0% found this document useful (0 votes)
4 views

Production Functions

The document discusses production functions, which model the relationship between inputs (capital and labor) and outputs in firms. It explains concepts such as marginal physical product, diminishing marginal productivity, and average productivity, emphasizing how changes in input levels affect output. Additionally, it introduces isoquants and the marginal rate of technical substitution, illustrating how inputs can be substituted while maintaining output levels.

Uploaded by

Dhirain Vij
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
4 views

Production Functions

The document discusses production functions, which model the relationship between inputs (capital and labor) and outputs in firms. It explains concepts such as marginal physical product, diminishing marginal productivity, and average productivity, emphasizing how changes in input levels affect output. Additionally, it introduces isoquants and the marginal rate of technical substitution, illustrating how inputs can be substituted while maintaining output levels.

Uploaded by

Dhirain Vij
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 83

Production Functions

Abhishek Dureja

Teaching Fellow: Shreya Kapoor

Plaksha University
Production Functions
Introduction

▶ Till now we have seen how individuals make consumption and labor
supply decisions
▶ We now turn to how firms make choices and take decisions
▶ The principal activity of any firm is to turn inputs into outputs
▶ Economists are interested in the choices the firm makes in
accomplishing this goal
▶ To avoid discussing many of the engineering intricacies involved
Economists construct an abstract model of production
▶ Economists model the relationship between inputs and outputs
by using a production function
▶ Production functions represent the production technology that
converts inputs into output

2 / 83
Production Functions
Introduction

▶ The production function Economists use can take a general form

q = f (k, l, ....) (1)

where q represents the firm’s output of a particular good during a


period
k represents the machine (i.e., capital) usage during the period
l represents hours of labor input
▶ There remains a possibility of other variables affecting the
production process
▶ The general production function (1) provides any conceivable set
of inputs, the engineer’s solution to the problem of how best
to combine those inputs to get output

3 / 83
Production Functions
Introduction

Production Function
▶ The firm’s production function for a particular good, q,

q = f (k, l) (2)

shows the maximum amount of the good that can be produced


using alternative combinations of capital (k) and labor (l)
▶ This means that as we keep changing the levels of k and l, the
level of output produced will keep changing
▶ Importantly, a change in output brought about by a change in
one of the productive inputs while keeping the other
productive input as fixed
▶ This leads us to the idea of marginal product

(For convenience, we are limiting to capital (k) and labor (l) as the
only two productive inputs in the production function)
4 / 83
Production Functions
Marginal Physical Product

Marginal physical product


▶ The marginal physical product of an input is the additional
output that can be produced by using one more unit of that
input while holding all other inputs constant
▶ Mathematically,

∂q
Marginal physical product of capital = MPk = = fk
∂k

▶ If the amount of capital input increases by 1 unit, keeping


labor input as fixed, what is the increase in the output
∂q
Marginal physical product of labor = MPl = = fl
∂l

▶ If the amount of labor input increases by 1 unit, keeping


capital input as fixed, what is the increase in the output
5 / 83
Production Functions
Marginal Physical Product

▶ Mathematical definitions of marginal product use partial derivatives,

=⇒ All other input usage is held constant while the input of


interest varies
▶ For example, consider a farmer hiring one more laborer to harvest
the crop but holding all other inputs constant
=⇒ The extra output this laborer produces is that laborer’s
marginal physical product
▶ Assume 50 workers on a farm are able to produce 100 Kgs of wheat
per year
→ Whereas 51 workers, with the same land and equipment, can
produce 102 Kgs
=⇒ The marginal physical product of the 51st worker is 2 Kgs per
year

6 / 83
Production Functions
Diminishing Marginal Productivity

▶ Marginal physical product of an input depends on how much


of that input is used

▶ For example, labor cannot be added indefinitely to a given field


(while keeping the amount of equipment, fertilizer, and so forth
fixed)
=⇒ Adding more labor will eventually exhibit some
deterioration in its productivity

▶ This assumption is the assumption of diminishing marginal


physical productivity

▶ Mathematically, it is an assumption about the second-order partial


derivatives of the production function

7 / 83
Production Functions
Diminishing Marginal Productivity

▶ Mathematically, this means

∂MPk ∂2f
= = fkk = f11 < 0
∂k ∂k

=⇒ As we keep adding more capital input, while holding labor


input fixed, the total output keeps increasing but at a
decreasing rate

∂MPl ∂2f
= = fll = f22 < 0
∂l ∂l

=⇒ As we keep adding more labor input, while holding capital


input fixed, the total output keeps increasing but at a
decreasing rate

8 / 83
Production Functions
Diminishing Marginal Productivity

▶ The assumption of diminishing marginal productivity was originally


proposed by the nineteenth-century economist Thomas Malthus
▶ Malthus worried that rapid increases in population would result
in lower labor productivity
▶ His gloomy predictions for the future of humanity led economics to
be called the dismal science
▶ But the mathematics of the production function suggests that such
gloom may be misplaced
▶ Changes in the marginal productivity of labor over time
depend not only on how labor input is growing but also on
changes in other inputs, such as capital
=⇒ We must also be concerned with MPlk

9 / 83
Production Functions
Diminishing Marginal Productivity

▶ In most cases, MPlk = flk > 0

=⇒ Marginal product of labor will increase if capital increases


( =⇒ Marginal product of capital will increase if labor increases)
=⇒ Declining labor productivity as both l and k increase is not a
foregone conclusion

▶ Indeed, labor productivity has risen significantly since Malthus’ time

▶ Because increases in capital inputs (along with technical


improvements) have offset the impact of decreasing marginal
productivity

10 / 83
Production Functions
Average Physical Productivity

▶ Economists are often interested in measuring the productivity of


labor (employees)
▶ How can labor productivity be measured?
▶ Labor productivity usually means average productivity
▶ Average productivity is easily measured (say, x Kgs of wheat per
labor-hour input) and it is often used as a measure of efficiency
▶ Average product of labor (APl ) is

Output q f (k, l)
APl = = =
Labor input l l

▶ Notice that APl also depends on the level of capital used

11 / 83
Production Functions
Example: A Two-Input Production Function

q = f (k, l) = 600k 2 l 2 − k 3 l 3

▶ Assume k = 10

=⇒ q = f (k, l) = 60000l 2 − 1000l 3

▶ Marginal product of labor is given by:

∂q
MPl = = 120000l − 3000l 2
∂l
▶ MPl diminishes as l increases, and eventually becoming negative

=⇒ q reaches a maximum value

12 / 83
Production Functions
Example: A Two-Input Production Function

▶ Finding where the MPl is maximum, set MPl = 0

120000l − 3000l 2 = 0

=⇒ 40l = l 2 =⇒ l = 40

▶ At l = 40, MPl is maximum

13 / 83
Production Functions
Example: A Two-Input Production Function

q
APl = = 60000l − 1000l 2
l

▶ APl is an inverted parabola that reaches its maximum value when

∂APl
= 60000 − 2000l = 0
∂l

=⇒ APl is maximum at l = 30

▶ At l = 30 =⇒ APl = 900000 and MPl = 900000


▶ When APl is at a maximum, average and marginal
productivities of labor are equal

14 / 83
Production Functions
Maximum of APl

q
APl =
l

Taking derivative wrt l (and using division rule, we get)

∂APl lMPl − q
=
∂l l2

∂APl l × MPl − q
For maxima = =0
∂l l2

=⇒ l × MPl = q =⇒ MPl = APl

▶ Therefore, whenever APl is maximum, APl = MPl

15 / 83
Production Functions
Isoquant Maps and the Rate of Technical Substitution

▶ Assume a production function of the form:

f (k, l)

▶ Isoquant: An isoquant shows those combinations of k and l


that can produce a given level of output (say, q0 )
▶ Mathematically, an isoquant records the set of k and l that satisfies

f (k, l) = q0

▶ An isoquant indicates the possible substitution of one input for


another in a production function
▶ An isoquant (from iso, meaning equal) records those combinations
of k and l that are able to produce a given quantity of output

16 / 83
Production Functions
Isoquant Maps and the Rate of Technical Substitution

▶ All those combinations of k and l that fall on the curve labeled


q = 10 are capable of producing 10 units of output per period
▶ We can use either (lA , kA ) or (lB , kB ) to produce 10 units of output

17 / 83
Production Functions
Isoquant Maps and the Rate of Technical Substitution

▶ As was the case for indifference curves, there are infinitely many
isoquants in the k–l plane

▶ Each isoquant represents a different level of output

▶ Isoquants record successively higher levels of output as we move in a


North-Easterly direction

▶ Using more of each of the inputs will permit output to increase

▶ Two other isoquants (for q = 20 and q = 30) are also shown in the
figure

18 / 83
Production Functions
Isoquant Maps and the Rate of Technical Substitution

19 / 83
Production Functions
Isoquant Maps and the Rate of Technical Substitution

▶ Isoquant map is similar to an Indifference map because both


represent contour maps of a particular function

▶ For isoquants, however, the labeling of the curves is measurable —


An output of 10 units per period has a quantifiable meaning
=⇒ Economists are more interested in studying the shape of
production functions than in examining the exact shape of utility
functions

20 / 83
Production Functions
The Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution (RTS)

▶ The slope of an isoquant shows how one input can be traded


for another while holding output constant
▶ Examining the slope provides information about the technical
possibility of substituting labor (l) for capital (k)
Marginal rate of technical substitution
▶ The marginal rate of technical substitution (RTS) shows the
rate at which labor (l) can be substituted for capital (k) while
holding output constant along an isoquant
▶ Mathematically,
dk
RTS (l for k) = − q=q0
dl

▶ The notation indicates that output is to be held constant as l is


substituted for k

21 / 83
Production Functions
The Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution (RTS)

dk
RTS (l for k) = − q=q0
dl

▶ The particular value of this trade-off rate (RTS) will depend on

i The level of output

ii Quantities of capital and labor being used

=⇒ RTS depends on the point on the isoquant map at which


the slope is to be measured

22 / 83
Production Functions
RTS and Marginal Productivities

▶ While we are on an isoquant, the output produced (say, q0 ) remains


the same

▶ We substitute one input for the other

→ If we increase l =⇒ k decreases (so that output remains


constant)

▶ We can say that along an isoquant, the quantity of k depends on


the quantity of l

▶ Mathematically, k is a function of l

=⇒ k can be generally be written as k(l)

23 / 83
Production Functions
RTS and Marginal Productivities

▶ Therefore the production function for a given isoquant can be


written as:
q0 = f (k(l), l)

▶ Taking total derivative

∂f ∂f
dk + dl = 0
∂k ∂l

=⇒ fk dk + fl dl = 0

dk fl
=⇒ − =
dl fk

dk MPl
=⇒ RTS = − q=q0
=
dl MPk
24 / 83
Production Functions
RTS and marginal productivities

MPl
RTS =
MPk

▶ Isoquants are negatively sloped (because if l increases =⇒ k


decreases)

▶ Both MPl and MPk are non-negative (as no firm would choose to
use a costly input that reduces output)
=⇒ The RTS will be positive

25 / 83
Production Functions
Reasons for a diminishing RTS

▶ The isoquants are convex to the origin

▶ Along an isoquant, RTS is diminishing

▶ For high ratios of k to l, the RTS is a large positive number

→ More capital can be given up to increase labor input by one more


unit

▶ However, when a lot of labor is already being used, the RTS is low

▶ =⇒ Only a small amount of capital can be traded for an additional


unit of labor

▶ The convexity of isoquants imposes assumptions on the


marginal products

26 / 83
Production Functions
Reasons for a diminishing RTS

▶ Lets compute dMRTS


dl

dMRTS d( ffkl )
=
dl dl

▶ For a given isoquant, quantities of k and l are interdependent

→ Also fl and fk are functions of both k and l

dMRTS fk (fll + flk dk dk


dl ) − fl (fkl + fkk dl )
=
dl (fk )2

▶ Using the fact that dk


dl = − ffkl and fkl = flk

27 / 83
Production Functions

dMRTS fk (fll + flk dk dk


dl ) − fl (fkl + fkk dl )
=
dl (fk )2

▶ Using the fact that dk


dl = − ffkl and fkl = flk

dRTS f 2 fll − 2fk fl fkl + fl 2 fkk


= k
dl (fk )3

▶ Since fk > 0 =⇒ Denominator is positive


▶ For diminishing RTS, the numerator must be negative
▶ Because fll and fkk are both assumed to be negative, the numerator
will be negative if fkl is positive

28 / 83
Production Functions
Importance of Cross-Productivity Effects

▶ fkl represents the cross-productivity effects

▶ If fkl > 0 =⇒ dRTS


dl <0
→ fkl > 0 =⇒ If workers had more capital, they would have higher
marginal productivities

▶ Alternatively, RTS can still be diminishing if fk2 fll + fl 2 fkk < 2fk fl fkl

▶ While assuming diminishing RTS, we are assuming

i Diminishing marginal productivities for each input (fkk < 0; fll < 0)

ii Marginal productivities diminish rapidly enough to compensate for


any possible negative cross-productivity effects (if we do not want to
impose strong assumption of fkl > 0)

29 / 83
Production Functions
Example: Diminshing RTS

q = f (k, l) = 600k 2 l 2 − k 3 l 3

▶ General marginal productivity functions for this production function


are
∂q
MPl = fl = = 1200k 2 l − 3k 3 l 2
∂l

∂q
MPk = fk = = 1200kl 2 − 3k 2 l 3
∂k

▶ Each of these marginal productivities depend on the values of both


inputs (k and l)
▶ Marginal productivities of k and l will be positive for values of k and
l for which kl < 400

30 / 83
Production Functions
Example: Diminshing RTS

q = f (k, l) = 600k 2 l 2 − k 3 l 3

fll = 1200k 2 − 6k 3 l

fkk = 1200l 2 − 6kl 3

▶ This production function exhibits diminishing marginal productivities


for sufficiently large values of k and l
▶ fkk < 0 and fll < 0 if kl > 200
▶ However, even within the range 200 < kl < 400 where the marginal
productivity relations for this function behave normally, this
production function may not necessarily have a diminishing
RTS
31 / 83
Production Functions
Example: Diminshing RTS

▶ The reason is the cross-marginal productivity


▶ Cross-differentiation of either of the marginal productivity gives the
cross-marginal productivity

fkl = flk = 2400kl − 9k 2 l 2

▶ The cross-marginal productivity is positive only for kl < 266

=⇒ RTS will be declining for 200 < kl < 266


▶ For cases where 266 < kl < 400,

→ The diminishing marginal productivities exhibited by the function


are sufficient to overcome the influence of a negative value for fkl on
the convexity of isoquants

32 / 83
Production Functions
Returns to Scale

▶ Given a production function, Economists want to characterize the


production function

▶ One question which is of interest about the production function is:

→ How output responds to increases in all inputs together

▶ For example, suppose that all inputs were doubled:

→ Would output double? Less than double? More than


double?

▶ This is a question of the returns to scale exhibited by the


production function

33 / 83
Production Functions
Returns to Scale

▶ This question of returns to scale has been of interest to economists


ever since Adam Smith intensively studied the production of
pins
▶ Smith identified two forces that may come into operation when the
conceptual experiment of doubling all inputs was performed
▶ First, a doubling of scale permits a greater division of labor and
specialization of function
=⇒ Efficiency might increase
=⇒ Production might more than double
▶ Second, doubling of inputs may also entail some loss in efficiency

→ Because managerial overseeing may become more difficult


given the larger scale of the firm
▶ Which of these two effect will have a greater effect is an important
empirical question
34 / 83
Production Functions
Returns to Scale

Returns to scale

▶ If the production function is given by

q = f (k, l)

→ If all inputs are multiplied by the same positive constant t (where


t > 1), then we classify the returns to scale of the production as

i Constant Returns to Scale if f (tk, tl) = tf (k, l) = tq

ii Decreasing Returns to Scale if f (tk, tl) < tf (k, l) = tq

iii Increasing Returns to Scale if f (tk, tl) > tf (k, l) = tq

35 / 83
Production Functions
Returns to Scale

▶ If a proportionate increase in inputs increases output by the same


proportion
=⇒ The production function exhibits constant returns to
scale

▶ If output increases less than the proportionate increase in inputs

=⇒ The function exhibits diminishing returns to scale

▶ If output increases more than the proportionate increase in inputs

=⇒ There are increasing returns to scale

36 / 83
Production Functions
Returns to Scale

▶ It is theoretically possible for a function to exhibit constant


returns to scale for some levels of input usage and increasing
or decreasing returns for other levels
▶ Economists examine returns to scale of a production function while
considering only a fairly narrow range of variation in input usage and
the related output level

37 / 83
Production Functions
Constant Returns to Scale

▶ Constant returns to scale is a theoretical construct

▶ Is there an economic rationale for production functions to


exhibit constant returns to scale ?

▶ There are economic reasons why a firm’s production function might


exhibit constant returns to scale

▶ If the firm operates many identical plants

=⇒ It may increase or decrease production simply by varying


the number of plants in operation
=⇒ The firm can double output by doubling the number of
plants it operates
→ This will require employing precisely twice as many inputs

38 / 83
Production Functions
Constant Returns to Scale

▶ Empirical studies of production functions often find that


returns to scale are roughly constant for the firms that were
studied
→ This holds true for outputs close to the firms’ established
operating levels
→ The firms may exhibit increasing returns to scale as they expand
to their established size

▶ Since constant returns to scale is an empirical fact

=⇒ It is worthwhile to examine these production functions more

39 / 83
Production Functions
Constant Returns to Scale

▶ Since constant returns to scale means

f (tk, tl) = t 1 f (k, l) = tq

=⇒ The production function is homogeneous of degree 1


▶ If a function is homogeneous of degree k

=⇒ Its derivatives are homogeneous of degree k − 1


▶ Since a production function is homogeneous of degree 1

=⇒ Its partial derivative with respect to k and l will be


homogeneous of degree 0 (zero)
=⇒ MPl and MPk are homogeneous of degree 0 (zero)

40 / 83
Production Functions
Constant Returns to Scale

▶ MPl and MPk are homogeneous of degree 0 (zero)

∂f (k,l)
▶ Since MPk = ∂k

∂f (tk, tl) ∂f (k, l)


=⇒ = = MPk for any t > 0
∂k ∂k

∂f (k,l)
▶ Similarly, MPl = ∂l

∂f (tk, tl) ∂f (k, l)


=⇒ = = MPl for any t > 0
∂l ∂l

41 / 83
Production Functions
Constant Returns to Scale

▶ Since for any t > 0

∂f (tk, tl) ∂f (k, l)


MPk = =
∂k ∂k

∂f (tk, tl) ∂f (k, l)


MPl = =
∂l ∂l

▶ Let t = 1
l

∂f ( kl , 1)
=⇒ MPk =
∂k

∂f ( kl , 1)
=⇒ MPl =
∂l

42 / 83
Production Functions
Constant Returns to Scale

∂f ( kl , 1)
MPk =
∂k

∂f ( kl , 1)
MPl =
∂l

▶ The marginal productivity of any input depends only on the


ratio of capital to labor input, not on the absolute levels of
these inputs

▶ This helps in explaining differences in productivity among industries


or across countries

43 / 83
Production Functions
Constant Returns to Scale

▶ For instance: Industries with high capital-labor ratio may have


higher productivity of labor
=⇒ Higher income levels
=⇒ Richer (Developed) countries

▶ Indeed developed countries have higher capital-labor ( kl ) ratios

▶ Many growth models also take capital-labor ( kl ) ratio as a key factor


in explaining growth rates
→ As capital-labor ratio is a key indicator of an economy’s
productivity level

44 / 83
Production Functions
Homothetic production functions

▶ Since MPl and MPk depend on the ratio of k


l

▶ Also, RTS = MPl


MPk

=⇒ RTS for any constant returns-to-scale production function


will depend only on the ratio of the inputs, not on their
absolute levels
k
=⇒ RTS depends upon the ratio of l (capital-labor ratio) and the
absolute level of k and l
=⇒ The production function is Homothetic
=⇒ Isoquants will be radial expansions of one another
=⇒ Along any ray through the origin (where the ratio k/l
does not change) the slopes of successively higher isoquants
are identical

45 / 83
Production Functions
Homothetic production functions

▶ Since RTS depends only on the ratio of k


l

=⇒ Isoquants will be radial expansions of one another


=⇒ Along any ray through the origin (where the ratio k/l
does not change) the slopes of successively higher isoquants
are identical

▶ This property of the isoquant map is very useful

▶ The substitution possibilities between k and l depend upon on the


ratio of kl

46 / 83
Production Functions
Homothetic production functions

47 / 83
Production Functions
Homothetic production functions

▶ Assume a bread order of 200 loaves can be completed in one day by


3 bakers working with 3 ovens or by 2 bakers working with 4 ovens
=⇒ RTS of ovens for bakers is one-for-one
=⇒ One extra oven can be substituted for one baker
▶ Assume this production process exhibits constant returns to
scale
=⇒ Two large bread orders of 400 loaves (total) can be completed
in one day, either by 6 bakers with 6 ovens or by 4 bakers with 8
ovens
=⇒ Two ovens are substituted for two bakers, so again the RTS is
one-for-one
▶ In constant returns-to-scale cases

=⇒ Expanding the level of production does not alter


trade-offs among inputs
48 / 83
Production Functions
Homothetic production functions

▶ In constant returns-to-scale cases

=⇒ Expanding the level of production does not alter trade-offs


among inputs

=⇒ If production functions are homothetic, RTS depends only


on the ratio of kl

49 / 83
Production Functions
Homothetic production functions

▶ If a production function is constant returns to scale

=⇒ A monotonic transformation can change the returns to scale of


the production

▶ But the monotonic transformation cannot change the RTS of


the production function

▶ Assume f (k, l) is a constant returns to scale production function

▶ Let us take a monotonic transformation: F (k, l) = [f (k, l)]γ

where γ is any positive exponent

50 / 83
Production Functions
Homothetic production functions

F (k, l) = [f (k, l)]γ

▶ Assuming γ > 1

=⇒ F (tk, tl) = [f (tk, tl)]γ = [tf (k, l)]γ

=⇒ F (tk, tl) = t γ [f (k, l)]γ > t[f (k, l)]γ

for any t > 1


▶ The exponent γ captures the degree of the increasing returns to
scale
▶ A doubling of inputs would lead to a four-fold (eight-fold) increase
in output if γ = 2 (γ = 3)

51 / 83
Production Functions
Homothetic production functions

▶ Therefore for γ > 1

=⇒ Monotonically transformed production function, F (k, l)


displays increasing returns to scale

▶ Similarly, for γ < 1, the monotonically transformed production


function, F (k, l) displays decreasing returns to scale

▶ But the monotonically transformed production function, F (k, l),


continues to be homothetic
=⇒ RTS of monotonically transformed production function,
F (k, l), depends on the kl ratio

52 / 83
Production Functions
The n-input case

▶ The definition of returns to scale can be easily generalized to a


production function with n inputs
▶ If the production function is given by

q = f (x1 , x2 , ...., xn )

and if all inputs are increased t-times, where t > 1, then

f (tx1 , tx2 , ...., txn ) = t k f (x1 , x2 , ...., xn )

i If k > 1 =⇒ The production function displays increasing returns


to scale

ii If k = 1 =⇒ The production function displays constant returns


to scale

iii If k < 1 =⇒ The production function displays decreasing


returns to scale
53 / 83
Production Functions
The n-input case

▶ It is important to note that the requirement is that

→ All inputs be increased by the same proportion: t


▶ In real-world production processes, this provision may make little
economic sense
▶ For example, a firm may have only one manager, and the number of
managers need not necessarily be doubled even if all other inputs
were
▶ Alternatively – if the output of a farm depends on the fertility of the
soil
=⇒ It may not be literally possible to double the cultivated area
while maintaining the same level of fertility
→ Because the new land may not be as good as that already under
cultivation

54 / 83
Production Functions
The n-input case

▶ =⇒ Hence some inputs may have to be fixed (or at least


imperfectly variable) for most practical purposes

▶ In such cases, some degree of diminishing productivity (a result of


increasing employment of variable inputs) seems likely

▶ But this cannot be called diminishing returns to scale because of the


presence of some inputs that are held fixed

55 / 83
Production Functions
Elasticity of Substitution

▶ An important characteristic of the production function is how easy


it is to substitute one input for another

▶ This question relates to the shape of a single isoquant (rather than


the isoquant map)

▶ Along an isoquant

→ The rate of technical substitution decreases


k
→ The capital-labor ratio also decreases (i.e. l ↓)

▶ We now wish to define a parameter that measures this degree


of responsiveness

56 / 83
Production Functions
Elasticity of Substitution

▶ If the RTS does not change at all for changes in k


l

=⇒ Substitution is easy
→ Because the ratio of the marginal productivities of the two
inputs does not change as the input mix changes

▶ Alternatively, if the RTS changes rapidly for small changes in k


l

=⇒ Substitution is difficult
→ Because minor variations in the input mix has a substantial
effect on the inputs’ relative productivities

57 / 83
Production Functions
Elasticity of Substitution

▶ We want a measure to the responsiveness of changes in RTS to


changes in kl ratio

▶ A scale-free measure of this responsiveness is provided by the


elasticity of substitution

▶ The elasticity of substitution (for small changes) is given by

d ln( kl ) d ( kl ) RTS
σ= = × k
d lnRTS d RTS (l )

58 / 83
Production Functions
Elasticity of Substitution

▶ Alternatively, for discrete changes in k and l, the elasticity of


substitution is given by

percent ∆ ( kl ) ∆ ( k ) ∆ RTS
σ= = kl ×
percent ∆ RTS (l ) RTS

∆ ( kl ) RTS
=⇒ σ = × k
∆ RTS (l )

▶ We will use the following to denote the elasticity of substitution

d ( kl ) RTS
σ= × k
d RTS (l )

59 / 83
Production Functions
Elasticity of Substitution

Elasticity of substitution
▶ For the production function

q = f (k, l)

The elasticity of substitution (σ) measures the proportionate change


in kl relative to the proportionate change in the RTS along an
isoquant

percent ∆ ( kl ) d ( kl ) RTS d ln( kl ) d ln( kl )


σ= = × k = =
percent ∆ RTS d RTS (l ) d lnRTS d ln( ffkl )

60 / 83
Production Functions
Elasticity of Substitution

▶ Is the elasticity of substitution positive or negative?

▶ Elasticity of substitution is always positive


k
→ Because along an isoquant l and RTS move in the same
direction
=⇒ The value of σ is always positive

61 / 83
Production Functions
Elasticity of Substitution: Graphical Explanation

62 / 83
Production Functions
Elasticity of Substitution: Graphical Explanation

▶ As we move from point A to point B on the isoquant


k
=⇒ Both the RTS and the ratio l will change

▶ The RTS changes from RTSA to RTSB


k
▶ The l changes from ( kl )A to ( kl )B

▶ We are interested in the relative magnitude of these change

63 / 83
Production Functions
Elasticity of Substitution: Graphical Explanation

▶ If σ is high
k
=⇒ The RTS will not change much relative to l

=⇒ The isoquant will be close to linear


▶ If σ value is low

=⇒ Isoquant is sharply curved


k
=⇒ The RTS will change by a substantial amount as l changes
▶ It is convenient to assume that σ is constant along an isoquant

▶ If the production function is also homothetic

=⇒ All the isoquants are merely radial blowups and σ will be


the same along all isoquants

64 / 83
Production Functions
Examples of Production Function

1. Linear (Perfect Substitutes) Production Function


▶ The Linear production function is given by

q = f (k, l) = αk + βl

▶ All isoquants for this production function are parallel straight


β
lines with slope − α
β
=⇒ RTS =
α

▶ This production function exhibits constant returns to scale

f (tk, tl) = α(tk) + β(tl) = t(αk + βl) = tf (k, l)

=⇒ f(tk,tl) = t f(k,l)

65 / 83
Production Functions
Examples of Production Function: Linear Production Function

66 / 83
Production Functions
Examples of Production Function

▶ Since RTS is constant along the isoquant

=⇒ Change in RTS along the isoquant is zero


=⇒ Elasticity of substitution is infinite for linear production
function

▶ Linear production implies perfect substitution between the


inputs (k and l)

67 / 83
Production Functions
Examples of Production Function

2. Fixed proportions (Perfect Complements) Production Function


▶ The fixed proportions production function is given by

q = min(αk, βl) where α > 0, β > 0

▶ The isoquants for this production function are L-shaped


▶ This production implies that the inputs are to be combined in
fixed-proportions to produce the output
▶ A firm would always operate at the corner of an isoquant
▶ Operating anywhere else is inefficient

→ Because the same output could be produced with fewer inputs by


moving along the isoquant toward the corner

68 / 83
Production Functions
Examples of Production Function: Linear Production Function

69 / 83
Production Functions
Examples of Production Function: Fixed Proportions Production Function

q = min(αk, βl) where α > 0, β > 0

▶ At the vertex of any isoquant, αk = βl =⇒ k β


l = α

▶ This is how the inputs k and l are to be combined

▶ Since the inputs are to be combined in fixed proportion to produce


the output
=⇒ It is not possible to substitute one input for the other
=⇒ Elasticity of Substitution for this production function is
zero

70 / 83
Production Functions
Examples of Production Function: Fixed Proportions Production Function

▶ Since the curve is L-shaped, there are only two RTS ratios

▶ One RTS ratio is represented by the vertical line (of the L-shaped)
of isoquant
▶ The other RTS ratio is represented by the horizontal line (of the
L-shaped) of isoquant
▶ As we move from the vertical segment to the horizontal segment

=⇒ RTS ratio changes


=⇒ RTS changes from infinity to zero
=⇒ A large change in the RTS as we move from vertical to
horizontal segment
=⇒ Elasticity of substitution is Zero

71 / 83
Production Functions
Examples of Production Function: Fixed Proportions Production Function

q = min(αk, βl) where α > 0, β > 0

▶ Suppose that αk < βl, then q = αk

=⇒ Capital is the binding constraint in this production process


=⇒ The employment of more labor would not increase output
=⇒ Marginal product of labor is zero
=⇒ Additional labor is superfluous in this case

72 / 83
Production Functions
Examples of Production Function: Fixed Proportions Production Function

▶ Similarly, if αk > βl,

=⇒ Labor is the binding constraint on output


=⇒ Additional capital is superfluous

▶ When αk = βl

=⇒ Both inputs are fully utilized


=⇒ Production takes place at a vertex on the isoquant map

▶ If both inputs are costly, this is the only cost-minimizing place


to operate

▶ The locus of all such vertices is a straight line through the origin
β
with a slope given by α

73 / 83
Production Functions
Examples of Production Function: Cobb-Douglas Production Function

3. Cobb-Douglas Production Function


▶ Cobb–Douglas production function, provides a middle ground
between the two polar cases previously discussed

▶ Cobb–Douglas production function is given by

q = f (k, l) = Ak α l β

where A, α, and β are all positive constants

▶ Isoquants for the Cobb–Douglas production function are


convex to the origin

74 / 83
Production Functions
Examples of Production Function: Cobb-Douglas Production Function

▶ The elasticity of substitution for these production functions is 1


(one)
k k
RTS = =⇒ ln RTS = ln
l l

k
=⇒ artialln RTS = artialln
l

∂ln kl
=⇒ =1
∂ln RTS

=⇒ σ = 1

75 / 83
Production Functions
Examples of Production Function: Cobb-Douglas Production Function

▶ The Cobb–Douglas function can exhibit any degree of returns to


scale, depending on the values of α and β

f (tk, tl) = A(tk)α (tl)β = t α+β Ak α l β

=⇒ f (tk, tl) = t α+β f (k, l)

▶ If α + β = 1 =⇒ Constant returns to scale

▶ If α + β < 1 =⇒ Decreasing returns to scale

▶ If α + β > 1 =⇒ Increasing returns to scale

76 / 83
Production Functions
Examples of Production Function: Cobb-Douglas Production Function

▶ The Cobb–Douglas function has also proved to be useful in many


applications because it is linear in logarithms

ln q = ln A + α ln k + β ln l

▶ α is the elasticity of output with respect to capital input

▶ β is the elasticity of output with respect to labor input

▶ These constants can be estimated from actual data and are used to
measure returns to scale (by using sum α + β)

77 / 83
Production Functions
Examples of Production Function: CES production function

4. Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) production function


▶ A functional form that incorporates all three previous cases is the
constant elasticity of substitution (CES) production function
▶ CES production function is of the form
γ
q = f (k, l) = [k ρ + l ρ ] ρ

where ρ <= 1, ρ ̸= 1, and γ > 0


▶ CES production function has a constant elasticity of
substitution
▶ CES production function allows σ to take on any value (including
the σ of past three production function)

78 / 83
Production Functions
Examples of Production Function: CES production function

γ
q = f (k, l) = [k ρ + l ρ ] ρ

▶ For γ > 1 the function exhibits increasing returns to scale

▶ For γ < 1 the function exhibits decreasing returns to scale

▶ The elasticity of substitution of this production function is given by

1
σ=
1−ρ

79 / 83
Production Functions
Examples of Production Function: CES production function

▶ CES production function boils down to Linear production


function when ρ = 1
=⇒ σ = ∞

▶ CES production function boils down to Fixed proportions


production function when ρ = −∞
=⇒ σ = 0

▶ CES production function boils down to Cobb-Douglas


production function when ρ = 0
=⇒ σ = 1

80 / 83
Production Functions
Examples of Production Function: CES production function

▶ Prooving that the CES production function boils down to different


production functions for different values of ρ requires using limits
argument

▶ For example:

γ
lim f (k, l) = lim [k ρ + l ρ ] ρ = k + l
ρ→1 ρ→1

81 / 83
Production Functions
Examples of Production Function: CES production function

▶ Often the CES production function is used with a distributional


weight, α(0 ≤ α ≤ 1) to indicate the relative significance of the
inputs
γ
=⇒ q = f (k, l) = [αk ρ + (1 − α)l ρ ] ρ

▶ With constant returns to scale (γ = 1) and ρ = 0, this function


converges to the Cobb–Douglas form

q = f (k, l) = k α l 1−α

82 / 83
References

Chapter 9
Snyder, Christopher and Nicholson, Walter. (2012). Microeconomic
Theory: Basic Principles and Extensions

83 / 83

You might also like