5 Game Incomplete
5 Game Incomplete
Masaki Miyashita
Chapter 5:
Games with Incomplete Information
Incomplete Information
• Players may not understand the partial/full details about the game in play.
• Each player may have private information that is not known to the others.
Example 1: Cournot Duopoly
• The rm’s optimal production level qi may depend not only on θi but also on their
expectation about θj .
• Each bidder has a private valuation θi for the good, drawn independently and
uniformly from [0,1] .
• The highest bidder wins the good and pays own bid bi .
• The bidder’s optimal strategy may depend not only on θi but also on their
expectation about θj .
Incomplete Information Game
Incomplete Information Game
• However, each individual type is private information; the player does not know
the realization of the opponent’s type.
Incomplete Information Game
• Ai is a set of actions.
• Θi is a set of of types.
• ui is a payoff function,
ui : A × Θi → ℝ where A = A1 × ⋯ × An .
• Timeline:
• The nature randomly draws a type pro le θ = (θ1, …, θn) according to the
prior distribution μ .
Remark. Complete information games correspond to the special case of this model,
where | Θi | = 1 for all players.
fi
Incomplete Information Game
• A strategy speci es a contingent plan detailing the player’s actions for each
type realization.
- We can also de ne a mixed strategy (though not used further): A mixed strategy is
any function σi : Θi → Δ(Ai) that assigns a lottery σi(θi) over actions to each type θi .
Remark: In incomplete information games, actions and pure strategies are distinct
concepts.
fi
fi
Incomplete Information Game
• Given any strategy pro le s = (s1, …, sn), the player i ’s (ex-ante) expected
payoff is de ned as follows:
• μ(θ) is the ex-ante probability that type pro le θ = (θ1, … . θn) realizes.
• s(θ) = (s1(θ1), …, sn(θn)) is the action pro le that results when type pro le θ
occurs, given each player j adopts strategy sj .
fi
fi
fi
fi
fi
Bayesian Nash Equilibrium
De nition.
ui(s*
i
, s*
−i
) ≥ ui(si, s*
−i
), ∀i ∈ N, ∀si ∈ Si .
fi
fi
Bayesian Nash Equilibrium
• Bayes’ rule:
μ(θi, θ−i)
∑
μ(θ−i ∣ θi) = where μ(θi) = μ(θi, θ′−i) .
μ(θi) θ′−i∈Θ−i
Proof.
Exercise. Derive the BNE in this Cournot duopoly under asymmetric information.
Compare the equilibrium output levels to the symmetric equilibrium output under
complete information. How does each rm’s expected pro t vary across ϵ?
fi
fi
fi
fi
Example 1: Cournot Duopoly
• We can derive BNE by solving the interim expected payoff maximization for each
possible type.
a − θi − [q*
j ]
q*
i
(θi) = .
2
𝔼
𝔼
𝔼
fi
Example 1: Cournot Duopoly
a − c − [q*
2]
q*
1
= .
2
• Firm 2’s output level depends on the marginal cost:
a − cH − q*
1 a − cL − q*
1
q* (c ) =
2 H
and q*(c ) =
2 L
.
2 2
• Consequently,
a−c ϵ
− if cH = c + ϵ,
{ a −3 c
a−c 3 2
q*
1
= and q*
2
= ϵ
3 + if cL = c − ϵ .
2
𝔼
𝔼
Example 1: Cournot Duopoly
• The expected pro t is higher for Firm 2 than for Firm 1 —- Why?
• The uncertainty in θ2 impacts the pro ts of both rms through the market price,
while θ2 is the private information of Firm 2.
• Firm 2 can adjust the production more ef ciently than Firm 1 in response to θ2.
fi
fi
fi
fi
Example 2: Auction
First-price Auction
b*
i
(θi) solves
Gain on winning
( )
max (θi − bi) ⋅ Pr bi > max b*
j
(θj) .
bi≥0 j≠i
Winning probability
Exercise. Derive the BNE of the rst-price auction. Also, calculate the equilibrium
expected revenue to the seller and compare it to that in the second-price auction
(recall that truth-telling is weakly dominant in 2PA).
fi
fi
First-price Auction
• Let us focus on a “symmetric” BNE, where every bidder adopts the same bidding
strategy f .
Verify: Show that there is a constant c > 0 such that f(θi) = cθi constitutes BNE.
First-price Auction
( )
Pr bi > max f(θj) = Pr (bi > f(θj), ∀j ≠ i)
j≠i
∏
= .
j≠i
( ) (c)
bi n−1
Pr bi > max f(θj) = .
j≠i
First-price Auction
• The bidder i’s payoff maximization problem:
(c)
n−1
bi
max (θi − bi) ⋅ .
bi≥0
• Taking FOC,
(c) (c)
n−1 n−2
bi (n − 1)(θi − bi) bi
− + = 0.
c
n−1
b*
i
= ⋅ θi .
n
• Setting c = (n − 1)/n, our initial guess is veri ed!
• Thus, in the symmetric BNE, each bidder reports (n − 1)/n times the true type.
fi
First-price Auction
[ i=1,…,n ] [ i=1,…,n ]
n−1
max f(θi) = ⋅ max θi .
n
⋆
n
• Since θi ∼i.i.d. Unif[0, 1], we can calculate that ⋆ = n+1
.
n−1
• Therefore, the seller’s revenue is n+1
.
• The revenue is increasing in n . In other words, the seller gains from having
additional participants in the auction.
n−1
• In fact, the expected revenue from 2PA is also n+1
. More generally, the
revenue equivalence theorem holds: under certain conditions, all
standard auction formats yield the same expected revenue.
𝔼
𝔼
Expected Value of Highest Type
Calculating ⋆.
• Let X = maxi=1,…,n θi .
1 1 1
n+1
x n
∫0 ∫0
n
[X] = x ⋅ fX(x)dx = n x dx = n ⋅ = .
n+1 n+1
0
• In 2PA, we have con rmed that the truth-telling strategy is optimal for each bidder
regardless of the behavior of the opponents.
• Given any value y ∈ [0,1], observe that Y < y occurs if and only if either of the
following occurs:
2. Exactly one θi exceeds y, which occurs with probability n(1 − y)y n−1 .
• Consequently,
• Differentiating FY , we get
∫0 ∫0 ( )
n−1 n
[Y ] = y ⋅ fY (y)dy = n(n − 1) y − y dy
[n n + 1] (n n + 1) n + 1
yn y n+1 1 1 n−1
= n(n − 1) − = n(n − 1) − = .
0
• Now, assume that the seller can set a reserve price r ∈ (0,1) .
• Otherwise, if at least one bidder bids above r , the highest bidder wins the
good and pays the higher of r or the highest bid among the losing bidders.
Exercise. Show that truth-telling is still weakly dominant. Then, calculate the
equilibrium expected revenue to the seller and discuss how it depends on r .
Speci cally, derive the seller-optimal reserver price r* for revenue maximization.
fi