L2 Output and aggregate demand
L2 Output and aggregate demand
» we have also seen that even in most developed economies in the world,
GDP fluctuates: economic booms and recessions are subject to
economic and political analysis;
» for simplicity, we will ignore differences between GDP, GNP, GNI and
use the terms „output” and „income” interchangeably.
2
» We observe the short-term fluctuations in real GDP – but isn’t it the case,
that – concluding from microeconomic analysis – the level of output should
depend on the inputs the economy has at its disposal and their productivity,
which usually do not change rapidly?
» Potential output is the economy’s output when inputs are fully employed. It
tends to grow over time as the supply of inputs or their productivity grow.
˃ Potential output is not the maximum the economy can conceivably
make: it is the output when every market in the economy is in its long-
run equilibrium (all resources are used effectively).
3
» We will analyze the factors determining the long-run economic growth
at the end of the semester – first we will concentrate on the deviations
of the short-term actual output from potential output.
» Since potential output does not change rapidly, we will assume that
potential output is fixed in the short run.
1. All prices and wages in the economy are fixed at a given level.
2. At these fixed prices and wages, the economy has spare resources
(there are workers without a job who would like to work and firms
with spare capacity they could profitably use).
5
» What results from our assumptions of:
▪ fixed prices and wages,
▪ existence of spare resources in the economy?
1. Since there are spare resources in the economy, actual output must be
different (smaller) than the potential output (where all markets are in
equilibrium).
YE = AD
(the economy reaches short run equilibrium if the companies produce exactly
the amount of goods that is demanded in a given period).
7
We have to analyze the determinants of C, I, G, X and Z☺
What determines the households’ consumption and saving decisions? Let
us start with a closed economy without a government model:
8
Economists assume that there are two parts of consumption demand:
9
Economists assume that there are two parts of consumption demand:
10
» marginal propensity to consume (c or the MPC) is the fraction of each extra
pound (zloty, dollar) of disposable income that households wish to
consume.
11
If Ca is a positive constant, and MPC is a positive fraction between 0 and 1, then
C = Ca + MPC x Y
12
The consumption function
0 Y
14
Saving is income not consumed:
Y=C+S S=Y-C
» Since a fraction MPC of each pound (zloty, dollar) of extra income is consumed, a
fraction (1 – MPC) of each extra pound (zloty, dollar) of income is saved.
» Since an extra pound (dollar, zloty) of income is divided into extra desired
consumption and extra desired saving, and there is no other way for the
households to allocate additional income, MPC + MPS = 1 15
The relationship between the consumption function and the saving function:
Y = C + S so S = Y – C
C = Ca + MPC x Y
S = Y – (Ca + MPCxY)
S = Y - Ca – MPCxY
S = - Ca + Y - MPCxY
S = - Ca + Y (1-MPC)
Thus:
S = - Ca + MPSxY
16
The saving function
• The saving function
shows desired saving
at each income level.
17
» We try to analyze aggregate demand in a closed economy without
government: Y = AD = C + I
18
» Investment – as we already know, the companies’ planned spending on new
capital goods in the form of factories, machinery and buildings, but also –
changes in inventories.
I
0 Y
20
To sum up:
AD = C + I
» We can also the AD function adding the constant amount of I for the
desired (planned) investment to the previous consumption function.
21
Aggregate demand function
YE = AD
(the economy reaches short run equilibrium if the companies produce exactly the
amount of goods that is demanded in a given period).
23
Aggregate demand function
• But how to determine the
right level of aggregate
demand and output, at which
the Y = AD short run
equilibrium condition is met?
AD
• Graphically it is simple: we
should include the 45-degree
line!
unplanned saving).
Aggregate demand function
Y2 Y
27
The AD schedule – moving along it or shifting it?
• The AD schedule is a straight line
whose position depends on its
intercept (autonomous demand)
and its slope (the MPC).
28
The AD schedule – moving along it or shifting it?
Y Y1 Y
29
The AD schedule – moving along it or shifting it?
• The slope of the AD schedule – how
aggregate demand changes as
income changes – is determined by
the MPC.
E1
AD • A change in the MPC changes the
slope of the AD schedule, causing it
to rotate around the point on the
E vertical axis at which income is zero.
Y=C+I
S = Y – C so Y = C + S
I=S 31
At equilibrium output, planned I equals planned S
S, I
E
Spl = -Ca + KSOxY
Ipl
-Ca
Output, income
32
At equilibrium output, planned I equals planned S
» firms make their investment decisions and households make their saving and
consumption plans: they are not the same decision units to automatically
equate I and S….
» But: planned saving depends on income, and planned investment does not:
equilibrium income adjusts to make households plan to save as much as firms
are planning to invest!
33
Let us consider an example:
» in an economy: MPC = 0,6 (thus MPS = 0,4), Ca = 10 and I = 30.
If income in our economy exceeds the equilibrium income (100), households want
to save more (38) than firms want to invest (30)…
Since AD = 112, companies will not be able to sell all the output produced (120): 35
there will be unplanned inventories (120-112 = 8)
» What would happen in our economy if income exceeded 100?
Since AD = 112, companies will not be able to sell all the output produced (120):
there will be unplanned inventories (120-112 = 8)
There is no unplanned saving (people may buy what they want) actual saving =
planned saving = -10 + 0,4x90 = -10 + 36 = 26
There is unplanned investment (stocks are depleted - disinvestment) = - 4
So actual investment = planned investment + unplanned investment
Actual investment = 30 + (-4) = 26
Actual investment = actual saving 38
Injections = leakages from the circular flow!
45o line
AD1 Suppose the economy
starts in equilibrium
at Y0.
AD0
An increase in aggregate
demand (to be precise – in
autonomous demand – eg.
investment) to AD1…
39
Notice that the change in equilibrium output is
larger than the original change in autonomous demand!
Do you remember our economy where:
Let us assume now that firms decide to invest more: ΔI = 10 (new investment = 40)
by 25!
Why does an increase in investment by 10 result in an increase in equilibrium
output by 25?
» Higher investment demand induces an increase in output and income that then
induces an extra increase in consumption (households have more money at
their disposal, so ceteris paribus – holding their Ca, MPC and MPS constant,
they will plan to consume and save more).
» Economists measure the strength of this change in income using the category
of multiplier:
The multiplier is the ratio of the change in equilibrium output to the change in
autonomous spending that caused the change: 41
∆𝐘
Multiplier (M)=
∆𝐀𝐃𝐚
The multiplier is the ratio of the change in equilibrium output to the change in
autonomous spending that caused the change:
∆𝐘
Multiplier (M)=
∆𝐀𝐃𝐚
∆Y
» Since M= , ∆Y = M x ∆Ada
∆ADa
» the multiplier tells us how much output changes after a shift in aggregate
demand (a change in autonomous demand);
» the size of the multiplier depends on the MPC: the initial effect of a unit
increase in investment is to increase output and income by one unit as well –
but then – in accordance with the MPC – some part of the additional income is
consumed, which also contributes to an increase in AD, and thus – income;
Step 1
» An initial increase in investment by 10 „injected” into the circular flow of our
economy resulted in an increase in AD by 10 and an increase in income by 10
as well
Step 2
» Households – who owe the factors of production – got this additional income
(10) and divided it into saving and consumption (since MPC = 0,6, 60% of the
additional income will be consumed, 40% will be saved).
Step 3
» since in step 2 income increased by 6, households will spend 0,6x6=3,6 and
save 0,4x6=2,4;
» Additional increase in consumption by 3,6 will result in an increase in AD and
income – and again, some of it (60%) will be consumed, and the rest – saved…
» The process continues in our circular flow as long as there are any positive
changes in income – but the changes in income are getting smaller and smaller
in accordance with an obvious pattern…
45
How did aggregate demand change in our example?
We should add up all the increases in AD and income to calculate the total
increase:
» The right-hand side of this equation is called a geometric series – each term
(increase in AD and income) is 0,6 times the previous term (increase);
» Mathematicians have come up with a general formula for the sum of all the
terms in such a series:
46
𝟏𝟎
Sum of our geometric series =
𝟏−𝟎,𝟔
» Mathematicians have come up with a general formula for the sum of all the
terms in such a series:
𝟏𝟎
Sum of our geometric series =
𝟏−𝟎,𝟔
» Sum of our geometric series = sum of all increases in AD and income (∆Y)
» 10 – initial change in autonomous demand (∆ADa)
» 0,6 – marginal propensity to consume.
Therefore:
∆ADa 47
∆Y = =
𝟏−𝑴𝑷𝑪
Do you remember?
The multiplier is the ratio of the change in equilibrium output to the change in
autonomous spending that caused the change:
∆𝐘
Multiplier (M)=
∆𝐀𝐃𝐚
∆ADa ∆Y 1
Since ∆Y = = ∆ADa =
𝟏−𝑴𝑷𝑪 𝟏−𝑴𝑷𝑪
Therefore:
1
Multiplier (M) =
𝟏−𝑴𝑷𝑪
1 1
So in our case: M = = =2,5!
𝟏−𝟎,𝟔 𝟎,𝟒
48
» The larger the MPC, ceteris paribus, the larger the multiplier.
» Since MPC + MPS = 1 (any part of an extra unit of income not spent must be
saved), 1 – MPC = MPS: we can also think of the multiplier as:
1 1
Multiplier (M) = =
𝟏−𝑴𝑷𝑪 𝑴𝑷𝑺
» The higher the marginal propensity to save, the more of each extra unit of
income leaks out of the circular flow into saving and the less goes back round the
circular flow to generate further increase in AD, output and income.
49
» We have already analyzed a change in equilibrium output caused by a change in
autonomous investment demand.
» A higher AD schedule must intersect the 45-degree line at a higher level of output
– hence equilibrium output increases.
» Since households intend to consume more at any given income, it means that
they want to save less… but does the level of saving decrease?
Ca = 20, ceteris paribus - MPC = 0,6 (thus MPS = 0,4) and I = 30.
The new equilibrium income is:
Y = AD
Y = 20 + 0,6Y + 30
0,4Y = 50
Y = 125.
S = - Ca + 0,4xY
S = -20 + 0,4x125 = -20 + 50 = 30
Or
Y=C+SS=Y–C
C = 20 + 0,6x125 = 20 + 75 = 95
S = 125 – 95 = 30
S = 30 – and so is investment – planned investments still equals planned saving! 53
To conclude:
» A decline to thriftiness – a fall in the desire to save – does not affect planned
investment – hence in order to restore equilibrium where planned investment =
planned saving, equilibrium income must rise enough to maintain the equality of
planned saving (which depends on current income) and planned investment.
» Why is it a paradox?
» Common sense would suggest that if we want to consume more, we will end up
with lower level of saving, and when we want to save more, out income will
remain unaffected.
54
» Is saving beneficial for the economy? Not necessarily in this model…
Our example again:
MPC = 0,6 (thus MPS = 0,4), Ca = 10 and I = 30.
Y = 100 (equilibrium output)
C = Ca + 0,6xY C = 10 + 60 = 70, S = I = 30
Now assume we want to save more and consume less at any income (Ca falls to 0)
Consumption function is C=0,6xY and saving: S=0,4Y
Equilibrium income must change:
Y = AD
Y = 0,6Y + 30
0,4Y = 30
Y = 75
We earn less, so we can consume less:
C = 0,6x75 = 45, but saving still equals investment: S = 0,4x75 = 30
Paradox: we still save the same sum, but equilibrium income and consumption 55
decrease… in our model, ceteris paribus, thrifty people actually seem not to know
which side their bread is buttered on…