Problem Set 3 Solutions
Problem Set 3 Solutions
1. Here, U (S, B) = SB + 10(S + B). Notice that here marginal utilities are linear (so not diminishing marginal
p1
utilities), and here we may not have an interior solution, so the M RS = p2 method may not work. But let’s
B + 10 1
=
S + 10 3
3B + 30 = S + 10
S = 3B + 20
Plugging this condition into the budget constraint, which will hold with equality because of monotonicity of
preferences, we get
pS S + pB B = 30
3S + 9B = 30
3 (3B + 20) + 9B = 30
9B + 60 + 9B = 30
18B = −30
30
∴B = −
18
Now, eating − 30
18 burgers is not physically possible (except in really gross fast food joints), so we must have
a corner solution with B = 0, and spend all the money on salad, so 3S = 30 and S = 10. What is the reason
1
spending one more dollar on Salad always adds more utility than spending one more dollar on Burger, hence
2. Here, U (x, y) = x2 y. Given the utility function, it’s easy to see we won’t have a corner solution, because
choosing either x = 0 or y = 0 leads to a utility level of 0, whereas positive amounts of both goods gives a
px
higher utility. So we can use the M RS = py trick. So,
M Ux px
=
M Uy py
2xy 8
=
x2 2
4y = 8x
∴ y∗ = 2x∗
px x∗ + py y ∗ = I
12x∗ = 240
∴ x∗ = 20
∴ y∗ = 40
√
3. Here, U (x, y) = 2 x + y
∂U (x,y) 1 ∂U (x,y)
(a) M Ux = = 2 2√ = √1 ; M Uy = = 1.
∂x x x ∂y
(c) You can easily see that √1 decreases as x increases. If you can’t, you can take the derivative of √1 and
x x
2
(f) Now, as monotonicity is satisfied, the budget constraint must hold with equality, so
p x x∗ + p y y ∗ = I
2
py
px + py y ∗ = I
px
2
(py )
+ py y ∗ = I
px
2
(py )
py y ∗ = I−
px
I py
∴ y∗ = −
py px
Her demand for y changes linearly as I changes. Basically, for a fixed price ratio, she spends a constant
(py )2
amount px on x, and spends the rest of her income on y. This is true for any interior solution with
quasilinear preferences.
√
4. Emily’s preferences are given by the utility function U (x1 , x2 ) = 32 x1 + 2x2 . Also, p1 = 2, and p2 = 1.
32
√
M Ux1
√8 ,
2 x1
(a) For Emily, M RSx1 ,x2 = M Ux2 = 2 = x1 which is diminishing as x1 increases.
p1
(b) Suppose m ≥ 32. Then, the M RS = p2 condition gives us
8 2
√ =
x1 1
√
x1 = 4
∴ x∗1 = 16
Notice that the optimal level of food is independent of income. However, as p1 = 2, Emily will need an
income of at least 32 in order to buy 16 units of food. So as long as m ≥ 32, we have x∗1 = 16.
(c) For this part, we will need to find her optimal consumption level of clothing as well. Because she will
p1 x∗1 + p2 x∗2 = m
∴ x∗2 = m − 32
3
For U (x1 (p1 , p2 , m) , x2 (p1 , p2 , m)), we compute the marginal utility of income as follows:
dU ∂U ∂x1 ∂U ∂x2
= +
dm ∂x1 ∂m ∂x2 ∂m
32
= √ (0) + 2 (1)
2 x1
= 2
Because the marginal utility of income is a constant, it does not change with her level of income. This
is because Emily spends all of her added income on clothing only, which has a constant marginal utility.
(d) If instead we had m < 32, then she does not have enough income to buy 16 units of food. In that case,
M U x1 √16 M U x2 M U x1
√8
x1
we see that p1 = 2 = x1 and p2 = 2; when x1 < 16, p1 > 2. This tells us that her
marginal utility of spending one more dollar on food is higher than her marginal utility of spending one
more dollar on clothing, which means she should spend all of her income on food, so x∗1 = m
p1 = m
2, and
dU ∂U ∂x1 ∂U ∂x2
= +
dm ∂x1 ∂m ∂x2 ∂m
32 1
= √ + 2 (0)
2 x1 2
8 8
= √ = pm
x1 2
So in this case, her marginal utility does depend on her level of income.