Lecture 1
Lecture 1
Lecture 1
Andrea Buraschi
Road Map
1. Introduction
2. Some housekeeping and questions
3. Overview of the course
4. Portfolio theory
I Consumption based asset pricing
Andrea Buraschi: Introduction
Chair in Finance
PhD at University of Chicago
Specialize in Financial Economics (Asset Pricing, Fixed Income, Derivatives)
Previously taught at University of Chicago, Columbia and LBS
The Course
I Lecture notes
I Reading list
I “Asset Pricing” by John Cochrane, 2005, Princeton University Press.
I “Asset Management: A Systematic Approach to Factor Investing”,
by Andrew Ang
I “E¢ ciently Ine¢ cient: How Smart Money Invests and Market Prices
Are Determined”, by Lasse Heje Pedersen
I Several articles
I Case studies
Course Requirements
Question: Suppose you buy a stock today, t, which yields an stochastic payo¤
tomorrow Xt +1 (possibly, the payo¤ tomorrow is the stock price plus dividend,
Xt +1 = pt +1 + dt +1 ). You know the possible outcomes and the associated
probability distribution. How much are you willing to pay for the stock?
Answer:
I Method 1: Asset prices must be consistent with how much utility you
derive from consumption.
I Method 2: Asset prices must be consistent among themselves (there are
no arbitrage opportunities: "Black and Scholes").
The Stochastic Discount Factor
An introduction
I The General Framework: the following is the general framework that can
help us understand most asset pricing models. The majority of them will
be special cases.
I The main idea is to think agents as interteporal optimizers. A simple 2
period case captures most of the intuition: preferences are represented by
a utility function de…ned over current and future levels of consumption
The investor chooses how much, θ , of a stock that pays Xi ,t +1 to hold in order
to maximize her utility U (Ct , Ct +1 ), given her endowment stream Kt , Kt +1
C t +1 = K t +1 + X t +1 θ
The Stochastic Discount Factor
Investors optimization problem
I the marginal loss in utility from acquiring another unit of the asset at time
t: pt u 0 (Ct )
equals
I the marginal gain from consuming the extra payo¤ at time (t + 1):
E t [ δ u 0 (C t +1 )X t +1 ]
The Stochastic Discount Factor
The basic pricing equation
u 0 (C t +1 )
pt = E t δ X t +1
u 0 (C t )
We de…ne the stochastic discount factor mt +1 as the rate at which the investor
is willing to substitute consumption at time (t + 1) for consumption at time t
u 0 (C t +1 )
m t +1 δ
u 0 (C t )
p t = E t [ m t +1 X t +1 ]
The Stochastic Discount Factor
The basic pricing equation
I There is more: the expected value of the stochastic discount factor gives
you enough information to infer the interest rate.
I The price of a zero coupon bond with face value 1 and maturity T is
p t = E t [ m t +T 1]
thus the term structure of bond prices is simply given by the sequence of
expected values of mt +T for di¤erent T
I If the risk-free rate is the rate you get if you invest $1 today and yo get
$1(1 + r ) next period, then:
1 = Et [mt +1 (1 + r )]
or
1
1+r =
E t (m t +1 )
The Stochastic Discount Factor
The risk-free rate
such that
1. (real) interest rates are high when people are impatient;
2. (real) interest rates are high when consumption growth is high;
3. (real) interest rates are more sensitive to consumption growth when
investors are more risk averse (i.e. γ is high).
Example
Forward Contracts
p t +1 F
The forward price F is the expected future spot price of the asset to be
transacted at time t + 1
E t (p t +1 )
plus a term that re‡ects how the discount factor co-varies with the underlying
spot price, or a risk premium
cov (mt +1 , pt +1 )
grossed up by the risk-free interest rate to re‡ect that the contract price is set
at time t, but the payo¤ is received at time t + 1.
I Notice that if future prices are uncorrelated with the SDF mt +1 , i.e.
cov (mt +1 , pt +1 ) = 0, then
F = E t (p t +1 )
max(St +T H, 0)
where St +T is the stock price at time t + T and H is the strike price set at
time t. The option price should be
Alternatively, Ct is given by
max Ct = Et [m (S t +T H )]
m
subject to
m > 0
St = Et (mST )
1 = Et (m (1 + rf ))
p t = E t (m t +1 X t +1 )
then
pt = Et (mt +1 )Et (Xt +1 ) + cov [mt +1 , Xt +1 ]
or
E t (X t +1 ) cov [δu 0 (Ct +1 ), Xt +1 ]
pt = +
1+r u 0 (C t )
Suppose we want to price another asset with payo¤ X̄t +1 such that
X̄t +1 = Xt +1 + εt +1
What is the di¤erence in the price of the payo¤ Xt +1 and in the payo¤ X̄t +1 ?
p̄t = pt
m t +1
Let us now use the same framework to derive the optimal portfolio choice rule.
I Suppose there are n assets available paying X1,t +1 , X2,t +1 , ..., Xn,t +1 at
date t + 1.
I The price of each asset is p1,t , p2,t , ..., pn,t .
Given pt , what is the optimal portfolio of these n assets? We need to specify
U 0 (C )
mt +1 = δ U 0 (Ct +)1 :
t
U 0 (C t +1 )
pi ,t = Et δ X
U 0 (Ct ) i ,t +1
Example
State ω i (t + 1 )
Asset ω1 ω2 ω2
D 6 8 4
E 13 9 8
F 1 1 1
Maximize utility
U 0 (C t +1 )
pt (i ) = E t δ X t +1 (i ) for i = 1, 2, 3.
U 0 (C t )
1 6 1 8 1 4 6
δ + + =
2 C t +1 (1 ) 4 C t +1 (2 ) 4 C t +1 (3 ) Ct
1 13 1 9 1 8 10
δ + + =
2 C t +1 (1 ) 4 C t +1 (2 ) 4 C t +1 (3 ) Ct
1 1 1 1 1 1 1
δ + + =
2 C t +1 (1 ) 4 C t +1 (2 ) 4 C t +1 (3 ) Ct
5
θD = Kt
246
10
θE = Kt
123
25
θF = Kt
123
The Stochastic Discount Factor
The data
I Most models are just special cases of the fundamental pricing equation
pt = Et (mt +1 Xi ,t +1 ).
I A “model” is equivalent to the speci…cation of the necessary structure to
determine the the stochastic discount factor mt +1
I We will show that both the CAPM and multi-factor models are just
di¤erent speci…cations of mt +1.
I In the previous example, m = δ C (Ct +t 1 ) . Notice that m is a stochastic
process.
The Stochastic Discount Factor
Asset returns
pt = Et (mt +1 Xi ,t +1 )
Then
Xi ,t +1
1 = Et m t +1 = Et (mt +1 (1 + ri ,t +1 )) .
pt
1
Since Et (mt +1 ) = 1 +r f
1
1= Et (1 + ri ,t +1 ) + cov [mt +1 , ri ,t +1 ]
1 + rf
or
Et (ri ,t +1 ) rf = (1 + rf ) cov [mt +1 , ri ,t +1 ] .
The Stochastic Discount Factor
CAPM
CAPM states that the expected return of asset j is higher as its beta is higher
E (rj ) = rf + β j [E (rm ) rf ]
cov (rj , rm )
βj =
σ2m
m = ā b̄rm
Exercise. Prove that indeed the CAPM is immediately obtained when the SDF
is linear in rm : to prove it you just need to show that there exists two set of
constants ā and b̄ that enforce the CAPM condition.
The Stochastic Discount Factor
Example 1: CAPM
then
(1 + rf ) b̄ σ2m = [E (rm ) rf ]
so that we recover the CAPM model!
Et (ri ,t +1 ) rf = βi [E (rm ) rf ]
h i
(Additional condition ā = 1 +1rf + b̄E (1 + rm ) )
The Stochastic Discount Factor
Example 2: APT
E (rj ) = λ0 + λ1 βj ,1 + ... + λk βj ,k
where
I λi is the factor risk premia which tells you how much extra return you get
for each extra unit of risk your portfolio has (there exists one λ for each
factor in the economy, plus one extra λ0 )
I βj ,i s represent factor loadings.
The Stochastic Discount Factor
Example 2: APT
The return and expected return on a portfolio with weight w on the risky
security and (1 w ) on the risk-free asset is:
rP = wri + (1 w )rf
rP = rf + w (ri rf )
| {z }
rie
E (rP ) = rf + wE (rie )
= w 2 σ2i
Which Portfolio?
E (ri ) rf
w =
γσ2i
Which Portfolio?
ERp,w = w 0 E (R ) + wf Rf = Rf + w 0 [E (R ) Rf ]
ERp,w Rf = w 0 [E (R ) Rf ]
0
Var (Rp,w ) = w Σw
For simplicity, let use a star to denote an excess return, so that the excess
return of the portfolio is ERp,w = E (Rp,w ) Rf and the excess return of each
risky asset is ERn = E (Rn ) Rf for n = 1, 2...N.
Portfolios of Assets
L (w , λ) = w 0 Σw + λ(w 0 ER µ0 )
∂L (w , λ )
= 2Σw + λER = 0
∂w
∂L (w , λ )
= (w 0 ER µ0 ) = 0
∂λ
Solve for (w , λ) by substitution. Start from the …rst equation and solve for w :
1 1
w = λΣ ER
2
Portfolios of Assets
1
λER 0 Σ 1
ER µ0 = 0
2
h i 1
λ = 2 ER 0 Σ 1
ER µ0
Σ 1 ER
w = µ0
[ER 0 Σ 1 ER ]
Σ 1 [E (R ) Rf ]
= µ0
[E (R ) Rf ]0 Σ 1 [E (R ) Rf ]
This is the amount to be invested in the risky assets. How much should you
invest in the risk-free? What is left from your total wealth: the sum of all the
portfolio weights should be 1, thus
wf = 1 i 0w
Portfolios of Assets
What is the portfolio weight wT for the tangency portfolio? This is the portfolio
which is invested 100% in the risky assets, thus i 0 w = 1. This implies that
h i 1
µ ER 0 Σ 1 ER [i 0 Σ 1 ER ] = 1
1 1. 164 4 0.867 34
wT = =
1. 342 5 0.178 08 0.132 65
Optimal Portfolio Choice
Exponential utility
C t +1 = θ t X t +1 + (K t θ t p t ) (1 + rf )
| {z } | {z }
Risky Payo¤ Risk Free
where θ t is the number of shares of the risky asset the investor acquires;
θ t pt is the dollar value of these shares.
I Let’s assume, morever, that
X t +1 N (µX , σ2X )
Optimal Portfolio Choice
Exponential utility
C t +1 = θ t p t (1 + rt +1 ) + (K t θ t p t ) (1 + rf )
where θ t is the number of shares of the risky asset the investor acquires, or
C t +1 = K t [ w t rt +1 + (1 w t ) rf ] + K t
where wt is the fraction of the initial wealth invested in the risky asset
(wt Kt = θ t pt ).
Optimal Portfolio Choice
Exponential utility
I Let’s re-write the problem in terms of the fraction wt of the initial wealth
invested in the risky asset: wt Kt = θ t pt
I In this case, we have Ct +1 = Kt rP + Kt
I Investors consume at date t + 1 the return of their portfolio
C t +1 = K t [ w t rt +1 + (1 w t ) rf ] + K t
1
E (exp V ) = exp µV + σ2V .
2
I Then...
Optimal Portfolio Choice
Exponential vs. Quadratic Utility
... Then if V = Kt rP + Kt ,
E [exp (γV )]
1 2
= exp (γ(µv γσ )
2 v
I Each curve plots the same utility level for di¤erent risk aversion γ.
I Higher γ implies that for a given σ, investors require higher mean return
to achieve same level of utility.
Next Time