Mixed Strategy Nash Equilibrium
Mixed Strategy Nash Equilibrium
player 2
player 1 1 −1 −1 1
−1 1 1 −1
player 2
player 1 6 6 2 7
7 2 0 0
6 + 2(1 − )
and if player 1 chooses , his payoff is
7 + 0(1 − )
Setting these payoffs equal to each other determines player
2’s MSNE mixing probability, = 23 .
Similarly, player 2 must receive the same payoff from
and . Setting these payoffs equal to each other deter-
mines player 1’s mixing probability, = 23 .
Notice that the firm with the higher cost is more likely
to enter! Mixed strategy NE often yields unintuitive
results, because mixing probabilities must make the other
player(s) indifferent.
Imagine the game being played over and over again, with
a new pair of players each time. It is very plausible that
the play will evolve into the lower cost firm always enter-
ing and the other firm always staying out. This is a pure
strategy NE.
If the play does not settle down into one of these patterns,
then both entering and not entering must be seen as
rational options. The higher cost players must be entering
with greater frequency than the lower cost players. If the
lower cost players entered at least as often as the higher
cost players, then someone is not being rational: either
the higher cost players should not be entering at all, or
the lower cost players should always be entering.
For games bigger than 2 × 2, then finding the MSNE is
more complicated. You need to determine which strate-
gies are being played with positive probability and which
ones are not being played. Here is Figure 11.2 from
the text (also discussed in Chapter 7). Player 1 decides
whether to serve to the opponent’s forehand side, the
center (at the opponent’s body), or the opponent’s back-
hand side. Player 2 must decide whether to protect his
forehand, his center, or his backhand.
player 2
0 5 2 3 2 3
player 1 2 3 0 5 3 2
5 0 3 2 2 3
Player 1’s payoff from is then 3(1 − ), and his payoff
from is 3 + 2(1 − ). Equating and solving for , we
have = 14 . Therefore, 2 = (0 14 34 ).