U2
U2
1
What problems does political economy address?
What questions does it ask?
It also indicates how the pedagogy of modern political economy can counteract the
dwindling interest in the formal study of economics.
3
4 ECONOMIC PROCESSES AND PROBLEMS—THE CURRENT CONTEXT
models have a strong influence on economic policies in practice and they therefore
do have an awesome relevance, for better or worse. This has been particularly evident
in the last three decades. Orthodox economic reasoning has given rise to particular
policy prescriptions, such as the liberalisation of trade, the deregulation of financial
markets, and the privatisation of public enterprises. The proponents of these policies
seem relatively untroubled by the failure of the real world to exhibit the features
assumed in the abstract theories. It is as if the real world is being reconstructed in
the image of a particular economic theory. Either way, as a purely theoretical exercise
or, as a vulgarised version of that theory used for political purposes, conventional
economics has deep problems.2
Modern political economy seeks to break free of this straightjacket by directly
confronting the current political economic problems and policy issues. There is no
shortage of such concerns: the challenge posed by the power of multinational
corporations, the tension between economic growth and ecological sustainability,
the economic insecurity and inequality intensified by contemporary structural
economic changes, the proliferation of speculative financial activities and their
adverse consequences for economic stability and productivity, and the continuing
problems of promoting balanced economic and social development, especially in
poorer nations.
The immediate appeal of the political economic approach is its direct engagement
with these issues. A link is thereby established between studies in economics and
what is reported in the daily newspapers and on radio and television current affairs
programs. Simultaneously, links are created with other areas of study, such as
geography, history, social studies, political science, and industrial relations. Indeed,
this interdisciplinary character of political economy is one of its strengths. Real-
world phenomena do not fit neatly into boxes labelled ‘economic’, ‘social’, ‘political’,
or ‘cultural’. These categories have been constructed for academic convenience, and
the disciplinary divisions—between economics, sociology, and political science, for
example—can impede a full understanding. Political economic analysis is enriched
by drawing from these other disciplines. It leads towards a more holistic approach to
social science.
O What is happening?
O Why?
O Who gains? Who loses?
O Does it matter?
O If so, what can be done and by whom?
inconsequential. Then, the 'Why?' question shifts attention to the analysis of causal
factors—the forces, people, or institutions driving the political economic processes
in question. Next, taking stock of winners and losers requires careful study of how
the various participants in the economic drama are affected. The question ‘Does it
matter? then introduces more explicitly evaluative considerations. This provides the
link between the analysis oi problems and the discussion of responses, leading into
the final question about remedial policies and strategies. We are not simply passive
observers of political economic change: as active participants, our effectiveness
depends on how we address the strategic question of what can be done.3 Box 1.1
illustrates these five steps applied to globalisation.
BOX 1.1
GLOBALISATION
It is commonly asserted that our lives are now being radically changed by the integration
of economic activities on a global scale. Globalisation is said to be breaking down the
territorial boundaries that used to limit the opportunities (and threats) that we experienced.
According to this view, technological and economic changes are transforming society
and culture. We fail to adjust at our peril, individually and collectively.
Is this really so? Asking the five key political economic questions can reveal a more
sophisticated story.
First, to answer 'What is happening?' requires important distinctions to be made
between the globalisation of finance and trade, of culture, of environmental concerns,
and of human rights. Focusing on the globalisation of business activities, for example,
requires careful study of the changing patterns of international trade in goods and
services, international investment, and/or international finance (including the proliferation
of speculative activities).
Answering the question 'Why?' requires analysis of the drivers of change, including the
complex interactions between the forces external to nation states and the forces nurtured
within them. The influences of consumerism, technology, and government policies towards
hosting multinational corporations, for example, come into the spotlight.
The question 'Who gains; who loses?' is equally complex. The changing international
distribution of jobs and incomes is one important aspect. Large multinational companies,
seeking to take advantage of differential labour costs, have often relocated parts of
their manufacturing activities to developing nations. As a result, significant numbers of
workers in those countries have gained industrial employment previously unavailable to
them; however, although usually better paying than the traditional occupations, these
jobs are frequently associated with particular health and environmental risks. Whether
the industrialisation, often localised in enclaves called 'export-processing zones', has
trickle-down benefits for the rest of the society is also uncertain: it depends on how and
where the extra income is spent and on whether the companies pay significant amounts
of money in local taxes. Meanwhile, the employees in more affluent nations face pressures
for wage reduction in order to try to keep the local manufacturing businesses competitive,
or face unemployment if the firms go under.
6 ECONOMIC PROCESSES AND PROBLEMS-THE CURRENT CONTEXT
Does globalisation matter? Certainly, the political economic changes have major social
and environmental implications. The advantages for consumers of being able to shop in
the global marketplace need to be balanced against the greater economic insecurity that
many workers face. The socially destabilising effects of changing patterns of economic
inequality demand attention. And the environmental impacts of worldwide sourcing of
raw materials, increasingly extensive transport, and use of non-renewable energy sources
are further sources of tension.
So, what is to be done? Is the capacity for national economic management
undermined by the greater mobility of capital? To what extent, and in which policy
fields, are governments able to shape the terms on which nation states engage with the
global economy? If governments are, indeed, losing their managerial capacity, to which
other institutions—local, non-governmental, or supranational—can we instead look to
control the processes of change? Can labour, environmental, or consumer movements,
for example, go global in order to counteract the globalisation of business and finance?
These are the kinds of big, strategic questions that globalising processes generate for
modern political economy.
given a progressive, modern twist. The emphasis on the troublesome issue of land
and land ownership, ignored by much economic theorising over the last century, is
particularly important.
Marxist economics
Marxist economics also warrants careful consideration. Its roots are in the tradition
of classical political economy, but it provides a quite different, more critical,
interpretation of capitalism. It emphasises the basis of the capitalist economy in
particular property relations, class structures, and the relentless drive for capital
accumulation. Marxist economics posits the exploitation of labour as the source of
the economic surplus. From that springs class conflict and the potential for radical
political economic change. The tenets of Marxist economic analysis that underlie
this view (such as the labour theory of value, the theory of surplus value, and the
explanation of recurrent economic crises) need to be critically re-evaluated to test
their applicability to the modern economy. These are, quite properly, focal points for
debate about the relevance of Marxism today. Generally, though, the holistic
character of Marxian political economy and its emphasis on the conflicts and
contradictions driving economic change has evident resonance in the current context.
Globalisation, for example, can be interpreted from this perspective as the drive by
capitalist business interests to break through the constraints on capital accumulation
imposed by national boundaries.4
Institutional economics
Institutional economics is another tradition that also has much to offer modern
political economy. It emerged from the German historical school of the nineteenth
century and flourished in the twentieth century, partly as a reaction to what is
considered to be the unrealistic abstractions of orthodox economic theory. Its leading
exponents, from Thorstein Veblen to J. K. Galbraith, have persistently emphasised
the need to come to terms with the changes in institutional form associated with the
ongoing development of capitalist economies. The focus is on economic evolution.
Distinctive themes are the growth of big business, transnational corporations, the
influence of trade unions, and the varied governmental economic activities that
occur in different nations. Although coming from politically diverse positions, the
institutional economists have provided powerful ideas for shaping economic reform.5
The potential for more extensive interventions by the state to alleviate the inequality
and instability of free-market capitalism is a particular focus.
Keynesian economics
In this context Keynesian economic analysis also has continuing importance.
John Maynard Keynes was probably the most significant economist of the twentieth
century. He explained why capitalism cannot guarantee full employment, and
identified the necessary remedial policies at a time when more conventional economic
prescriptions had demonstrably failed. He showed that the economy did not function
simply as the aggregation of economic markets and that, without enlightened
government intervention, unemployment would recur. So, too, would the problem
of inflation. Orthodox economists subsequently sought to graft a mechanistic
8 ECONOMIC PROCESSES AND PROBLEMS—THE CURRENT CONTEXT
Neoclassical economics
The role of neoclassical economic theory is more problematic. As already noted, it
has been the dominant economic orthodoxy. As such, it needs to be carefully
understood. But much of the impetus for modern political economy comes from the
quest for an alternative. One approach is to consider neoclassical economics
pragmatically, as a possible source of contributions to the modern political economist’s
tool kit. Some elements within neoclassical economics—such as the analysis of
externalities and the measurement of demand and supply elasticities—can be
salvaged for this purpose. However, the problem is that neoclassical theory also
embodies a distinctive ideology—presenting a particular image of a free market
capitalist economy serving societal preferences. These orthodox economic ideas are
better understood when treated comparatively with classical, Marxist, institutional,
and Keynesian views. This is the essence of the liberal educational principle applied
to the study of economic issues.
BOX 1.2
STUDYING ECONOMICS OR
POLITICAL ECONOMY?
It appears paradoxical that, at a time when economic issues are of such importance in the
world, there has been widespread decline in student enthusiasm for studying economics.
Reorienting the discipline towards modern political economy, as suggested here, does
not necessarily arrest or reverse that decline. At the secondary school level, the fall in
enrolments in economics courses, and the corresponding growth in subject areas such
as business studies, has a complex explanation that goes beyond the concerns of this
introductory chapter. However, to the extent that the aversion to studying conventional
economics is partly the product of its supposedly dry subject matter, the political economic
approach offers a potentially engaging alternative. This approach is capable of stimulating
more interest and enthusiasm than the more conventional economics syllabus. Studying
political economy is not easy; indeed, the emphasis on competing currents of economic
thought and their association with rival political philosophies adds complexity to the
subject. But this engagement with controversial issues creates more intellectual excitement
than the narrow, seemingly technical, treatment of orthodox economic analysis.
The link between political economy and current affairs, as discussed in newspapers,
and on radio and television, is also more explicit. There is less requirement than in
orthodox economics courses and textbooks for the suspension of disbelief. Students do
not have to switch off from the world around them as they watch elaborate theories being
constructed with little evident connection to observable phenomena in the real world. In
political economy, the point of the analysis can usually be seen more clearly and directly.
There are theories to be studied, of course, but their relative plausibility can be discussed
with reference to real-world observations. Moreover, there is plenty of scope for students
to develop links between their own personal experiences and the broader concerns of
political economy. Case studies (of particular firms or industries, of cities and regions, of
industrial disputes, of unemployment problems, or of the winners and losers resulting
from different government economic policies, for example) can be a useful vehicle for this.
For all these reasons, the approach of political economy should have substantial appeal
for students who are interested in how they fit into the world around them, and how they
might contribute to changing it for the better.9
10 ECONOMIC PROCESSES AND PROBLEMS—THE CURRENT CONTEXT
CONCLUSION
KEY POINTS
O Political economy addresses real-world concerns in a way that emphasises the
connections between economic problems, social structures, and political processes.
O There is a rich heritage of economic thought from which modern political economy
draws—particularly, but not exclusively, classical political economy, Marxist economics,
institutional economics, and Keynesian economics.
M any people come to the study of economics expecting that it will offer
guidelines for getting rich. They are usually disappointed to find that it is
about how the economic system works, rather than how the system can be worked
for personal advantage. The former may help the latter, of course, in that people are
likely to make more astute financial decisions if they know about the economic,
social, and political forces shaping the business and financial environment.
Concurrently, it is also to be hoped that a better understanding of how the economy
works and what the sources of economic problems are will stimulate more concern
with remedial policies and strategies to achieve better social outcomes.
Generally, it is not an unreasonable expectation that the study of economics should
serve the needs of intelligent citizens who wish to make sense of the world around them.
It is an expectation that, currently, is both in sharp focus and difficult to satisfy. This is
because the current era is one of economic uncertainty, a time when individuals have to
cope with major changes to their material circumstances, often with little understanding
of what is driving those changes and the potential for a change of direction.
BOX 2.1
ECONOMIC DECISIONS
Our day-to-day lives involve many economic decisions. Most of these are fairly small-scale
and short-term and of no apparent significance to anyone beyond our immediate family
and friends. In the aggregate, they shape the economic environment in which we live. Some
such decisions, illustrating our various social and economic roles, are described below.
O As workers, we are faced with constrained choices about the jobs we seek and the
hours we work. We also have to make periodic decisions, individually or collectively,
about the strategic stance to take in negotiations with our employers about wages and
conditions of work.
O Meanwhile, business decision-makers make their own strategic decisions about
employment and wages payments. They also periodically review the methods they use
for producing goods and services, how much they will invest in new production facilities,
the prices they will charge for their products, and their sales promotion practices.
O Speculators continually review their portfolio of assets, deciding what to buy and sell
according to their judgments about future price movements and the possibility of
capital gains. When media commentators refer to how 'the markets' respond to
economic news or government policy initiatives, it is the behaviour of these speculators
to which they are referring.
O Banks decide about making loans to their clients, usually according to set guidelines.
They also make decisions about the interest rates offered to depositors and charged
to borrowers. The margins between these borrowing and lending rates are a principal
source of banks' profits, and so they are kept under continual review.
O Government ministers, especially those in key departments such as Treasury and
Finance, also make frequent adjustments to economic policies. They do so in response
to changing economic conditions in national and global markets, and to political
pressures (including the speculative sentiments of the markets). These public policy
positions are also significantly influenced by prevailing economic theories.
There is a link between micro personal choices and macro social choices. Individuals’
economic decisions affect and are affected by broader political economic forces. Indeed,
it is reasonable, as a first approximation, to see what is happening in the economy as a
whole as the outcome of the sum of individual decisions. So, whether the economy is
functioning well or not—whether the overall conditions are buoyant or stagnant, for
example—is the result of whether the numerous interdependent decisions mesh
effectively. There is, of course, much scope for inconsistency, conflicts of interest, and
contradictory elements.
As political economists, we can step back from the minutiae of individual choices
and short-term decisions to see the bigger picture. This can help us understand the
political economic structures that shape and constrain our options. It can also help to
reveal the forces operating to change the context within which individual economic
decisions are made.
THREE TRILOGIES
A simple device for considering some basic political economic principles is shown in
figure 2.1 on the next page. This is taxonomic in character, emphasising classification
rather than explanation. It draws attention to some tensions that arise between
various types of economic arrangement.2
14 ECONOMIC PROCESSES AND PROBLEMS—THE CURRENT CONTEXT
The first diagram depicts the relationship between market, state, and community.
It shows the three different ways in which economic activity can be organised. Goods
and services may be produced for exchange in the market. Many are. Alternatively, the
production and distribution of goods and services may be organised by a central
coordinating agency. Usually, the state then becomes the economic manager. As such, it
may be responsive to the wishes of the society through democratic processes, or it may
be authoritarian in character. The third possibility is that the production and distribution
of goods and services directly serves community needs. Community provision involves
people producing goods and services for themselves and their neighbours, and benefiting
from reciprocal relationships/ The community may be quite small—perhaps just a
household—or it may comprise a larger group of people whose voluntary cooperation
results in purposeful economic activity without the need for markets or a state.
These three different ways of providing for our material needs and wants
normally coexist in any society, but their relative weight can vary enormously,4 and
there are recurrent tensions on the margins between them. Figure 2.1 illustrates
these boundary tensions in terms of the balance between public and private sectors
of the economy, the choice between voluntary and government welfare provision,
and the extent to which social life is structured by market processes.
The second trilogy concerns the spatial scales at which economic activities can be
organised and coordinated. Local production can be for local consumption. Much is.
National coordination of productive activity is also commonly attempted. The
markets for some products are nationwide, and governments usually try, more or less
successfully, to manage national economies. The global dimension is becoming
increasingly important, however, as global markets, and even some embryonic forms
of a global state, have developed. How these three spatial scales are articulated and
how best to strike a balance between them are key issues. As suggested in the second
diagram in figure 2.1, these concerns manifest in challenges to national sovereignty,
the development of global cities, and regional tensions. Here is a gentle reminder of
the importance of the spatial dimension in political economy. All economic activity—
indeed, all of life—takes place in both time and space, so we need analytical structures
that pay due attention to these coordinates of our behaviour.5
The third trilogy shown in figure 2.1 depicts the relationship between economy,
society, and ecology. Economic activities always depend on certain social and
ecological preconditions—the availability of labour and natural resources, for
example—and they have major social and environmental consequences. Political
economy must necessarily focus on these connections. It must show how the balance
between economic, social, and ecological concerns is affected by the relationships
between market, state, and community, and between local, national, and global
scales of economic organisation. In practice, balance is seldom achieved, and the
resulting contradictions are manifest in ongoing concerns about distributional
equity, ecological sustainability, and the quality of life.
The three trilogies shown in figure 2.1 draw attention to social choices. Do we
want our economic arrangements to be mainly market-oriented, increasingly global
in character, and prioritising the pursuit of economic growth? Would we prefer a
greater emphasis on the state, on planning national economic development, and on
social and/or environmental goals? Or would we prefer more focus on the role of the
16 ECONOMIC PROCESSES AND PROBLEMS—THE CURRENT CONTEXT
CONCLUSION
KEY.PQ1NTS
O Political economy emphasises the context within which an array of individual decisions
are made—decisions about the production of goods and services, work and wages,
consumption choices, savings and investment, and economic and financial
management.
O The current political economic context features substantial uncertainty and risks.