegal activities
Transfer payments
Sales of used goods
Intermediate goods and services that are used to produce other final
goods and services
GNP = C + I + G + X + Z
GNP measures final output: While calculating GNP, the market value of
only final goods and services produced in a year are added up. Final goods
are those goods which are purchased for final use in the market.
(iv) Net Exports (X – M): Net exports of goods and services are the value
of exports minus the value of imports.
Formula for Gross Profit:
GNP = C + I + G + (X – M)
Where:
C = Consumption, I = Investment, G = Government Expenditure, X –
M = Net exports
Capital Spending by
Businesses: Spending on
purchases of fixed assets
investment.
and unsold stock by private
businesses
GNP = GDP – NFIA
Net Exports: Represents
the country’s balance of
trade (BOT), where a
positive number bumps up
the GDP as country exports
more than it imports, and
vice versa
GDP = Consumption+
Investment + Government
Spending + Net export.
S = P 1 / P2
Where:
Transport Costs
Tax Differences
Government sales taxes such as the value-added tax (VAT) can spike
prices in one country, relative to another.
Government Intervention
Tariffs can dramatically augment the price of imported goods, where
the same products in other countries will be comparatively cheaper.
Non-Traded Services
The Big Mac's price factors input costs that are not traded. These
factors include such items as insurance, utility costs, and labor costs.
Therefore, those expenses are unlikely to be at parity internationally.
Market Competition
Goods might be deliberately priced higher in a country. In some cases,
higher prices are because a company may have a competitive
advantage over other sellers. The company may have a monopoly or be part
of a cartel of companies that manipulate prices, keeping them artificially
high.
Definition:
The Human Development Index (HDI) is a statistic composite index
of life expectancy, education (Literacy Rate, Gross Enrollment Ratio at
different levels and Net Attendance Ratio), and per capita income indicators,
which are used to rank countries into four tiers of human development.
OR
The Human Development Index (HDI) is a statistical tool used to
measure a country's overall achievement in its social and economic
dimensions. The social and economic dimensions of a country are based on
the health of people, their level of education attainment and their standard
of living.
United Nations Development Programme has defined human
development as a process of enlarging peoples’ choices and their level of
well-being. According to Human Development Report, the three most
important choices of people are: To lead a long and healthy life To acquire
knowledge To enjoy a decent standard of living. Human Development is
measured by constructing Human Development Index (H.D.I).
In order to calculate the index, the following formula has been derived:
Dimension Index = Actual Value – Minimum Value Maximum Value
– Minimum Value
Limitations of H.D.I.
Human Development is measured by constructing Human Development
Index (H.D.I).
1. The Human Development Index (HDI) is a composite statistic of life
expectancy, education, and income indices used to rank
countries.Many factors have been ignored Some critics are of view that
many indicators of human development such as infant mortality,
nutrition, security are totally neglected.
2. Problem of inequality is ignored Since HDI is an overall average, it
reflects the entire economy as a whole. HDI of a country neglects the
problem of inequality. It treats all people and all regions at par.
3. Imperfect index According to Prof. Amartya Sen, a Nobel Laureate, the
HDI is an imperfect index which tries to catch complex reality of
human development in one simple number.
4. Arbitrary use of weights The HDI uses weighted average but it does not
have any fruitful impact on measurement. The use of weights is
arbitrary.
Advantages
1. Aspect of welfare has been considered The three indicator i.e. life
expectancy rate, infant mortality rate and literacy rate very well represent
the welfare of the people of the country. A country wherein all the three
indicators are good can be said to be a developed economy.
2. Helps the government for analysis P.Q.L.I helps to government to
understand the overall welfare in the economy and how well its welfare
policies are being implemented. This helps the government to take
corrective action.
3. Easy to compare The method followed to measure P.Q.L.I is standard for
all the countries. Therefore, it can be used to make comparison between
countries and this helps the relatively underdeveloped countries to take
corrective measure.
4. Also considers distribution The P.Q.L.I considers the distribution of welfare
in the country. A country cannot have a high average of literacy rate, life
expectancy and low infant mortality rate unless a large part of the
population is covered by the benefits of economic development.
5. Data required is easily available The data relating to all the three
indicators is easily available in the census report. Therefore, measurement
of P.Q.L.I is a simple.
Limitations
1. Many other factors have been ignored P.Q.L.I ignores many factors which
influence the quality of life such as employment, housing, justice, social
security as well as human rights.
2. All factors have been given equal importance P.Q.L.I is a simple average of
literacy rate, infant mortality rate and life expectancy rate i.e. all the
factors have been giving equal weightage. However, it is difficult to
understand the rationale behind giving equal importance to all factors.
3. Not a proper measure of economic development P.Q.L.I. does not explain
the structural change in the economy of a country. Moreover, it does not
at all consider economic or monetary concept. Hence, it is a poor measure
of economic development as well as economic growth. Inspite of these
drawbacks, P.Q.L.I. is considered as an improvement over traditional
measure of economic welfare. However, recently developed Human
Development Index (HDI) is a better and more refined version of PQLI.
1. Livings Standards
Since per capita income uses the overall income of a population and
divides it by the total number of people, it doesn't always provide an
accurate representation of the standard of living. In other words, the
data can be skewed, whereby it doesn't account for income inequality.
2. Inflation
Per capita income doesn't reflect inflation in an economy, which is the rate
at which prices rise over time.
3. International Comparisons
5. Children
Per capita includes children in the total population, but children don't earn
any income. Countries with many children would have a skewed result
since they would have more people dividing up the income versus
countries with fewer children.
6. Economic Welfare
The welfare of the people isn't necessarily captured with per capita
income. For example, the quality of work conditions, the number of hours
worked, education level, and health benefits are not included in per capita
income calculations. As a result, the overall welfare of the community may
not be accurately reflected.
It's important to consider that per capita income is only one metric and
should be used in conjunction with other income measurements, such as
the median income, income by regions, and the percentage of residents
living in poverty.
National Income
Introduction:
National income is an uncertain term which is used interchangeably
with national dividend, national output and national expenditure. On this
basis, national income has been defined in a number of ways. In common
parlance, national income means the total value of goods and services
produced annually in a country.
Definitions:
The definitions of national income can be grouped into two classes:
One, the traditional definitions advanced by Marshall, Pigou and Fisher;
and two, modern definitions.
2. National Policies:
National income data form the basis of national policies such as
employment policy, because these figures enable us to know the direction
in which the industrial output, investment and savings, etc. change, and
proper measures can be adopted to bring the economy to the right path.
3. Economic Planning:
In the present age of planning, the national data are of great
importance. For economic planning, it is essential that the data pertaining
to a country’s gross income, output, saving and consumption from
different sources should be available. Without these, planning is not
possible.
4. Economic Models:
The economists propound short-run as well as long-run economic
models or long-run investment models in which the national income data
are very widely used.
5. Research:
The national income data are also made use of by the research
scholars of economics. They make use of the various data of the country’s
input, output, income, saving, consumption, investment, employment,
etc., which are obtained from social accounts.
7. Distribution of Income:
National income statistics enable us to know about the distribution of
income in the country. From the data pertaining to wages, rent, interest
and profits, we learn of the disparities in the incomes of different sections
of the society. Similarly, the regional distribution of income is revealed.
It is only on the basis of these that the government can adopt measures to
remove the inequalities in income distribution and to restore regional
equilibrium. With a view to removing these personal and regional
disequibria, the decisions to levy more taxes and increase public
expenditure also rest on national income statistics.
Inter-Relationship among different concept of National Income
Each goal had specific targets, and dates for achieving those targets.
The 8 goals were measured by 21 targets. To accelerate progress,
the G8 finance ministers agreed in June 2005 to provide enough funds to
the World Bank, the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the African
Development Bank (AfDB) to cancel $40 to $55 billion in debt owed by
members of the heavily indebted poor countries (HIPC) to allow them to
redirect resources to programs for improving health and education and for
alleviating poverty.
Interventions evaluated include (1) improvements required to meet the
millennium development goals (MDG) for water supply (by halving by 2015
the proportion of those without access to safe drinking water), (2) meet the
water MDG plus halving by 2015 the proportion of those without access to
adequate sanitation, (3) increasing access to improved water and sanitation
for everyone, (4) providing disinfection at point-of-use over and above
increasing access to improved water supply and sanitation (5) providing
regulated piped water supply in house and sewage connection with partial
sewerage for everyone (Hutton, G. Evaluation of the Cost and Benefits of
Water and Sanitation Improvements at the Global Level, 2004 WHO-Geneva)
Critics of the MDGs complained of a lack of analysis and justification
behind the chosen objectives, and the difficulty or lack of measurements for
some goals and uneven progress, among others. Although developed
countries' aid for achieving the MDGs rose during the challenge period, more
than half went for debt relief and much of the remainder going
towards natural disaster relief and military aid, rather than further
development.
As of 2013, progress towards the goals was uneven. Some countries
achieved many goals, while others were not on track to realize any. A UN
conference in September 2010 reviewed progress to date and adopted a
global plan to achieve the eight goals by their target date. New
commitments targeted women's and children's health, and new initiatives in
the worldwide battle against poverty, hunger and disease.
Among the non-governmental organizations assisting were the United
Nations Millennium Campaign, the Millennium Promise Alliance, Inc., the
Global Poverty Project, the Micah Challenge, The Youth in Action EU
Programme, "Cartoons in Action" video project and the 8 Visions of Hope
global art project.
Sustainable Development Goals:
Development, however defined and measured, is something that has not been
realized in low-income countries. From its narrow measurement through gross
domestic product (GDP) to human development index (HDI) to a more
comprehensive index of sustainable development, now development can be seen in
low-income countries. Low-income levels have been associated with low
achievements in all aspects of social and environmental progress in these countries.
Even some levels of economic growth in terms of income per capita and social,
political, and environmental indicators of progress are all lacking behind. That is,
economic growth alone is not sufficient to advance societies and improve the
quality of life of citizens.
Meaning of the Term Underdeveloped/ Developing countries
The term ‘underdeveloped’ has been used in a variety of ways.
‘Undeveloped’ and ‘under developed’ countries are often used as synonyms. But
these two terms are easily distinguishable. An underdeveloped country is one which
has no prospects of development. An undeveloped country, on the other hand, is
one which has no potentialities of development. The Antarctic, the Arctic and parts
of the Sahara may be termed as undeveloped, while India, Pakistan, Uganda,
Columbia, Panama, etc. may be called underdeveloped. “Poor” and “backward” are
also used as synonyms for “underdeveloped”. A poor country does not mean a
young country. Poverty simply refers to the low level of per capita income of a
country. It has nothing to do with the country’s culture. ‘Backward countries’ is a
static term like the term ‘underdeveloped’. So the terms ‘poor’ and
‘underdeveloped’ are interchangeable. A more respectable term “developing
countries” has also come to be used in economic literature. However, Bauer regards
the expressions underdeveloped, developing and less developed as clearly
euphemisms. The terms underdeveloped and developing are especially
inappropriate euphemisms: underdeveloped because it so clearly suggests that the
condition it describes is abnormal, reprehensible and also perhaps readily
rectifiable. The term developing because its use leads to such contradictions as
references to the stagnation or retrogression of the developing world. According to
him poor or materially backward are the most appropriate expressions. The World
Bank uses the term developing countries and divides them into low income and
middle income countries. Middle income countries are further divided into lower-
middle-income and upper-middle countries. Of late, a new term Third World is being
used.
Definition:
Underdeveloped is having a low standard of living, or immature and having a low
level of economic productivity and technological sophistication within the
contemporary range of possibility; developing.
1. The first criterion of underdevelopment is the ratio of population to land area. But it
is very difficult to ascertain whether a high or a low ratio of population to area is an
indicator of underdevelopment. There are many underdeveloped countries in Africa
and Latin America where there are “empty spaces” signifying a low ratio. While
there are a number of other underdeveloped countries like India, China, Myanmar,
Pakistan, Malaysia and many other South Asian countries which have a high ratio
of population to area. This criterion is, therefore, vague and superfluous.
3. The third criterion of underdevelopment is the low ratio of capital to per head of
population. Nurkse defines underdeveloped countries as those which “compared
with the advanced countries are underequipped with capital in relation to their
population and natural resources”. But dearth of capital is not a satisfactory
criterion of underdevelopment for the following reasons:
(a) Capital deficiency is not related to absolute size of a country’s stock of
capital but to the ratio of capital to population or to some other factor.
(b) The Principle of Marginal Productivity tells that where the ratio of capital
to other factors is low, the marginal productivity of capital is high. But it is
difficult to infer from this that in underdeveloped countries marginal
productivity of capital is high since capital is scarce, or that a high
marginal productivity of capital suggests a scarcity of capital. It is possible
that poor organisation, low skills, unfavourable weather, etc. may tend to
keep the marginal productivity of capital low in underdeveloped countries,
(c) Moreover, if capital deficiency is taken as an indicator of
underdevelopment, other socio-economic factors are neglected. As Nurkse
himself says, “Economic development has much to do with human
endowments, social attitudes, political conditions and historical accidents.
Capital is a necessary but not a sufficient condition of progress.”
4. Another criterion indicates towards poverty as the main cause of
underdevelopment. Staley defines an underdeveloped country as one
“characterised by mass poverty which is chronic and not the result of some
temporary misfortune and by obsolete methods of production and social
organisation, which means that the poverty is not entirely due to poor natural
resources and hence could presumably be lessened by methods already proved in
other countries”. This definition points towards some of the important
characteristics of underdeveloped countries. That underdeveloped countries have
unexploited natural resources, scarcity of capital goods and equipment, obsolete
techniques of production and defects in socio-economic organisation, none can
deny. But it does not lay emphasis on the basic criterion of underdevelopment,
viz., low per capita income. As Barbara Ward says, “Perhaps the most satisfactory
method of defining poverty is to discuss the question simply in terms of per capita
income—the average income available to citizens in various countries.”
(c) In underdeveloped countries people are mostly illiterate and do not keep
any accounts, and even if they do, they are reluctant to disclose their income
correctly. In such a situation only rough estimates are possible.
(d) National income estimates include only those goods and services which
are commercially used. But in underdeveloped countries people living in rural
areas and manufacturing articles of consumption from rudimentary goods are
able to avoid many expenses. They build their own huts, garments and other
necessities. Thus in underdeveloped countries, relatively fewer goods are
channelised through the market, and therefore are not included in the national
income estimates.
(i) Above all, difficulties arise in the definition of income, in the differences
in concepts used for the computation of national income in various countries
and calculating the contribution to national income of such governmental
activities as irrigation and power projects, police and military services etc.
Despite these limitations, per capita income is the most widely used
indicator of the level of underdevelopment.
Characteristics of an Underdeveloped Country/ Developing
Countries.
General Poverty;
Demographic Features
Economic Backwardness
In underdeveloped countries particular manifestations of economic
backwardness are low labour efficiency, factor immobility, limited specialization in
occupation and in trade, economic ignorance, values and social structure that
minimize the incentives for economic change. The basic cause of backwardness is
to be found in low labour productivity as compared with the developed countries.
This low labour efficiency results from general poverty which is reflected in low
nutritional standards, ill health, illiteracy and lack of training and occupational
mobility, etc.
There is also occupational immobility of labour due to the joint family system
and the caste system. Certain cultural and psychological factors are more dominant
than wage rates in determining the supply of labour. The joint family system makes
people lethargic and stay-at-home. In many underdeveloped countries, certain
occupations are reserved for members of some particular caste, religion, race, tribe
or sex. In Latin America, cloth making falls within the exclusive jurisdiction of
women. In India, a janitor always belongs to a particular caste. According to
Stephen. Enke, “underdeveloped countries have what might be termed an
uneconomic culture. Primarily, this means that traditional attitudes discourage the
full utilization of human resources. More specifically, it means that men are less
likely to strive for extra- consumption.” In underdeveloped countries people are
mostly illiterate, ignorant, conservative, superstitious and fatalists. Poverty in such
countries is abysmal, but it is considered to be God-given, something preordained.
It is -never attributed to personal lack of thrift and industry.
There is extensive prevalence of child labour and women’s status and
position in society is inferior to men. Dignity of labour is conspicuously absent.
Government jobs, even of a clerical nature, have more prestige than manual work.
People are ranked not according to their capacity to do a particular job but by age,
sex, caste, clan and kinship. They are governed by customs and traditions.
Individualistic spirit is absent. Exchange by barter is widespread and money
economy is hardly understood. “The value system minimizes the importance of
economic incentives, material rewards, independence and rational calculation. It
inhibits the development and acceptance of new ideas and objectives and fails to
compare the costs and advantages of alternative methods to achieve objectives. In
short, the cultural value system within many poor countries is not favourable to
economic achievement and the people remain economically backward.”
Technological Backwardness
But what are the main reasons for the lack of incentives to save and
invest in underdeveloped countries? These include, imperfect
maintenance of law and order, political instability, unsettled monetary
conditions, lack of continuity in economic life, the extended family
system with its drain on resources, and its stifling of personal initiative
and certain systems of land tenure.” The other reasons which inhibit
investment are:
Firstly, sheer habit. It is always easier to attempt the familiar than the
unfamiliar. By nature man is happy in his old moorings and would not like
to take risks in new ventures.
Secondly, small extent of the domestic market. The capacity of the
domestic market to absorb new supplies of commodities is limited due
to the low purchasing power of the masses.
Thirdly, the difficulties of securing funds for investment purposes are
also insurmountable. Many manufacturing activities require large capital-
outlays which are difficult to obtain due to lack of a well- developed
capital and stock market, and credit and banking system.
Fourthly, the lack of skilled labour and factor mobility enhance the
cost of production and thereby hamper potential investors.
Fifthly, absence or inadequacy of basic services like transportation,
power and water-supply, etc., further reduce the inducement to invest.
Lastly, the entrepreneurial ability in itself is a scarce factor in most of
the underdeveloped countries. Whatever little entrepreneurship is
available, that is scared away by high risks involved in investment. The
traders and merchants are mostly engaged in the export industry which
consists of primary products. Thus, there is no addition to the real stock
of capital in these countries.
In between the low income and high income groups, there is a small
middle income group. It is mostly engaged in well-established and less
risky ventures, such as providing marketing and other services. This
group, though not lacking in entrepreneurial ability, is reluctant to invest
in manufacturing industries for the reasons which are not far to seek.
There is the difficulty of obtaining institutional and corporate finance,
advanced technology, trained labour and management. Above all, the
difficulties enumerated in the preceding para go together to inhibit the
growth of capital in such countries.
Socio-cultural Constraints
Agricultural Constraint
Smith’s theory has the great merit of pointing out how economic growth came
about and what factors and policies impede it. In particular, he pointed out the
importance of parsimony in saving and capital accumulation; of improved
technology, division of labour and expansion of market in production; and of the
process of balanced growth in the interdependence of farmers, traders and
producers. Despite these merits, it has certain weaknesses.
6. Static Model. According to Hicks, Smith’s model, though it looks like a growth
model, is not a growth model in the modern sense. It does not exhibit a
sequence. Thus it is a static model.
Conclusion.
Introduction
The Theory
The primitive communal stage was the first stage in the evolution
of society. During this stage, man succeeded in advancing from the use
of sticks and stones to making new implements like bows and arrows,
boats, etc. Man also learnt how to make fire.
People lived in groups and in clans based on consanguineous ties.
They lived in common dwellings, and worked on common lands with
common tools. The products they produced were shared equally. But
whatever they obtained was hardly enough for subsistence. Thus the
relations of production were based on the common ownership of the
means of production. The productive forces developed slowly but
steadily. The primitive society developed and improved its work from
gathering natural products like fruits, berries, etc., to cultivation of
crops, and from hunting wild animals to raising livestock. The
development of new tools and implements increased the skills and
productivity of labour. The use of metal tools, the wooden plough with a
metal plough-share, the metal axe, etc. made labour more productive.
Later on, this led to the development of different crafts and
occupations for making tools, implements, weapons, clothing, etc.
within the community.
The barter system began to develop when people started
exchanging products and paying for work in the form of products.
With the social division of labour, the clan began to break into
families. This led to the institution of private property whereby the family
became the owner of the means of production. But the head of the former
clan was the real head of families who owned the means of production.
In this process of social evolution, some producers began to produce
more products than required for the subsistence of the families. This led
to the appropriation of the surplus produced by them and to the
exploitation of others. This paved the way for emergence of the slave
society.
The state grew on the strength of the feudal lords who often had
their own armies and helped the monarchy to expand its frontiers. The
state, in turn, tried to preserve and consolidate feudal private property
and the relations of production.
Productive forces continued to develop under the feudal society.
There was much progress in agriculture. Varieties of grains, vegetables
and fruits were cultivated. Fertilisers and rotation of crops were
introduced. The output of animal products was increased by animal
husbandry. Draught animals were employed on a wider scale for farming,
transportation, etc. Crafts were further developed with inventions of new
machines, tools and implements, especially in textile production. People
learnt harnessing water and wind power by making water mills and wind
mills. They discovered the art of paper making and book printing.
As the productive forces continued to develop, small handicraft
workshops gave place to manufacturing units under one roof with a large
number of workers. This led to large division of labour and specialisation
which raised labour productivity. The manufacturing process was further
encouraged by the discovery of new countries like America, India, etc.
which spread the demand for manufactured products to them.
Feudalism gave rise to two types of class struggle: one, between
the serfs and the feudal lords, and two, between the proletariat and the
urban bourgeoisie. This led to revolutions which replaced the feudal
relations of production with the capitalist relations.
The stages of growth theories of Marx and Rostow have both similarities
and differences which are discussed as under:
Similarities
Differences
The following are the differences between the Marxian and the
Rostowian theories:
1. Marx’s theory of stages of growth is based on the economic interpretation
of history. Marx provides the actual process of the stages of growth of the
society right from the origin of mankind to the present. For this, he develops the
theory of Historical Materialism based on the changes in the mode of
production and consequent changes in the relation of production. But Rostow
does not provide any specific theory of the stages of economic growth. He
explains only some characteristics which move an economy from one stage to
another.
NURKSE’S THEORY
12. Fall in Production. Schultz does not agree with Nurkse that the removal of
surplus labour force from the farms to the new capital projects will not reduce
agricultural productivity. He contends that there is “no evidence for any poor
country anywhere that would suggest that a transfer of even some small
fraction, say, 5 per cent of the existing labour force out of agriculture, with other
things equal, could be made without reducing its production.”As Doreen
Warriner has pointed out, the emphasis on overpopulation or disguised
unemployment is most unfortunate because it concentrates on pure guesswork
and diverts attention away from the ascertainable facts—the fall in output per
head resulting from pressure of population on the means of subsistence and
the destruction of soil fertility.
13. Defective Empirical Evidence. Empirical evidence has shown that the
estimates of 20-25 per cent of surplus labour are entirely inadequate and
defective. Kao, Anschel and Eicher have shown that the empirical studies
supporting such optimistic estimates of disguised unemployment were often
poorly conceived. In addition, “by considering temporary rather than
permanent labour transfers and by allowing some reorganisation of production,
various writers have arrived at a high percentage of disguised unemployment.
To date, there is little reliable empirical evidence to support the existence of
more than 5 per cent disguised unemployment in underdeveloped countries.”
Conclusion. The inference can be drawn from the entire discussion that
the existence of disguised unemployment as a concealed saving
potential and hence as a source of capital formation in overpopulated
underdeveloped countries is beset with a number of difficulties and has
little practicability in countries that have wedded themselves to a
democratic way of living. We may thus conclude with Viner that “there is
little or nothing in all the phenomena designated as ‘disguised
unemployment,’ as ‘hidden unemployment,’ or as ‘underemployment’
which in so far as they constitute genuine social problems would not be
adequately taken into account by competent, informed, and
comprehensive analysis of the phenomenon of low productivity of
employed labour, its causes, its true extent, and its possible remedies.”
A REALISTIC VIEW
The views expressed above are by those who are sceptical about
the concept. But it cannot be denied that the use of surplus labour as the
source of capital formation “brings within a narrow time-horizon projects
which were outside this horizon. It gives scale economies, enlarges land,
capital and employment and raises productivities all round.” So far as
the problem of wage payment is concerned Prof. Khusro suggests three
methods:
(i) Underemployed workers can be organized on their own and on their
neighbours’ farms on mutual aid on capital building. They need not be given
a wage. They eat the same food at their own kitchens. As a result, there are
no inflationary pressures on food prices.
(ii) Underemployed workers can be organized to work on capital construction
within a village outside their own farms. They are given a wage. But they
return to their kitchens daily to eat the same food which they would have
eaten any way. They spend their wages on non-food items whose prices
rise. But with a time-lag, they would produce the capital which would
produce the extra food which will pay for the ‘wage-goods.’
(iii) Underemployed workers can be organized to work on capital projects
away from their villages and paid a wage. They would spend their wages
on food and this will lead to inflationary pressures. “But eventually it
produces the capital which produces the food which pays for the wage.
The problem in all the three cases is (a) of organization, and (b) of bridging
the gap between work (wage payment) and product. If these programmes
are undertaken on a nationwide basis, monetary-fiscal measures become
necessary.” According to Khusro, the essence of the matter is organization
in the field and taking up of projects with due regard to efficiency.
(c) the high cost of living and some humanitarian consideration may
move the employers to raise the real wage, or government may
encourage trade unions and support their wage-bargaining efforts.
The supply of labour is, however, considered to be perfectly elastic
at the existing capitalist wage.
1. Wage Rate Not Constant in the Capitalist Sector. The theory assumes a
constant wage rate in the capitalist sector until the supply of labour is
exhausted from, the subsistence sector. This is unrealistic because the wage
rate continues to rise over time in the industrial sector of an under developed
economy even when there is open unemployment in its rural sector.
5. Multiplier Process does not operate in LDC. Again, the theory assumes
that capital accumulation takes place when the capitalist class continues to
reinvest profits. It, therefore, presupposes the operation of the “investment
multiplier” which is not applicable to underdeveloped countries. For if profits
are reduced somehow or the prices of wage goods rise, the process of capital
formation will stop before all the surplus labour is absorbed.
6. One sided Theory. This is a one-sided theory because Lewis does not
consider the possibility of progress in the agricultural sector. As the industrial
sector develops with the transfer of surplus labour, the demand for food and
raw materials will rise which will, in turn, lead to the growth of the agricultural
sector.
7. Neglects Total Demand. Lewis does not study the problem of aggregate
demand. He assumes that whatever is produced in the capitalist sector is either
consumed by itself or is exported. He does not even analyse the possibility of
the capitalist sector selling its products to the subsistence sector. In case, it so
happens, the growth process may come to a halt much earlier through
unfavourable terms of trade or the subsistence sector adopting new techniques
of production to meet the expanding raw material demand of the capitalist
sector.
8. Mobility of Labour not so Easy. Higher capitalist wage will not lead to the
movement of surplus labour from the subsistence sector to the capitalist
sector. People are so intensely attached to their family and land that they do
not like to leave their kith and kin. Moreover, differences in language and
custom, the problems of congestion, housing and high cost of living in the
capitalist sector stand in the way of mobility of labour to this sector. This is the
main weakness of the theory.
9. Marginal Productivity of Labour not Zero. Schultz does not agree that the
marginal productivity of labour in overpopulated underdeveloped countries is
zero or negligible. If it were so, the subsistence wage would also be zero. The
fact is that every worker receives the subsistence wage, may be in kind, if not
in cash. It is, therefore, difficult to find out the exact number of surplus
labourers who are to move to the capitalist sector, their number hardly
exceeding 5 per cent, as is now generally accepted.
11. Low Income Groups also Save. It is not correct to say that only 10 per
cent of the people with the largest income save. In fact, people, with low
incomes also save due to social reasons and even small farmers save for
capital accumulation in underdeveloped countries, whereas high income groups
save less because they spend more under the influence of the demonstration
effect.
12. Inflation, not Self-Destructive. Lewis’s view that inflation for the
purpose of capital formation is self-destructive is difficult to believe in the face
of acute shortage of consumer goods. Production of consumer goods fails to
increase rapidly due to structural rigidities. On the other hand, the marginal
propensity to consume of the people is near unity, so that all increases in
income lead to inflationary rise in prices.
13. Inefficient Tax Administration. Lewis’s contention that taxation will mop
up increasing income cannot be accepted because the tax administration in
underdeveloped countries is not so efficient and developed as to collect taxes
sufficient enough for capital accumulation.
Conclusion. Despite these limitations, the Lewis theory has the merit of
explaining in a very clear cut way the process of development. This two
sector theory has great analytical value. It explains how low capital
formation takes place in underdeveloped countries which have plethora
of labour and scarcity of capital. His study of the problems of credit
inflation, population growth, technological progress, and international
trade gives the theory a touch of realism.
ROSENSTEIN-RODAN’S THESIS
2. INDIVISIBILITY OF DEMAND
A CRITICAL APPRAISAL
7. Not an Historical Fact. Last but not the least, Rodan’s thesis is a
sort of prescription for launching underdeveloped countries on the path
to progress rapidly in the present. It is not an historical explanation of
how development takes place. Historically, the presence or absence of a
big push has not been a distinguishing feature of growth anywhere,
according to Professor Hagen.
CHAPTER 4
DETERMINANTS OF ECONOMIC
DEVELOPMENT
Introduction
The Economics of Development refers to the problems of the economic
development of underdeveloped countries. Though the study of economic
development has attracted the attention of economists right from Adam
Smith down to Marx and Keynes, yet they were mainly interested in the
problems which were essentially static in nature and largely related to a
Western European framework of social and cultural institutions. It is,
however, in the forties of the 20th century and especially after the Second
World War that economists started devoting their attention towards
analyzing the problems of underdeveloped countries and formulating
theories and models of development and growth. Their interest in the
economics of development has been further stimulated by the wave of
political resurgence that swept the Asian and African nations as they threw
off the colonial yoke after the Second World War. The desire on the part of
new leaders in these countries to promote rapid economic development
coupled with the realisation on the part of the developed nations that
‘poverty anywhere is a threat to prosperity everywhere,’ has aroused further
interest in the subject.
The process of economic growth is determined by two types of factors,
economic and non-economic. Economic growth is dependent upon its
natural resources, human resources, capital, enterprise, technology, etc.
These are economic factors. But economic growth is not possible so long
as social institutions, political conditions and moral values in a nation do
not encourage development. These are non-economic factors. We study
these economic and non-economic determinants of economic growth
separately.
Economic Factors
Economists regard factors of production as the main economic forces that
determine growth. The growth rate of the economy rises or falls as a
consequence of changes in them. Some of the economic factors are
discussed below:
Technological Progress
Technological changes are regarded as the most important factor in
the process of economic growth. They are related to changes in the
methods of production which are the result of some new techniques of
research or innovation. Changes in technology lead to increase in the
productivity of labour, capital and other factors of production.
Kuznets traces five distinct patterns in the growth of technology in
modern economic growth. They are: a scientific discovery or an addition
to technical knowledge; an invention; an innovation; an improvement;
and the spread of invention usually accompanied by improvements. Like
Schumpeter, he regards innovation as the most important technological
factor in economic growth. In modern economic growth the five factors,
mentioned by Kuznets, have helped in the development of technology.
Kuznets points out that LDCs must import modern technology to accelerate
their productive capacity in the short run because they cannot wait until
they themselves invent or modify the technology of advanced countries.
But as they adopt imported technology, they must develop their
indigenous technical skills.
It is a misnomer that all modern technology is capital-intensive. Advanced
countries have also low-cost capital-saving, labour-intensive
productivity-raising technology which can be transferred to developing
countries.
LDCs should, therefore, benefit from the vast fund of technical knowledge
of the advanced countries. However, scientific and industrial technology
to be useful in an LDC needs careful processing and adaptation in
accordance with its social, economic and technical absorption capacities
and requirements. Above all, imported technology requires strong
backing of R and D studies of problems arising in assimilation,
adaptation and improvement in keeping with the factor endowments of
the country. One of the principal causes in modern economic growth has
been the spending of high percentages of their national income on R and
D by the advanced countries.
Structural Change
Structural changes imply the transition from a traditional agricultural society
to a modern industrial economy involving a radical transformation of existing
institutions, social attitudes, and motivations. Such structural changes lead
to increasing employment opportunities, higher labour productivity and the
stock of capital, exploitation of new resources and improvement in
technology.
An LDC is characterized by a large primary sector and a very small
secondary sector along with an equally small tertiary sector. Structural
changes may begin with the transfer of population from the primary to
secondary and then to tertiary employment. In an overpopulated
agriculture-oriented economy, 70-80 per cent of the population is engaged
in the agricultural sector. Structural changes involve the expansion of the
non-agricultural sector so that the proportion of population in the
agricultural sector is progressively reduced. It implies reduction in the size
of contribution to net national output by the agricultural sector. But a
decline in the share of the agricultural sector in the net national product
does not mean a fall in the output of agriculture. Rather agricultural
output must increase in absolute terms. In order to increase agricultural
output, radical changes will have to be made in the form of land reforms,
improved agricultural techniques and inputs, better marketing
organisation, new credit institutions etc.
When agricultural production increases, it increases money incomes in
the agricultural sector. This, in turn, expands rural demand for consumer
goods and agricultural inputs which act as stimulants to the expansion of
the industrial sector. The industrial sector itself affects the agricultural
sector.
First, the expansion of farm output requires improved farm machinery
and other inputs manufactured by the industrial sector.
Second, increasing agricultural productivity and income expands the
demand for consumer goods and services available in the industrial
sector. “The scope for increasing agricultural productivity and income, in
other words, is heavily dependent upon the structural transformation of
the economy as it affects the growth of commercial demand for goods
produced, the growth of alternative employment opportunities, and the
increased quantity of purchased inputs available to the agricultural
sector.”
Another important aspect of structural changes is the transfer of
population from primary and secondary to tertiary employment. Tertiary
production includes a number of dissimilar services producing non-
material goods like transport, retail and wholesale distribution, education,
government and domestic services, etc. With economic development the
demand for tertiary products increases very rapidly because the
expansion of the agricultural and industrial sectors is dependent largely
on the existence of transport, retail and wholesale distribution, technical
personnel, etc. So the proportion of working labour in tertiary
occupations rises with economic development. But many of the tertiary
occupations like railways, motor transport, etc., are of high capital
intensity and involve substitution of capital for labour on a large scale.
Thus, in the initial phase of economic growth, tertiary occupations fail to
absorb large number of people, and the majority of workers become
“pedlars of all kinds of goods and services requiring little or no capital
outfit, such as vendors of fruit, newspapers, or else car washers, porters,
waiters and shop assistants.” This type of underemployment is reinforced
by disguised unemployment in the rural sector.
An innovation or the opening of a new area may bring about a structural
change within the economy thereby, widening the domestic market and
creating a foreign market. Technical invention takes place in such
societies where traditionalism gives way to desire for experimentation.
“Apart from the build-up of economic overhead capital, such as a
communications and transport system and investment in harbour
facilities, some warehouses and similar installation favouring especially
foreign trade, most of the innovations introduced during the preparatory
period are based upon changes in the institutional arrangements in the
legal, educational, familial, or motivational orders. Once these new
institutions have been created, they operate as ‘gifts from the past,’
contributing freely to the vigorous spurt of economic activity in the period
of take-off. What is perhaps most important about the structural changes
taking place during the take-off period is the adaptation of previously
existing institutions for new ends, especially for capital formation.”
Non-Economic Factors
Social Factors
Social attitudes, values and institutions also influence economic, growth.
The term “attitude” means the totality of beliefs and values that cause
human behaviour to be what it is. The term “values” refers to motivations
of human behaviour towards particular ends.
Modern economic growth has been influenced by social and psychological
factors. Western culture and education led to reasoning and scepticism. It
inculcated the spirit of adventure which led to new discoveries and
inventions and consequently to the rise of the new mercantile classes.
These forces brought about changes in social attitudes, expectations, and
values. People cultivated the habits of saving and investment, and
undertook risks to earn profits. They developed what Lewis calls, “The
will to economise,” to maximise output for a given input. As a result, the
European countries experienced the Industrial Revolution in the 18th and
19th centuries. Economic and religious freedom brought about further
changes in social attitudes and values. Single family unit took the place of
joint family system which further helped in modern economic growth.
In LDCs there are such social attitudes, values and institutions which are
not conducive to economic development. Religion gives less inducements
to the virtues of thrift and hardwork. People are fatalists and therefore
are not hard working. They are influenced more by traditional customs
and place high values on leisure, contentment and participation in
festivals and ceremonies. Thus social attitudes stand in the way of
development when money is wasted on non-economic ventures.
Moreover, the joint family is the primary social and economic unit. It
prevents people from taking independent economic decisions, breeds
lethargy, and encourages growth in numbers. In such societies relations
are personal or patriarchal. People are influenced by caste, clan or creed
at the social level.
These social attitudes, values and institutions should be changed or
modified for economic development to take place. Social organizations
like the joint family, caste system, kinship, and religious dogmas should be
modified so that they may be more favourable to development. But it is
not an easy task. Any social change will bring discontentment and
resistance in its wake. It may, therefore, adversely affect the national
economy. Therefore, all socio-cultural changes should be selective. They
should be introduced by stages. Persuasion and not coercion should be
the method. Education and demonstration can do a lot in this direction.
Popular education leads to popular enlightenment and opens the way to
knowledge. It opens men’s mind to new methods and new techniques of
production. It creates self-discipline, power to think rationally and to
probe into the future. Emphasizing the importance of education in
economic development. Cairncross writes: “No country can count itself
developed, in which education in the way of industrial civilization has not
taken place. Peasants have to be brought within the monetary economy
and not left to pursue subsistence farming; workers have to become used
to working fixed hours in factories for wage payments; towns have to
grow, and so banks and business enterprises; the fruits of science have to
be applied throughout the economy. Above all, there must emerge as a
continuing element in the life of the country, a group of business,
administrative and political leaders who can be depended upon to
maintain the momentum of development by constant innovation.”
Certain races have higher tendencies to develop than others, such as
Punjabis and Parsees in India, and Negroes in America and Brazil. For
development, it is essential that races should not be kept aloof from each
other. Rather, they should be intermixed so that there is a union of cultural
values and racial qualities. But such measures require a lot of patience.
The society’s structure is transformed by such racial changes.
The UN Report on Economic Development of Underdeveloped Countries,
laying emphasis on changes in social attitudes, values and institutions
observes that without painful adjustments rapid economic development is
impossible. Old ideas will have to be dispensed with; old institutions will
have to be dispensed with; the bonds of caste, religion and race will
have to be broken. But the process of change should be evolutionary
rather than revolutionary. Otherwise, radical changes in social attitudes
and values will bring about dissatisfaction, discontentment and violence
in their wake and retard the path to economic development.
Myrdal in his Asian Drama advocates the adoption of “modernisation
values” or “modernisation ideals” for the rapid economic development of
LDCs. Modernisation means “the social, cultural and psychological
framework which facilitates the application of tested knowledge to all
phases and branches of production.” The modernisation ideals include,
first, rationality in thought and action through a deliberate cultivation of
scientific attitude and application of modern technology in order to
increase productivity, raise levels of living, and bring about social and
economic equalisation. As pointed out by Jawaharlal Nehru, “The test of a
country’s advance is how far it is utilising modern techniques. Modern -
technique is not a matter of just getting a tool and use it. Modern
technique follows modern thinking.”
But the desire to better their lot and the initiative to make material
progress must arise among the nationals of the country. Development
must be willed by the country itself; it cannot be implanted from outside.
External forces should stimulate and facilitate the national forces. They
should supplement and not supplant them. Foreign aid can only initiate or
stimulate development; it cannot maintain it. Development will falter in
the absence of sufficient internal motivation. Unless the momentum of
development comes from within the economy, the initial initiative to
development will be dissipated and shortlived. As Cairncross puts it,
“Development is impossible if it does not take place in the minds of
men.” It is, therefore, imperative that if the process of economic growth is
to be cumulative and long lasting, the forces of development must be
firmly rooted within the domestic economy.
Modernisation ideals also require changes in institutions and attitudes ‘in
order to increase labour efficiency and diligence, effective competition,
mobility and enterprise; permit greater equality of opportunities, make
possible higher productivity and well-being and generally promote
development’. The barriers of caste, colour, religion, ethnic origin,
culture, language, and provincial loyalties should be broken down, and
property and education should not be so unequally distributed as to
represent social monopolies. All this is possible through changes in social
institutions and attitudes of the people by spreading education and
knowledge. People should be aware of the objectives before them and
the ‘will’ to attain them. But where the social set-up is influenced by rigid
caste and joint family systems, there is little individual freedom and
professional mobility. As a result, people have little incentive to work
more, earn more and save more, and have a backward sloping curve of
effort and risk taking. For development, therefore, such social institutions
and attitudes should be changed which stand in the way of free society
and free competition. For instance, Myrdal views the various land reforms
in India as attempts to breakup the caste system so as to eradicate social
monopolies and barriers to free competition.
Modernisation of ideals with regard to attitudes are called by Myrdal as
the creation of the “new man” or the “modern man”, the “citizen of the
new state”, the “man in the era of science”, the “industrial man”. This
implies change in attitudes so that people have efficiency, diligence,
orderliness, punctuality, frugality, scrupulous honesty, rationality in
decision on action, preparedness for change, alertness to opportunities
as they arise in the changing world, energetic enterprise, integrity and
self-reliance co- operativeness, and willingness to take the long view.
Changes in attitudes towards modernisation lead to development of the
agricultural, industrial and tertiary sectors of the economy. But the
development of these sectors is not possible without entrepreneurship.
According to Myrdal, LDCs lack entrepreneurship not because they are
deficient in capital or raw materials but because they are deficient in
persons with right attitude for entrepreneurship. E. Hagen in his On the
Theory of Social Change (1962) ascribes the lack of entrepreneurship to
the childhood environment in the traditional society which creates
tensions, anxieties, and rage among adults. They suffer from “respect
withdrawal” and develop “retreatism” as the dominant personality trait.
According to Hagen, it is over a very long period of several generations
that there develops a class of entrepreneurs with “need achievement”
motivation. Such psychological attitude emerges when a generation of
fathers demand achievement or do not stand in the way of achievement,
and mothers play a supporting role in encouraging activity on the part of
infants.
McClelland in The Achieving Society (1961) propounds the view that the
growth of entrepreneurship depends on the need for achievement
motivation. According to him, n-Ach (n-achievement) is a relatively stable
personality characteristic rooted in experiences in middle of childhood.
Variations in n-Ach levels were correlated with the stories in children’s
textbooks, and it was found that n-Ach was very high in the United States
of America 80 or 90 years ago. It is the highest in Russia and China now.
It is rising in such developing countries as Mexico and Nigeria. He
attributes high n-Ach in these countries to ideological reform hypothesis,
to Protestantism in Europe and America, to zealous Communist ideology
in Russia and China, and to the spirit 0f nationalism in the developing
countries.
McClelland alongwith David Winter conducted experiments in Kakinada
town of Andhra Pradesh in India and revealed that neither money, nor
caste, nor traditional beliefs played an important part in the n-Ach factor
in the emergence of entrepreneurship there. It was found that those who
were trained in the Small Industries Extension Training Institute at
Hyderabad in 1964-65 for a two-week motivation programme displayed a
more active entrepreneurial behaviour later on. Thus, attitudes,
motivations and environment should all combine to promote
entrepreneurship for economic development.
Human Factor
Human resources have been an important factor in modern-economic
growth. Economic growth does not depend on the mere size of human
resources but on their efficiency. According to Kuznets, the population of
Europe increased by 433 per cent between 1750-1950 while the
population of the remaining world increased by 200 per cent over the
period. Whereas population increased five-fold in European and now
developed countries, there was ten-fold increase in their GNP per capita.
Such a phenomenal increase in their GNP per capita is attributed to the
development of the human factor which is reflected in the increased
efficiency or productivity: of their labour force. This is called human
capital formation. This “is the process of increasing knowledge, the skills,
and the capacities of all people of the country.” It includes expenditure on
health, education and generally on social services. Denison’s estimates
reveal that expenditure incurred on education in the United States
between 1929-57 contributed 23 per cent to its gross national output.
According to Soloman Fabricant, the increase in the total national
product of the United States through increase in physical capital between
1889-1957 equaled the increase through higher labour productivity.
But rapidly increasing population is a great hindrance to the economic
development of LDCs. With their low per capita incomes and low rates of
capital formation, it becomes difficult for them to support the increase in
population. And when output increases due to improved technology and
capital formation, it is swallowed up by increase in numbers. As a
result, there is no improvement in the real growth rate of the
economy.
A proper use of human resources can be made for economic
development in the following ways:
First, there should be control over population. Human resources can be
utilized best if the size of population is controlled and reduced. This
requires family planning and research on population control so as to
bring down the birth-rate.
Second, there should be change in the outlook of the labour force. The
social behaviour of the labour force is important in the process of
economic development. To increase labour productivity and the
mobility of labour, there should be change in the outlook of the people
so that they should imbibe the importance of dignity of labour. This
requires changes in institutional and social factors. Such changes
depend upon the spread of education. It is the educated and trained
labour force with high productive efficiency that leads to rapid
economic development. Thus “the most important requirement of
rapid industrial growth is people. People ready to welcome the
challenge of economic change and the opportunities in it. People,
above all, who are dedicated to the economic development of their
country, and to high standards of honesty, competency, knowledge
and performance.”
Political and Administrative Factors
Political and administrative factors also helped in modern economic
growth. The economic growth of Britain, Germany, the United States,
Japan and France has been due to their political stability and strong
administration since the 19th century. With the exception of the United
States, they were directly involved in the two World Wars and were
devastated. Still they have continued to progress on the strength of their
political and administrative traditions. On the other hand, Italy has not
been able to grow up to their level due to political instability and corrupt
and weak administration. Peace, protection and stability have
encouraged the development of entrepreneurship in developed countries,
alongwith the adoption of appropriate fiscal and monetary policies by the
governments from time to time.
The weak administrative and political structure is a big hindrance to the
economic development of LDCs. A strong, efficient and incorrupt
administration is, therefore, essential for economic development. Prof.
Lewis rightly observed: “The behaviour of government plays an
important role in stimulating or discouraging economic activity.” Peace,
stability and legal protection encourages entrepreneurship. The greater
the freedom, the more the entrepreneurship will prosper. Technical
progress, factor mobility and large size of market help stimulate
enterprise and initiative. But the former can only take place under clean
administration and stable political conditions. Similarly, a good
government can help in capital formation by adopting the right monetary
and fiscal policies, and by providing timely overhead capital fatilities.
Thus “a government must offer society the services if it desires to
stimulate economic development: order, justice, police and defence;
rewards commensurate with ability and application in productivity,
security in the enjoyment of property which may be of extremely varied
character; testamentary rights; the assurance that business covenants
and contracts will be kept; the provision of standards of weights and
measures and currency and the stability of governmental system itself, to
maintain the sense of order and future calculability of expectations and
duties.” In this way, clean and strong administration, full of justice,
stimulates economic development. As rightly pointed out by Lewis, “No
country has made progress without positive stimulus from intelligent
governments.”
All LDCs have emerged as independent nations from the colonial rule. But
independence has not necessarily led to national consolidation. Myrdal
regards national consolidation as “a pre-condition both for the
preservation of the states as a growing concern and for its efficient
functioning as a matrix for the effective formation and execution of
national policies, that is for planning.” By national consolidation he means
“a national system of government, courts and administration that is
effective, cohesive, and internally united in purpose and action, with
unchallenged authority over all regions and groups within the boundaries
of the state.” National consolidation, in turn, requires “emotional
integration” which coincides with the modernisation ideals of changes in
values, attitudes and institutions.
Additional Sources
Factors Determining Economic Development
Regarding the determinants of economic growth Prof. Ragner Nurkse
observed that, “Economic development has much to do with human
endowments, social attitude, political condition and historical accidents.”
Again, Prof. PT. Bauer also mentioned that “The main determinants of
economic development are aptitude, abilities, qualities, capacities and
facilities.”
Thus economic development of a country depends on both economic and
non-economic factors. The following are some of the economic and non-
economic factors determining the pace of economic development
A. Economic Factors:
Economic environment is working as an important determinant of economic
development of a country. Economic environment can determine the pace of
economic development as well as the rate of growth of the economy. This
economic environment is influenced by the economic factors like—
population and manpower resources, natural resources and its utilization,
capital formation and accumulation, capital output ratio, occupational
structure, external resources, extent of the market, investing pattern,
technological advancement, development planning, infrastructural facilities,
suitable industrial relations etc.
4. Capital-Output Ratio:
Capital-output ratio is also considered as an important determinant of
economic development in n country. By capital-output ratio we mean
number of units of capital required to produce per unit of output. It also
refers to productivity of capital of different sectors at a definite point of time.
But the capital output ratio in a country is also determined by stage of
economic development reached and the judicial mix of investment pattern.
Moreover, capital-output ratio along with national savings ratio can
determine the rate of growth of national income.
6. Occupational Structure:
Another determinant of economic development is the occupational structure
of the working population of the country. Too much dependence on
agricultural sector is not an encouraging situation for economic
development. Increasing pressure of working population on agriculture and
other primary occupations must be shifted gradually to the secondary and
tertiary or services sector through gradual development of these sectors.
The rate of economic development and the level of per capita income
increase as more and more work force shift from primary sector to secondary
and tertiary sector. As A.G.B. Fisher writes, “We may say that in every
progressive economy there has been a steady shift of employment and
investment from the essential ‘Primary activities’ … to secondary activities of
all kinds and to a still greater extent into tertiary production.”
Thus to attain a high rate of economic development, inter-sectoral transfer of
work force is very much necessary. The extent and pace of inter-sectoral
transfer of work force-depend very much on the rate of increase in
productivity in the primary sector in relation to other sectors.
8. Technological Advancement:
Technological advancement is considered as an important determinant of
economic environment. By technological advancement we mean improved
technical know-how and its broad-based applications.
It includes:
(a) Use of technological progress for economic gains,
(b) Application of applied sciences resulting in innovations and inventions
and
(c) Utilisation of innovations on a large scale.
With the advancement of technology, capital goods become more
productive. Accordingly, Prof. Samuelson rightly observed that “High
Invention Nation” normally attain growth at a quicker pace than “High
Investment Nation”.
There may be three forms of technological advancement, i.e.,
(a) Capital saving,
(b) Labour saving or
(c) Neutral.
9. Development Planning:
In recent years, economic planning has been playing an important role in
accelerating the pace of economic development in different countries.
Economic development is considered as an important strategy for building
various social and economic overhead or infra- structural facilities along with
the development of both agricultural, industrial and services sectors in a
balanced manner.
Planning is also essential for mobilization of resources, capital formation and
also to raise the volume of investment required for accelerating the pace of
development. Countries like former U.S.S.R. and even U.S.A. and West
Germany have achieved a rapid development through the adoption of
economic planning.
B. Non-Economic Factors:
Economic factors alone are not sufficient for determining the process of
economic development in a country like India. In order to attain economic
development, proper social and political climate must be provided. In this
connection, United Nations Experts observed, “Economic Progress will not
occur unless the atmosphere is favorable to it. The people of a country must
desire progress and their social, economic, legal and political situations must
be favorable to it.”
Emphasizing the role of non-economic factors Prof. Cairn-cross observed,
“Development is not governed in any country by economic forces alone and
the more backward the country, the more this is true. The key to
development lies in men’s minds, in the institutions in which their thinking
finds expression and in the play of opportunity on ideas and institutions.”
Global poverty is decreasing, but billions of people still do not have the
resources they need to survive and thrive. Economic growth can reduce
poverty, but it can also drive inequality that generates social and
economic problems. And efforts at domestic resource mobilization
through taxation, though critical to funding the SDGs, can negatively
impact the poor. In this work, CGD experts offer suggestions to improve
how changes in development financing can be made to tackle poverty
and inequality.
Meaning and Definition of Inequality, Poverty
Inequality refers to disparities and discrepancies in areas such as income,
wealth, education, health, nutrition, space, politics and social identity.
Economic inequality is the unequal distribution of income and
opportunity between different groups in society. It is a concern in almost
all countries around the world and often people are trapped in poverty
with little chance to climb up the social ladder. But, being born into
poverty does not automatically mean you stay poor. Education, at all
levels, enhancing skills, and training policies can be used alongside social
assistance programs to help people out of poverty and to reduce
inequality. Several countries are also now exploring whether a universal
basic income could be the answer.
Poverty is the state of not having enough material possessions or income for a
person's basic needs. Poverty may include social, economic, and political elements.
There has been much controversy among economists over the issue
whether economic growth increases or decreases income distribution.
Prof. Kuznets is the first economist to study this problem empirically. He
observes that in the early stages of economic growth relative income
inequality increases, stabilises for a time and then declines in the later
stages. This is known as the inverted U-shaped hypothesis of income
distribution.
In his 1955 Study, Kuznets takes the following data relating to three
LDCs–India, Ceylon and Puerto-Rico and two DCs—U.K. and U.S.
Table 1 shows that in LDCs 60% of the poorest received 30% and
less of national income, whereas in DCs they received more than 30% of
national income. So far as the richest 20% in LDCs are concerned, they
received 50% and more of national income. In DCs, they received 45%
and less. Kuznets comes to the conclusion that the size distribution of
income was more unequal in LDCs than in DCs. It was high (1.67 to 2.33)
in LDCs and low (1.25 to 1.29) in DCs.
1. Rurality
In Asia and Africa, around 80% of absolute poverty is found in rural areas,
where most of the poor are engaged in subsistence farming or related
activities. In South America, this number is around 50%. However, in many
developing nations, most investment and relief has been delivered to urban
centres.
Ethnic minorities and indigenous populations are very often more likely
to live in poverty, and lack access to education, medical services and
employment. This is often a result of economic, social and political
discrimination. A factor here is also statistical discrimination, or a
propensity to discriminate because the majority of encounters with a
given ethnicity have been deemed negative overall.
2. Asset ownership
3. Progressive taxation
4. Direct transfers
This has been used in many contexts, but runs the risk of being abused
both by those in need, and those not in need. A good way of getting
around these problems is through workfare programs, which reward the
poor for work that they do at such low wages that only the most
desperate would have enough incentive to take advantage of the
program
Chapter 6
Education and Development
Introduction
At the end of the chapter will be able to answer the following six basic
questions:
growth?
poverty?
unemployment?
ship between the education of women and their desired family size?
professional and technical workers from the less developed to the more
developed nations?
Education and Human Resources
Most economists argue that it is the human resources of a nation, not its
physical capital or its natural resources, that ultimately determine the
character and pace of its economic and social development. The principal
institutional mechanism for developing human skills and knowledge is the
formal educational system. Most Third World nations believe that the rapid
quantitative expansion of educational Opportunities is the key to national
development: The more education, the more rapid the development.
Therefore, all countries have committed themselves to the goal of universal
education in the shortest possible time.
Nevertheless, the challenge is now gathering momentum, and it comes from
many sources. It can be found most clearly in the character and results of
the development process itself. After more than three decades of rapidly
expanding enrolments and hundreds of billions of dollars of educational
expenditure, the plight of the average citizen in many parts of Africa and
Latin America seems little improved. Absolute poverty is chronic and
pervasive. Economic disparities between rich and poor widen with each
passing year. Unemployment and underemployment have reached
staggering proportions, with the "educated" increasingly swelling the ranks
of the urban unemployed
Literacy
The ability to read, write, and comprehend information, is obviously a
fundamental component of human resource development. The percentage of
LDC adults who are illiterate has fallen from 60% in 1960 to 31 % in 1995.
However, as a result of rapid population growth, the actual number of adult
illiterates has risen over this same period by nearly 150 million to an
estimated total of over 872 million in 1996. Illiteracy rate in Saharan Africa is
43%.
The answer is that there now exists ample empirical evidence that
educational discrimination against women hinders economic development in
addition to reinforcing social inequality.
3.Improved child health and nutrition and more educated mothers lead to
multiplier effects on the quality of a nation's human resources for many
generations to come.
An investment in a child's education involves more than just the direct out-
of
-pocket costs of that education, especially when the child reaches the age at
which he can make a productive contribution to family income. At this point,
for each year the child continues his education, he in effect foregoes the
money income he could expect to earn or the output he could produce for
the family farm. This opportunity cost of education must also be included as
a variable affecting its demand.
This widening gap between social and private costs provides an even greater
stimulus to the demand for higher education than it does for education at
lower levels. Educational demand therefore becomes increasingly
exaggerated at the postsecondary levels. But educational opportunities can
be accommodated to these distorted demands only at full social cost. As
demands are generated progressively through the system, the social cost of
accommodation grows much more rapidly than the places provided. More
and more resources may be misallocated to educational expansion in terms
of social costs, and the potential for creating new jobs will consequently
diminish for lack of public financial resources.
In Figure 1a expected private returns and actual private costs are plotted
against years of completed schooling. As a student completes more and
more years of schooling, her expected private returns grow at a much faster
rate than her private costs, for reasons explained earlier. To maximize the
difference between expected benefits and costs, the optimal strategy for a
student would be to secure as much schooling as possible.
Now consider Figure 1b, where social returns and social costs are plotted
against years of schooling. The social benefits curve rises sharply at first,
reflecting the improved levels of productivity of, say, small farmers and the
self-employed that result from receipt of a basic education and the
attainment of literacy, arithmetic skills, and elementary vocational skills.
Thereafter, the marginal social benefit of additional years of schooling rises
more slowly, and the social returns curve begins to level off. By contrast, the
social cost curve shows a slow rate of growth for early years of schooling and
then a much more rapid growth for higher levels of education. This rapid
increase in the marginal social costs of post primary education is the result
both of the much more expensive capital and recurrent costs of higher
education and, more important, of the fact that much post primary education
in developing countries is heavily subsidized.
With these general observations in mind, let us look at five specific economic
components of the development question-growth, inequality and poverty,
population and fertility, migration, and rural development – to see in what
way they influence or are influenced by most LDC educational systems. Such
an examination will demonstrate the important two-way relationship that
exists between education and development. It should also provide us with an
even broader understanding of the development problems.
For many years, the proposition that educational expansion promoted and in
some cases even determined the rate of overall GNP growth remained
unquestioned. The logic seemed fairly straightforward. Developing nations
were deficient in their supply of semiskilled and skilled manpower. Without
such manpower, which, it was assumed, could be created only through the
formal educational system, development leadership in both the public and
private sectors would be woefully lacking.
Clearly, in the newly independent nations of Africa and Asia, there was an
immediate need to build up the human as well as physical capital
(infrastructure) in order to provide indigenous leadership for the major tasks
of development. Rapid quantitative expansion of enrolments therefore
appeared justified in light of the substantial manpower scarcities of the
1950s and 1960s. And although it is often difficult to document statistically,
it seems clear that the expansion of educational opportunities at all levels
has contributed to aggregate economic growth by (1) creating a more
productive labour force and endowing it with increased knowledge and skills;
(2) providing widespread employment and income-earning opportunities (3)
creating a class of educated leaders to fill vacancies left by departing
expatriates or otherwise vacant positions (4) providing the kind of training
and education that would promote literacy and basic skills while encouraging
"modern" attitudes on the part of diverse segments of the population. Even if
alternative investments in the economy could have generated greater
growth, educated and skilled labour force is a necessary condition of
sustained economic growth.
The basic reason for this perverse effect of formal education on income
distribution is the positive correlation between level of education and level of
lifetime earnings. This correlation holds especially for workers who are able
to complete secondary and university education where income differentials
over workers who have completed only part or all of their primary education
can be on the order of 300% to 800%. And as levels of earned income are
clearly dependent on years of completed schooling, it follows that large
income inequalities will be reinforced if students from the middle and upper
income brackets are represented disproportionately in secondary and
university enrolments. In short, if for financial or other reasons the poor are
effectively denied access to secondary and higher educational
The international brain drain deserves mention not only because of its
effects on the rate and structure of LDC economic growth but also because
of its impact on the style and approach of Third World educational systems.
The brain drain, broadly construed, has not merely reduced the supply of
vital professional people available within developing countries; perhaps even
more serious, it has diverted the attention of the scientists, physicians,
architects, engineers, and academics who remain from important local
problems and goals. These include the development of appropriate
technology; the promotion of low-cost preventive health care; the
construction of low-cost housing, hospitals, schools, other service facilities;
the design and building of functional yet inexpensive labour intensive roads,
bridges, and machinery; the development of relevant university teaching
materials; and the promotion of problem-oriented research on vital domestic
development issues. Such needs are often neglected as, dominated by rich-
country ideas as to what represents true professional excellence, those
highly educated and highly skilled LDC professionals who do not physically
migrate to the developed nations nevertheless migrate intellectually in terms
of the orientation of their activities. This "internal" brain drain is much more
serious than the external one.
Second, if, as many observers have argued, the education of women does
affect their fertility behaviour, primarily through the mechanism of raising
the opportunity cost of their time in child-rearing activities, then it follows
that unless sufficient employment opportunities for women (as well as for
men) can be created, the reliance on educational expansion as a policy
instrument for lowering fertility will be much less effective. However,
reallocating existing educational resources to women's education, in
combination with an aggressive program of rural and urban female
employment creation could go a long way toward achieving the twin goals of
fertility reduction and poverty alleviation.
Finally, as mentioned earlier in the chapter, educating women has been
shown to be a critical ingredient in breaking the vicious cycle of poor child
health, low educational performance, low income, high fertility, and poor
child health.
A. Educational Budgets
B. Subsidies
D. Quotas
CHAPTER 7
GENDER AND DEVELOPMENT
Introduction
Quick Definitions
Culture: The distinctive patterns of ideas, beliefs, and norms which characterise
the way of life and relations of a society or group within a society
Gender Equality and Equity: Gender equality denotes women having the same
opportunities in life as men, including the ability to participate in the public sphere.
Gender equity denotes the equivalence in life outcomes for women and men,
recognising their different needs and interests, and requiring a redistribution of
power and resources.
Gender Mainstreaming: An organisational strategy to bring a gender perspective
to all aspects of an institution’s policy and activities, through building gender
capacity and accountability
Gender Needs: Shared and prioritised needs identified by women that arise from
their common experiences as a gender.
Gender Planning: The technical and political processes and procedures necessary
to implement gender-sensitive policy
Sex and Gender: Sex refers to the biological characteristics that categorise
someone as either female or male; whereas gender refers to the socially
determined ideas and practices of what it is to be female or male
Social Justice: Fairness and equity as a right for all in the outcomes of
development, through processes of social transformation
WID: The WID (or Women in Development) approach calls for greater attention to
women in development policy and practice, and emphasises the need to integrate
them into the development process.
GAD (or Gender and Development) approach focuses on the socially constructed
basis of differences between men and women and emphasises the need to
challenge existing gender roles and relations
The WID (or Women in Development) approach calls for greater attention to
women in development policy and practice, and emphasises the need to integrate
them into the development process.
The WID perspective evolved in the early 1970s from a ‘liberal’ feminist
framework and was particularly influential in North America. It was a reaction to
women being seen as passive beneficiaries of development. It marked an important
corrective, highlighting the fact that women need to be integrated into development
processes as active agents if efficient and effective development is to be achieved.
Women’s significant productive contribution was made visible, although their
reproductive role was downplayed. Women’s subordination was seen in terms of
their exclusion from the market sphere, and limited access to and control over
resources. Programmes informed by a WID approach addressed women’s practical
needs by, for example, creating employment and income-generating opportunities,
improving access to credit and to education. Women’s ‘problem’ was therefore
diagnosed as insufficient participation in a benign development process, through an
oversight on behalf of policymakers.
The GAD (or Gender and Development) approach to development policy and
practice focuses on the socially constructed basis of differences between men and
women and emphasises the need to challenge existing gender roles and relations.
GAD emerged from a frustration with the lack of progress of WID policy, in changing
women’s lives and in influencing the broader development agenda. GAD challenged
the WID focus on women in isolation, seeing women’s ‘real’ problem as the
imbalance of power between women and men. There are different interpretations of
GAD, some of which focus primarily on the gender division of labour and gender
roles focus on gender as a relation of power embedded in institutions (see Gender
Analysis). GAD approaches generally aim to meet both women’s practical gender
needs and more strategic gender needs (see Gender Needs), by challenging
existing divisions of labour or power relations (see Gender Division of Labour;
Gender Relations).
Although WID and GAD perspectives are theoretically distinct, in practice it is less
clear, with a programme possibly involving elements of both. Whilst many
development agencies are now committed to a gender approach, in practice, the
primary institutional perspective remains as WID and associated ‘antipoverty’ and
‘efficiency’ policies. There is often a slippage between GAD policy rhetoric and a
WID reality where ‘gender’ is mistakenly interpreted as ‘women’.
Women’s Empowerment
Whilst empowerment cannot be ‘done to’ women, appropriate external support can
be important to foster and support the process of empowerment. A facilitative
rather than directive role is needed, such as funding women’s organisations that
work locally to address the causes of gender subordination and promoting dialogue
between such organisations and those in positions of power.
Agencies with a mandate for the advancement of women established within and by
governments for integrating gender concerns in development policy and planning
National Machineries for Women (NMWs) - whether offices, desks, or ministries –
were central to the integration strategies of the 1970s (see WID/GAD). They
expanded in numbers in the 1980s and 1990s, now being a feature of most
governments.
NMWs have made many positive achievements, most importantly legitmising the
place of gender issues in development planning (Goetz, 1998).
Some lessons have been learned. National machineries set up during democratic
transitions (e.g. Philippines, Chile, South Africa, Uganda) have been more influential
and effective, at least in part because of a political commitment to greater social
equality and justice. Positive experiences also highlight the importance of broad and
open processes of consultation, for example in the development of national gender
policies.
NMWs have therefore had varying degrees of success, and face many challenges in
their ability to fulfil a catalytic role and build capacity in other ministries as well as
their own. There are many constraints remaining on their effectiveness. These
include: lack of strong and clear mandates; underfunding and overreliance on donor
funding; lack of qualified and technically skilled staff; bureaucratic resistance;
inappropriate location; lack of political autonomy; and often lack of political support
from national political leadership.
The 1990s have seen a shift towards new strategies for NMWs of institutionalising or
‘mainstreaming’ gender through advocacy and policy oversight work across all
sectors, ministries and departments. Strategies include: lobbying for gender in
national development plans; setting up of focal points in other ministries; gender
training at all levels; guidelines and checklists to assist planning and evaluation;
and building strategic alliances with NGOs and other women’s organisations.
Social Justice
Social Justice Fairness and equity as a right for all in the outcomes of development,
through processes of social transformation The idea of ‘social justice’ as the
outcome of struggles against
social inequalities implies change towards a more ‘fair’ society. This requires
strategies to redress past injustices, violation of rights or persistent economic and
social inequalities. Social movements such as the women’s, worker’s, and human
rights movements, have fought against perceived social injustices from a variety of
entry points. Such movements have also challenged the ideologies and prejudices
that legitimate social inequalities, in order to mobilise people for change.
There are varying conceptions of ‘justice’. Common to them all is a formal idea of
justice - the idea that inequalities of distribution must be justified by an impartial
and rational assessment of ‘relevant’ differences between the people involved. One
key theory of justice, based on Rawls’ ideas, translates this into the idea of ‘justice
as fairness’ with its equity overtones and need for redistributive strategies. Other
thinking, derived from welfare economics, focuses on more ‘efficiency’ ideas of
maximising overall utility or welfare, such that no-one can be made better off
without someone else being worse off. In development thinking a ‘capability’
perspective of justice is common, based on the work of Amartya Sen, i.e. the idea
that people should have the capabilities to survive and function and the freedom to
pursue well-being. This requires both aggregative and redistributive considerations.
Mainstream poverty debates have tended to focus on meeting the basic needs of
poor people and maximising their opportunities, rather than seeing poverty as an
issue of social inequality or injustice. More radical perspectives, often adopted by
NGOs, do see poverty as an issue of injustice and focus on organising and building
capacity for the assertion of rights by the marginalised. The idea of poverty as an
issue of rights is growing in influence in the development discourse, however, as for
example in the DFID White Paper.
Strategies towards social justice have often overlooked the specific gender injustice
or discrimination, as well as wider social injustices, faced by women. The women’s
movement has been working to ensure that efforts to address injustice, through
human rights measures, or economic and social policies, are informed by an
understanding of gender inequalities.
Gender analysis
The Gender Roles framework focuses on describing women’s and men’s roles and
their relative access to and control over resources. The analysis aims to anticipate
the impacts of projects on both productive and reproductive roles. It takes the
household, rather than the breadth of institutions, as the unit of analysis and tends
to assume that women are a homogeneous category.
In contrast, the Social Relations approach seeks to expose the gendered power
relations that perpetuate inequities. This analysis moves beyond the household to
include the community, market, and state institutions and so involves collecting
data at all these levels. It uncovers differences between women, divided by other
aspects of social differentiation such as class, race and ethnicity. The aim is to
understand the dynamics of gender relations in different institutional contexts and
thereby to identify women’s bargaining position and formulate strategies to
improve this. It has proved challenging to adopt this approach in operational work.
Other gender analysis frameworks include: the Moser/DPU Framework; the Longwe
Method/Women’s Empowerment Framework; and Levy’s Web of Institutionalisation.
Recently, tools have also been developed to apply gender analysis to the analysis of
markets, of macro-economic and sectoral policies, and of public expenditure and
budgets.
The term ‘gender equity’ is often used interchangeably with ‘gender equality’. Here,
a distinction is drawn between these two concepts, reflecting divergent
understandings of gender differences and of the appropriate strategies to address
these. Gender equality denotes women having the same opportunities in life as
men, including the ability to participate in the public sphere.
However, this focus on what is sometimes called formal equality, does not
necessarily demand or ensure equality of outcomes. It assumes that once the
barriers to participation are removed, there is a level playing field. It also does not
recognise that women’s reality and experience may be different from men’s.
Gender equity denotes the equivalence in life outcomes for women and men,
recognising their different needs and interests, and requiring a redistribution of
power and resources. The goal of gender equity, sometimes called substantive
equality, moves beyond equality of opportunity by requiring transformative change.
It recognises that women and men have different needs, preferences, and interests
and that equality of outcomes may necessitate different treatment of men and
women.
An equity approach implies that all development policies and interventions need to
be scrutinised for their impact on gender relations. It necessitates a rethinking of
policies and programmes to take account of men’s and women’s different realities
and interests. So, for example, it implies rethinking existing legislation on
employment, as well as development programmes, to take account of women’s
reproductive work and their concentration in unprotected, casual work in informal
and home based enterprises.
It is worth examining the content of policies, not just the language, before deciding
whether an equity or an equality approach is being followed. Gender equity goals
are seen as being more political than gender equality goals, and are hence are
generally less accepted in mainstream development agencies.
Gender Mainstreaming
Such a process of mainstreaming has been seen to take one of two forms. The
agenda-setting approach to mainstreaming seeks to transform the development
agenda itself whilst prioritizing gender concerns. The more politically acceptable
integrationist approach brings women’s and gender concerns into all of the existing
policies and programmes, focusing on adapting institutional procedures to achieve
this. In both cases, political as well as technical skills are essential to a
mainstreaming strategy.
Any approach to mainstreaming requires sufficient resources, as well as high-level
commitment and authority. A combined strategy can be particularly powerful. This
involves the synergy of a catalytic central gender unit with a cross-sectoral policy
oversight and monitoring role, combined with a web of gender specialists across the
institution. The building of alliances both within the institution and with outside
constituencies, such as women’s organisations, is crucial for success.
Mainstreaming tools include gender training, introducing incentive structures which
reward efforts on gender, and the development of gender-specific operational tools
such as checklists and guidelines.
Gender Needs
Shared and prioritised needs identified by women that arise from their common
experiences as a gender.
Practical Gender Needs (PGNs) according to Moser (1989) are the immediate needs
identified by women to assist their survival in their socially accepted roles, within
existing power structures. Policies to meet PGNs tend to focus on ensuring that
women and their families have adequate living conditions, such as health care and
food provision, access to safe water and sanitation, but also seek to ensure access
to income-earning opportunities. PGNs do not directly challenge gender inequalities,
even though these needs may be a direct result of women’s subordinate position in
society.
Strategic gender needs (SGNs), are those needs identified by women that require
strategies for challenging male dominance and privilege. These needs may relate to
inequalities in the gender division of labour, in ownership and control of resources,
in participation in decision-making, or to experiences of domestic and other sexual
violence. These needs are often seen as feminist in nature as they seek to change
women’s status and position in society in relation to men. As such, they are more
likely to be resisted than PGNs.
Gender Planning
The social relations approach differs in its focus on power in gender relations (See
Gender Analysis). This approach uses aninstitutional framework for the analysis of
gender inequalities as a tool for gender-aware planning. It recognises that the
means through which needs are met is as important as the planned ends of any
intervention. The planning process is conceived as participatory and constituted by
an analysis and evaluation of causes, effects, means and ends. A seven-point
‘Gender audit for development interventions’ supports this framework. (Kabeer and
Subrahmanian, 1996).
At the project level, a variety of planning tools are used to operationalise gender
policy, including general and sector-specific checklists and guidelines. Logical
Framework Analysis is an example of a planning tool which, if used in a gender-
sensitive manner, can help to ensure accountability, participation of various
stakeholders, and that relevant monitoring and evaluation procedures are
implemented.
Gender Training
Attention has recently focused on the need to evaluate the impact of gender
training. Experience suggests that training is most effective when it is part of a
broader strategy of organisational change.
CHAPTER 8
GENDER ISSUES, TRENDS OF
WOMEN EMPOWERMENT AND
ROLES OF GENDER IN
DEVELOPMENT IN ETHIOPIA
Introduction to Gender Issues
Gender issues include all aspects and concerns related to women’s and men’s lives
and situation in society, to the way they interrelate, their differences in access to
and use of resources, their activities, and how they react to changes, interventions
and policies.
Gender Discrimination
The socially determined ideas and practices which define what roles and activities
are deemed appropriate for women and men Whilst the gender division of labour
tends to be seen as natural and immutable, in fact, these ideas and practices are
socially constructed. This results in context-specific patterns of who does what by
gender and how this is valued. Gender divisions of labour are not necessarily rigidly
defined in terms of men’s and women’s roles, as is sometimes assumed. They are
characterised by co-operation in joint activities, as well as by separation. Often, the
accepted norm regarding gender divisions varies from the actual practice.
However, roles typically designated as female are almost invariably less valued
than those designated as male. Women are generally expected to fulfil the
reproductive role of bearing and raising children, caring for other family members,
and household management tasks, as well as home based production. Men tend to
be more associated with productive roles, particularly paid work, and market
production. In the labour market, although women’s overall participation rates are
rising, they tend to be confined to a relatively narrow range of occupations or
concentrated in lower grades than men, usually earning less.
Historically, women’s productive roles have been ignored or under-valued,
particularly in the informal sector and subsistence agriculture. This has led to
misconceived development projects; for example the services of extension agents
and agricultural inputs being targeted at men. Because women’s labour is
undervalued, it is often assumed by mainstream development policies to be
infinitely elastic. For example, policy makers expect that women can take on roles
previously fulfilled by public services, such as care for the sick and elderly, when
cutbacks are made.
The formal documentation and recognition of women’s roles and the related time
burden is crucial for gender-sensitive development interventions. Recently,
international organisations have begun to measure all forms of economic activity by
gender. International definitions of economic activity have also been broadened to
include subsistence farming, food processing and homeworking ‘in anticipation of
profit’. Time budget surveys are also being implemented in some places to measure
women’s input into reproductive work.
Gender and development policies and programmes can challenge and change
women’s socially prescribed roles, in pursuit of gender equity. For example, women
have been successfully trained and employed as water technicians or builders in
communities where these were jobs previously a male domain. However,
programmes aiming to increase women’s participation in spheres beyond the
household must ensure that they are properly remunerated. They should also be
accompanied by consideration of how men, or public provision, can reduce women’s
responsibilities in the home.
Gender Relations
Hierarchical relations of power between women and men that tend to disadvantage
women These gender hierarchies are often accepted as ‘natural’ but are socially
determined relations, culturally based, and are subject to change over time. They
can be seen in a range of gendered practices, such as the division of labour and
resources, and gendered ideologies, such as ideas of acceptable behaviour for
women and men.
Analyses which focus on gender relations differ in emphasis from those which take
‘gender roles’ as a starting point. They give more prominence to the connectedness
of men’s and women’s lives, and to the imbalances of power embedded in male-
female relations. They also emphasise the interaction of gender relations with other
hierarchical social relations such as class, caste, ethnicity and race. But whether
gender relations act to alleviate, or to exacerbate other social inequalities, depends
on the context.
Gender relations constitute and are constituted by a range of institutions, such as
the family, legal systems or the market. They are a resource which is drawn on daily
to reinforce or redefine the rules, norms and practices which govern social
institutions. Since historically women have been excluded from many institutional
spheres, or their participation circumscribed, they often have less bargaining power
to affect change who institutions operate.
So, for example, where they are perceived to transgress their accepted roles,
women can be physically or sexually abused by male partners with relative
impunity. In many cultures, beatings or rape in marriage are considered acceptable
in the existing legal framework. Even where, following lobbying of women’s groups,
rape or violence within marriage is outlawed, women may be reluctant to seek
redress because the male dominated judicial system is unsympathetic, or because
they fear ostracism. Where women retaliate, they become criminalised themselves.
However, change is possible: in a few recent cases, following sustained campaigns,
women have been acquitted of ‘crimes’ against violent partners and new laws have
been passed to respond to such attenuating circumstances.
Hierarchical gender relations constrain development efforts. For example, rigidities
in the gender division of labour limit the effective mobilisation of women’s labour to
support export production. Poverty reduction efforts are hampered where men use
their authority to usurp control over resources targeted at women. Development
strategies need to be informed by an analysis of gender relations and to support
women’s own attempts to change the rules and practices which reinforce these
gender hierarchies.
Gender Violence
The recognition that women’s rights are human rights and that women experience
injustices solely because of their gender. The UN Universal Declaration of Human
Rights (1948) laid out the idea of the universality of rights, but failed to take into
account women’s needs and interests as women. Its focus was on formal political
and civil rights, hence conceiving rights to be relevant to the ‘public’ rather than the
‘private’ sphere. As such, violations of women’s bodily integrity, which occurred in
the private sphere were not part of the human rights discourse.
The Convention on the Elimination of all forms of Discrimination against Women
(CEDAW) established in 1979 marked an important step towards explicit prohibition
of discrimination against women. During preparations for the World Conference on
Human Rights in Vienna (1993), women’s groups mobilized around the slogan of
“Women’s rights are human rights!” which signifies the indivisibility of women’s
rights from universal human rights. Participants in the UN Beijing Women’s
Conference (1995) continued with this call, attempting to broaden the conception of
rights to include social, economic, and cultural rights, as well as reproductive and
sexual rights put on the agenda at the 1994 Cairo population conference.
Gender-based violence has been a high profile issue in advocacy efforts on women’s
human rights. Groups have campaigned for the recognition as human rights of, for
example, the right of women to freedom from rape, from sexual assault as refugees
and displaced women, from abuse in custody, and particularly domestic violence.
The 1993 Vienna Conference on Human Rights was a watershed as it marked the
first international recognition of violence against women as a human rights
violation. There is now a UN Special Rapporteur on Violence Against Women with
the specific remit to gather facts and report to the UN.
Whilst there has been progress in the recognition of women’s human rights in
international human rights instruments this has not been matched by progress in
the implementation and enforcement of these rights by state bodies. Many
countries have failed to ratify CEDAW, and some that have ratified it have failed to
uphold it. Even when international and national laws recognize women’s human
rights, they may be undermined by patriarchal customary laws or social practices.
Furthermore, human rights advocates, including those promoting women’s rights,
face challenges from those who regard human rights discourse as a western,
imperialist imposition on other cultures.
Mobilisation of women to claim their rights is essential in order to press for reforms,
and for the implementation and enforcement of human rights and national legal
instruments. This requires strategies of capacity-building in terms of literacy, legal
knowledge, and political participation. Gender-awareness training for the judiciary
and the police, in addition to strengthening women’s participation in these fields, is
also crucial.
The dynamics of how different resources that are generated within, or which come
into the household are controlled and accessed by its different members.
Gender analysis has revealed some evidence of bias against female members of
households in the allocation of resources such as income, food, nutrition, health
care and education. These patterns are not universal, however, and are also
mediated by other factors such as age, and birth order. For example, there is little
evidence of nutritional bias against girl children in Sub-Saharan Africa, whereas in
South Asia this pattern has been widely noted. It has also been shown that
resources controlled by women, for example in female-headed households, are
distributed differently to resources controlled by men. There is some evidence that
women spend a higher percentage of their generally smaller incomes on family
consumption and children’s welfare.
Conventional macro-economics treats the activities performed within the household
as non-economic and hence irrelevant. Conventional micro-economists typically
sees the household as a consumption unit and treat it as a ‘black-box’, assuming
genderneutrality. It was the New Household Economics (pioneered by Gary Becker
in the 1960s) that challenged the conventional microeconomic approach and
highlighted the importance of production within the household. In this model, all
resources are pooled and distributed in an altruistic manner by a benevolent male
household head to maximise the welfare of household members. However, gender
analysts, particularly feminist anthropologists and economists, have demonstrated
that this characterisation of the household is naïve and ignores gender power
imbalances and conflict within the household.
Feminist models highlighted the fact that resources are not always pooled and
stressed the role of bargaining processes within the household in determining
access to resources. Gender relations within the household are then seen as
characterised by both conflict and co-operation, whereby women tend to have less
bargaining power in the struggle over household resources (for example, Sen). The
division of labour and dynamics within the household are seen also to influence
opportunities and outcomes for women outside the home, in employment for
example. Certain theorists suggest that women’s bargaining position within the
household is enhanced when they work outside the home. Other mechanisms for
enhancing women’s bargaining power in the home include strengthened property
rights, and membership of collective organisations.
The household has often been used as the basic unit of analysis in, for example,
poverty measures. But because of inequalities in intrahousehold distribution,
household income-based measures of poverty do not correlate neatly with gender-
differentiated assessments of well-being. Consequently, poverty reduction
strategies that target male household heads, erroneously assume that benefits will
‘trickle-down’ to the rest of the household. Where women are targeted with income-
generating opportunities, it cannot either be assumed that women will retain control
of those resources they bring into the household. This suggests the need for
improved data collection and analysis procedures that collect more data at
individual level, incorporate consideration of intrahousehold dynamics and
recognise the heterogeneity of household arrangements.
Patriarchy
Systemic societal structures that institutionalise male physical, social and economic
power over women.
Some feminists use the concept of patriarchy to explain the systematic
subordination of women by both overarching and localised structures. These
structures work to the benefit of men by constraining women’s life choices and
chances. There are many differing interpretations of patriarchy. However, the roots
of patriarchy are often located in women’s reproductive role and sexual violence,
interwoven with processes of capitalist exploitation. The main ‘sites’ of patriarchal
oppression have been identified as housework, paid work, the state, culture,
sexuality, and violence. Behaviours that discriminate against women because of
their gender are seen as patriarchal ‘practices’; for example occupational
segregation, exclusion, and unequal pay.
The concept of patriarchy has been drawn into gender and development theorising;
in order to challenge not only unequal gender relations but also unequal capitalist
relations, sometimes seen as underpinning patriarchy (Mies, 1986; DAWN, 1995).
Feminists who explain gender inequality in terms of patriarchy often reject male-
biased societal structures and practices and propose greater female autonomy or
even separatism as a strategy. In some views, women are seen as having room for
manoeuvre within a constraining patriarchal system by negotiating a ‘patriarchal
bargain’ with men. This entails a trade-off between women’s autonomy, and men’s
responsibility for their wives and children.
An overarching theory of male power may help to conceptualise the extent of
gender inequality but fails to deal with its complexity. It tends to assume that
gender oppression is uniform across time and space. More recent thinking has
therefore rejected such a universal concept, identifying the need for detailed
historical and cultural analysis to understand gender-based oppression. Neither are
women a homogeneous group constrained in identical ways.
Gender inequalities are crosscut by other social inequalities such as class, caste,
ethnicity and race, which could be prioritised over gender concerns in certain
contexts. A rigid and universal concept of patriarchy denies women space for
resistance and strategies for change. A more nuanced analysis is needed that takes
into account difference and complexity, and the agency of women.
Access to Education
Gender often influences whether or not children attend or remain in school. Across
the world, girls are more likely than boys to be out of school, and the poorest
girls/women from the most disadvantaged rural areas tend to have the lowest
educational attainment levels. The reasons why girls are more likely than boys to be
out of school relate to social power structures and socially-constructed norms that
define the roles that boys/men and girls/women should play. These gender roles
affect their rights, responsibilities, opportunities and capabilities, including their
access to and treatment in school. While educational exclusion based on gender
disproportionately affects girls/women, it also affects boys/men.
The ways in which gender relates to educational exclusion are complex, and affect
males and females differently. For example, when poverty forces children out of
school, boys are often sent to work, while girls are kept at home to help with
domestic chores. In some cases, young people’s gendered perceptions of their own
roles and responsibilities may lead them to regard school as unmasculine or
irrelevant. In some cases, the intersectionality between sex and other factors
collectively determine gender norms and expectations and lead to educational
exclusion. For example, poverty and lack of lucrative employment opportunities for
women may cause some families to prioritise boys’ education over girls’. Similarly,
gendered traditional practices – such as rites of passage or female genital
mutilation – may take place during the school term and prevent boys or girls from
going to school. In many countries, rural girls are more affected by the lack of a
nearby school than rural boys or urban students, because of concerns for girls’
safety while travelling to school.
In terms of impacts, research suggests that low educational attainment can lead to
the entrenchmentof unequal power structures as well as discriminatory gender
norms and attitudes at individual or household level, which may then be replicated
and perpetuated at community level through unequal practices within schools and
unequal opportunities in the workplace. Breaking the cycle of gender inequality and
its detrimental impacts requires ending state patriarchy and overturning unequal
power relations at governmental level. Yet women’s subordinate position in society
and low educational levels relative to men’s block their equal representation in key
decision-making fora, which in turn prevents gender- equalising reforms from being
implemented – thus preserving the status quo.
Reproductive Health & Rights
Sexual rights
The human rights of women include their right to have control over and decide
freely and responsibly on matters related to their sexuality, including sexual and
reproductive health, free of coercion discrimination, and violence. (Beijing Platform
for Action, paragraph 96)
The 4th World Conference on Women in Beijing in 1995 further advanced the
agenda by linking SRHR to a broader gender perspective. It established that women
had the right to decide on all matters related to their sexuality, including sexual and
reproductive health, free from coercion, discrimination and violence, and linked
these rights to their ability to participate in democratic processes, economic
activities and development at large.
Sexual and reproductive health and rights include, among others, access to sexual
and reproductive health services, the ability to exercise one’s rights over one’s
body, comprehensive sexuality education, safe motherhood, access to commodities
such as contraceptives, and HIV and AIDS prevention and treatment. The provision
of sexuality education and sexual and reproductive health services to young people
to promote safer sex, reduce unwanted pregnancies and school drop-out rates –
enabling young people to participate in democracy, economic growth and
sustainable development – is also an integral part of SRHR.
Maternal Health
Maternal health is also a matter of human rights and gender equality and not only a
public health issue. Maternal deaths in low income countries are largely due to an
inadequate attention to women’s health issues and to repressive structures that
prevent women and young people from being able to influence their own situation
and development based on personal choices and preferences. These choices
include being able to determine the number of children one would like to have and
the spacing of births. The currently high maternal mortality rate is also due to lack
of access to adequate SRHR services such as comprehensive family planning, safe
and legal abortion, skilled attendance and care in pregnancy and at birth for
mothers and newborns.
Gender-based violence
Also in 1993, the UN General Assembly adopted the Declaration on the Elimination
of Violence Against Women (DEVAW), which is currently the main international
document addressing the problem of gender-based violence. In DEVAW, the UN
offered the first official definition of gender-based violence. In the remaining time
we will explore the definition of gender-based violence found in the DEVAW.
Child Marriage
The concept- FGM – has been coined and used to refer to what is otherwise
commonly known as female circumcision in part to reflect the amount of genital
organs removed and therefore the pain and damage it inflicts on girls and women.
Unlike male circumcision which entails only the removal of the foreskin in the penis,
FGM in almost all cases involves removal of genital organs ranging from
clitoridectomy- the removal of the prepuce or hood of the clitoris; excision- the
removal of the clitoris and all or part of the labia minora; to infibulation which
involves the removal of the clitoris, the labia minora and most of the labia majora.
In the last procedure, the two remaining sides of the vulva are sewn together
leaving only a tiny opening for the passage of urine and menstrual blood (Toubia
1993). Approximately 85% of women who are subjected to FGM undergo
clitoridectomy and excision while 15% are infibulated (Toubia 1993). FGM is
supposed to transform a girl to a woman although the age at which it is done varies
from society to society but ranges from a few weeks to puberty. In societies where
the ritual takes place at puberty, it enacts a symbolic rebirth into adulthood, a
process by which the society passes on knowledge and codes of conduct expected
in adulthood. This is thus an initiation rite. There are however cases, as in the
Chisungu in Zambia where the initiation rite does not involve removal of the genital
organs (Richards 1982).
The consequences of FGM are numerous. As a physical surgery without anaesthesia,
the pain must be excruciating. Moreover, bleeding and infections the latter due to
the use of unsterilised tools are life threatening risks. Many other problems
including, stress, shock and trauma; complications during sexual intercourse
especially in the case of infibulation; complications during pregnancy and childbirth;
urine retention, damage to the urethra and obstruction of menstrual flow arise
(Toubia 1993, WHO 1994, Dorkenoo and Elworthy 1994, Heise, Pitanguy and
Germain 1994). As an irreversible operation, the physical and psychological damage
inflicted on girls and women affect their sexual and reproductive health throughout
life.
In Ethiopia, 80 percent of the population resides in rural areas and women provide
the majority of the agricultural labor in these communities. However, their
contributions often go largely unrecognized and their fathers or husbands often
restrict access to resources and community participation. Worse, one in three
women experience physical, emotional or sexual violence, 65 percent of women
have experienced female genital mutilation, and only half of girls who enroll in
primary schools ever make it to grade 5.
USAID invests in empowering women and girls in Ethiopia across all of our programs
by promoting equal access to education, health, and economic opportunities. In
doing so, we help create opportunities for more equitable participation in society for
females across the country. We also address the root causes of gender-based
violence, child marriage, and female genital mutilation.
Role of