Lecture 14
Lecture 14
Hideo Konishi
October 26, 2014
[Note] Please let me know if you …nd typos. I will update the
notes later in class.
1. Introduction
2. Exchange economy
3. Existence of Equilibrium
1
5. Production Economy
applications
– time
– location choice
– transportation cost
missing markets
– new products
– externalities, public goods
– asymmetric information: adverse selection, moral hazard
– absence of complete asset market
OLG model
ill-de…ned property right
distortions (tax, monopoly power)
8. 2 2 Production Economy
Shephard’s lemma,
factor price equalization theorem
the Stolper-Samuelson theorem
2
Math One-Minute (?) Lessons
1. [Closed sets] In each class (just the …rst part), I talk about math tools
we need in class.
3
Consider set X Rn . Set X is convex if x + (1 )y 2 X for
all x; y 2 X and all 2 [0; 1].
Consider nonempty sets X; Y Rn . A set X + Y = fz 2 Rn :
z = x + y for some x 2 X and y 2 Y g is an addition of sets X
and Y .
Similarly, X Y = fz = x y for some x 2 X and y 2 Y g is an
subtraction of Y from X.
Consider set X Rn . For all 0, set X = fz 2 Rn : z = x
for some x 2 Xg is a multiplication of set X and .
F Consider nonempty sets X; Y Rn . If X and Y are convex, X +Y
is convex.
F Consider set X Rn . If X is convex, then X is convex for all
0.
4. [Compactness]
4
F Consider nonempty sets X; Y Rn . If X and Y are compact,
X + Y is compact.
F Consider nonempty sets X; Y Rn . Even if X and Y are closed,
X + Y may not be closed.
5. [Continuity of functions]
6. [Continuity of correspondences]
5
A correspondence is nonempty-valued, i¤ (x) 6= ; for any
x 2 X. (This can be assured by the Weierstrass’s theorem.)
A correspondence is upper hemi-continuous, i¤ for any con-
vergent sequence fxk g1 1
k=1 ! x, any sequence fyk gk=1 with yk 2
(xk ) for each k = 1; 2; :::, and any convergent subsequence of
fyk g1 0 1
k=1 , fyk gk=1 ! y, we have y 2 (x). Note that graph of
an upper hemi-continuous is closed in X Y . An upper hemi-
continuous correspondence is one of generalizations of a continu-
ous function for multi-valued function world. A continuous func-
tion f has the following property: for any convergent sequence
fxk g1 1
k=1 ! x, a sequence ff (xk )gk=1 ! f (x). Since we are work-
ing on correspondence, we need to select an element of (xk ) for
each k.
A correspondence is lower hemi-continuous, i¤ for any x 2 X,
and any y 2 (x), and any convergent sequence fxk g1 k=1 ! x,
1
there is a sequence fyk gk=1 such that yk 2 (xk ) for each k =
1; 2; :::, and fyk g1
k=1 ! y.
6
7. [Berge’s maximum theorem]
8. [Convex-valuedness of correspondence]
7
A correspondence : Y X is convex-valued, i¤ for any y 2 Y ,
any x; x 2 (y), and any t 2 (0; 1), tx + (1 t)x0 2 (y) holds.
0
8
A set S 2 Rn is separated by a hyperplane Hp;c if either S
fz 2 Rn : p z cg (half-space below) or S fz 2 Rn : p z cg
(half-space above).
F [Separating hyperplane theorem] Suppose that X; Y Rn
are convex and X \ Y = ;. Then, there exists p 2 Rn nf0g and
c 2 R such that Hp;c separates X and Y .
9
1 Introduction
1. Organization Matters: Hideo Konishi 482, 2-1209, [email protected],
O¢ ce Hours just stop by or by appointment
2. General equilibrium theory in our …rst year micro sequence has two
aspects. Putting Marvin’s material together to analyze the entire econ-
omy is one thing, and regarding market equilibrium as a mechanism to
think about other possible allocation mechanisms, we can start think-
ing about theory of social choice and mechanism design.
3. General equilibrium does not mean that the analysis is very compli-
cated. The important thing is that the model is closed (with relevant
sectors and economic agents).
4. This course will make use of mathematics. However, the important
thing is to understand de…nitions and logics. The course is designed to
be more or less self-contained in math tools.
5. General equilibrium theory deals with resource allocation problem in
the whole economy. It provides foundations for market economy (the
…rst and second welfare theorems and the core convergence theorem).
Also general equilibrium theory is an important language to talk about
economy as a whole. For example, if you want to study macroeconomic
phenomenon, you need general equilibrium theory to describe the econ-
omy. If you are interested in e¤ects of government policies, you need
think about the e¤ects of both governmental expenditure and …nance
(taxes), since the government is a big player that has a signi…cant im-
pacts in both expenditure and …nancing. International trade (market
interaction between countries) and public economics (economics of the
government) need general equilibrium for sure.
6. Why is general equilibrium important? There are pitfalls in partial
equilibrium analysis. A trivial example is Pepsi and Coke markets.
The two demand curves interact with each other. If Pepsi marginal
cost exogenously goes down (by a technological innovation), then Pepsi
market price decreases. Then, Coke demand decreases, and Coke mar-
ket price goes down. Then, the Pepsi demand decreases and the Pepsi
market price goes down, etc. Clearly, a partial equilibrium analysis is
not su¢ cient.
10
7. Let me explain more substantial pitfalls of partial equilibrium analysis
by using a taxation analysis. Let’s …rst review undergraduate-level
partial equilibrium analysis. We use surplus analysis, so tax revenue
will be returned to consumers (in a lump sum manner).
8. producer tax:
and
(demand) = (supply)
Thus, the traded quantity is less, and the total surplus
9. consumption tax:
11. Consider ad valorem tax (tax rates in %: not tax rates in $). Suppose
that consumption of all goods face the same ad valorem tax rates,
and that the tax revenue is returned to consumers (assume identical
consumers). Then, what happens? Intuitively,
11
12. M RS = M RT is satis…ed q` = (1 + t)p` for all `. For all ` and `0
q` (1 + t)p` p`
M RS = = = = M RT
q `0 (1 + t)p`0 p `0
Thus, the allocation will not be a¤ected. This is totally contradic-
tory with partial equilibrium analysis. It is important to think about
interactions among markets.
12
More generally, given arbitrary ! i , draw pictures.
[Note on notations] In Mas-Colell’s book, both i and ` are sub-
scripts of consumption vector (xi = (xi1 ; :::; xi` ; :::; xiL )). However,
I will use the above notations so that you can see what each vari-
able represents (Imagine x12 in an economy with I = 2 and L = 2.
Isn’t x12 clearer than x12 ? The same?)
max pf (z) wz
z 0
given price vector (w; p), …rm’s labor demand is z(w; p), output
supply is q(w; p) and pro…t is
I=w L x1 + (w; p)
given price vector (w; p), consumer demand functions are x1 (w; p)
and x2 (w; p).
13
A (Walras or market) equilibrium price vector (w; p) requires
that demand equals supply in every market. (i) consumption mar-
ket: demand = supply
x2 (w; p) = q(w; p)
L x1 (w; p) = z(w; p)
14
an e¢ cient allocation is a Walras equilibrium under convex pref-
erence and technology and more hidden assumptions. "Under ap-
propriate conditions including convex preferences and technolo-
gies, every (Pareto) e¢ cient allocation is supported by a Wal-
ras equilibrium with appropriate transfers. The second welfare
theorem
15
PI PI PJ
(c) i=1xi = i=1 !i + j=1 y j (equilibrium in market of every
good `)
16. [Note] You may wonder why p y j is the pro…t of …rm j. As you will see,
in general equilibrium theory, an input of …rm j is regarded as negative
output of …rm j. Thus, we have
X
L
p yj = p` y`j
`=1
X X
= p` y`j p `0 ( y`j0 )
| {z }
`2Outputs `0 2Inputs
input amount
= (Revenue) (Cost)
17. How do we …t one consumer one …rm economy to this general frame-
work?
16
describe o¤er curves in two consumers’consumption sets
describe the market equilibrium
the Walras law
2 Exchange Economy
1. An exchange economy is a list (I; (X i ; ! i ; ui )i2I ) such that I =
f1; :::; Ig is a set of households (an abuse of notation), X i RL+ is
i i i i
a consumption set for all i, ! 2 X is i’s endowment, and u : X ! R
is i’s utility function. Here L is the number of goods in the economy
(…nite).
endowment
feasible allocations
budget sets (include infeasible allocations)
o¤er curves and net demand and supply: O¤er curve for i 2 I:
xi = xi (p; p ! i ).
market equilibrium
3. A feasible allocation isPa list x P= (xi )i2I = (x1 ; :::; xI ) such that
xi 2 X i for all i 2 I and i2I xi = i2I ! i , where xi = (xi1 ; :::; xiL ).
5. Draw an Edgeworth box with o¤er curves again. O¤er curve for i 2 I:
xi = xi (p; p ! i ). There are substitution e¤ect and income e¤ect: income
e¤ect depends on two things — (i) is it a normal good or an inferior
good, and (ii) does consumer i’s income increase or decrease by the
17
price change. Recall labor supply. Slutsky equation:
dxi @xi @xi
= + ! i`
dp` @p` @W i
@xi @xi i @x
i
= xi` + ! `
@p` u=const @W i @W i
| {z }
Slutsky equation
i
@x @xi
= (xi` ! i` )
@p` u=const
| {z } @W i
net demand
multiple equilibria
unique equilibrium
monotonicity of preferences
convex preferences
i i
6. Cobb-Douglass example: ui (xi1 ; xi2 ) = (xi1 ) 1 (xi2 ) 2 with i
1+
i
2 = 1 for
i = 1; 2. In Marvin’s class, you learned
i i
`W
xi` (p; W i ) = :
p`
Thus, it is easy to see
@xi` i
`W
i
@xi`
= < 0 and = 0:
@p` (p` )2 @p`0
dxi1 dxi2
= 0 and > 0:
dp1 dp1
18
i (p !i )
However, in general, what we have is xi` (p; W i ) = `
p`
. Thus,
@xi` i
` (p` !i) i i
`!`
= +
@p` (p` )2 p`
and
P i
P
@xi` i
`
i
`0 2L p`0 ! `0
i i
`!` ` `0 6=` p`0 ! i`0 @xi`0 i i
`0 ! `
= + = 0 and = 0:
@p` (p` )2 p` (p` )2 @p` p`
1
2 (p !1) 2
2 (p !2)
z2 (p) = ! 12 + ! 22 = 0:
p2 p2
Let us calculate the value of excess demand:
p1 z1 (p) + p2 z2 (p)
= 11 (p ! 1 ) p1 ! 11 + 21 (p ! 2 ) p1 ! 21 + 1
2 (p !1) p2 ! 12 + 2
2 (p !2) p2 ! 22
= p ! 1 + p ! 2 p ! 1 p ! 2 = 0:
19
We can focus on one market, and demand function is homogeneous
of degree zero (even if all prices are doubled, demand does not
change — since the budget constraint is not a¤ected by that).
Let’s say p2 = 1, and focus on market 1.
1
1 (p !1) 2
1 (p !2)
z1 (p) = ! 11 + ! 21
p1 p1
1 1 1 2 2
1 (p1 ! 1 + ! 2 ) 1 (p1 ! 1 + ! 22 )
= ! 11 + ! 21
p1 p1
= 0
10. Utility function ui satis…es local nonsatiation if and only if for all
xi 2 X i and all > 0, there exists x~i 2 X i with jxi x~i j < such that
ui (~
xi ) > ui (xi ).
20
11. Utility function ui satis…es (weak) monotonicity if and only if for
all xi 2 X i and all x~i 2 X i with x~ii > xii for all i = 1; :::; L (~
xi xi ),
ui (~
xi ) > ui (xi ) holds.
12. Note that the proof of the …rst welfare theorem basically requires noth-
ing but local nonsatiation. It does not require:
production is included
time dimension is included
uncertainty is included
multiple locations are included
14. But also remember that it does not talk about existence of equilibrium.
The statement of the theorem is "If there is an equilibrium, it must be
Pareto-e¢ ceint."
21
15. Moreover, there are hidden assumptions:
16. The Pareto (e¢ cient) set in the Edgeworth economy is found in the
following manner.
max
1 1
u1 (x11 ; x12 ) s:t: u2 (x21 ; x22 ) = u2
x1 ;x2
x11 + x21 = ! 1
x12 + x22 = ! 2
x11 + x21 = ! 1
x12 + x22 = ! 2
From these conditions, the …rst welfare theorem is trivial, because mar-
ket equilibrium requires
u11 u21 p1
1
= 2
=
u2 u2 p2
22
and feasibility constraints
x11 + x21 = ! 1
x12 + x22 = ! 2 :
u11 1 1
1 x2
1 1
1 x2
2 2
1 x2
2 2
1 x2 u21
= = = = =
u12 1 1
2 x1 (1 1 1
1 )x1 (1 2 2
1 )x1
2 2
2 x1 u22
Substituting
x21 = ! 1 x11
x22 = ! 2 x12
into the MRS-equating condition, we can write x12 with x11 only.
x11 (1 1
1 ) 2
1
! 1 x11 1
(1 2
)
x12 =
1 1
!2:
x11 (1 1
1 ) 2
1
1+ ! 1 x11 1
1 (1 2
1 )
18. Leontief preference ui (xi1 ; xi2 ) = minfxi1 ; xi2 g and Edgeworth boxes.
Pareto set, market equilibrium.
19. Linear preference ui (xi1 ; xi2 ) = ai1 xi1 +ai2 xi2 and Edgeworth boxes. Pareto
set, market equilibrium.
3 Existence of Equilibrium
1. We will talk a bit about the existence of equilibrium. Before that let
us de…ne quasi-concave utility. Utility function ui is quasi-concave, if
and only if for all xi 2 X i , the better set B(xi ) fxi0 2 X i : ui (xi0 )
ui (xi )g is convex.
23
Theorem 2 Suppose that ui is continuous and quasi-concave, and sat-
is…es weak monotonicity, and that X i RL+ is closed and convex,
! i 2 int(X i ) hold for all i 2 I. Then, there exists a market equi-
librium.
24
This is about nonexistence of cheaper point. If there is no cheaper
point, the budget correspondence may fail to satisfy continuity. This is
the reason that type (ii) failure occurred in 2. With the cheaper point
assumption, we can show that individual demand is nonempty-valued
and upper hemicontinuous. Now, type (i) failure comes to play if pref-
erences are not convex (utility function is not quasi-concave). With
quasi-concavity, all conditions of Kakutani’s theorem are met on the
excess demand mapping.
9. Now, we need to think about how price is determined. Gale and Nikaido
had a brilliant idea to introduce a hypothetical auctioneer who deter-
mines market price from excess demand vector. In order to explain
their idea, let us state the Walras law.
max
i i
ui (xi ) s:t: p xi p !i
x 2X
That is, the value of consumer i’s optimal consumption bundle is less
than or equal to the one of her endowment. Summing them up, we
have X X
p xi (p) p !i
i2I i2I
The Walras law has two versions: strong and weak ones. The
above is weak one (inequality). If l.n.s. is assumed, then the
above inequality becomes equality. This is the strong version. The
strong version has an important implication. Due to the Walras
law, one freedom is lost. As a result, if L 1 markets clear, then
the last Lth market also clears.
11. This simple observation (the Walras law) plays an important role in
…nding the market equilibrium. Let us introduce a hypothetical player
— an auctioneer — who sets prices in order to maximize the value of
excess demand z.
(z) arg max p z
p2 L
25
This arti…cial mapping together with the Walras law proves the exis-
tence of market equilibrium. Note that mapping is nonempty-valued
and u.h.c. since function p z is continuous and set L is compact.
Moreover, function p z is quasi-concave thus is convex-valued, too.
(See math one-minute lectures.) The reason why we use such an auc-
tioneer is revealed in 16 below.
This mapping has special nature. For each z, ` (z) > 0 can
occur only for `s such that z` z`0 for all `0 = 1; :::; L. That is,
(z) almost always takes the form of (z) = (0; :::; 0; 1; 0; :::; 0).
However, if z = 0 holds, (z) = , and a price vector p that is
consistent with z(p) = 0 will be a …xed point.
12. [The …xed point mapping] Let Z RL be the set of possible excess
demand vectors. The …xed point mapping : L Z L
Z
L L
is the Cartesian product of mappings : Z and z : Z
( = z):
p p (z )
2 = ;
z z z(p )
or 0 1 0 1
p1 1 (z )
B .. C B .. C
B . C B . C
B C B C
B pL C B L (z ) C
B C B
2 C
B z1 C B z1 (p ) C
B . C B .. C
@ .. A @ . A
zL zL (p )
26
under some p an element outside of X i is chosen, then such p cannot
be aP
part of any
P …xed point,
P so iwe can ignore such possibility.) Since
z = i2I z i = i2I ! i i2I x ,
( )
X X
Z= X^i !i
i2I i2I
27
17. With weak monotonicity, z = 0 (budget is exhausted). This proves
the existence of market equilibrium.
28
L
– we want to …nd a selection f : A !
R R+ of demand
R correspon-
L
dence '(p; ) : A R+ such that A f d = A !d
[Liapunov’s theorem] If space of consumers is atomless (for all
S AR with (S) > 0, there exists T S with 0 < (T ) < (S)),
then A '(p; a)d RL+ is convex.
By Liapunov’s theorem, convex-valuedness of demand correspon-
dence is assured in an atomless economy.
Aumann (1966, Econometrica) In atomless economies, there exists
a market equilibrium if U is the space of continuous and strictly
monotonic utilities (with measurability restrictions). Later, Schmei-
dler weakened the restriction to local nonsatiation.
Nonconvex consumption set (location- or job-choice) is a bit harder
to deal with, but it is possible to apply the same method.
3. Draw a picture for the …rst welfare theorem. Show that the market
equilibrium is in the core.
29
Theorem 3 Suppose that for all i 2 I, ui satis…es local nonsatiation.
Then, in every market equilibrium (p; x), the realized allocation x is in
the core.
6. Replica economy (core convergence: Debreu and Scarf 1963 IER: simple
case in pictures). An N -replica of an exchange economy (I; (X i ; ! i ; ui )i2I )
is an exchange economy with each type i 2 I having N 2 consumers.
An allocation for N -replica economy is x = (x11 ; :::; x1N ; :::; xi1 ; :::; xiN ; ::::; xI1 ; :::; xIN ) 2
RL I N .
4.2 Uniqueness
1. First, I mention that it is fruitless to try to show the uniqueness
of Walras equilibrium if there are multiple types of consumers. Of
course, using utility functions in a restrictive functional form (say,
Cobb-Douglass), we can sometimes show uniqueness of equilibrium.
However, in general, we cannot hope such a well-behaved economy. An
example in an Edgeworth economy su¢ ces (see …gure). This and next
subsection mainly follow Varian’s text book.
30
2. Moreover, there is a theorem by Sonnenschein, Mantel and Debreu. It
in e¤ect says that any continuous function with the Walras law prop-
erty (p z(p) = 0 for all p) can be constructed by aggregating some
L consumers’ excess demand functions. That is, an aggregate excess
demand function can take any form, as a result, it is hopeless to achieve
uniqueness of equilibrium in a strict sense.
Proof. Suppose that there are two equilibria with p0 6= p for any
p0
> 0. Since p 0 holds, we can de…ne m = max p ` 6= 0. By
`
homogeneity of degree zero, we have z(mp ) = 0. Thus, p0 mp
0 0
with p 6= mp and p` = mp` for at least one commodity `. Note
z` (mp ) = z` (p0 ) = 0. Increase price of commodity `0 with p0`0 < mp`0
one by one to mp`0 . By gross substitution, z` (mp ) > z` (p0 ) = 0 holds.
This is a contradiction.
31
See …gures. Notice that if @z@p1 (p)
1
< 0 at all equilibrium price vectors p ,
then the equilibrium is unique. This argument can be extended to many
commodity case, though this theory requires sophisticated mathematics
(di¤erential topology).
has positive determinant at all equilibria, then there is only one equi-
librium.
Remark 6 OK, looks nice, but what does it mean? Let us use Slutsky
equation:
!
X X
Dz(p) = Dp xi (p ; ui ) u=const + DW xi (p; p !) (xi (p) ! i )
i2I i2I
The …rst term is the (negative) Slutsky matrix, so it has positive de-
terminant. Thus, you can see that the potential issue is always income
e¤ects. As long as substitution e¤ect is dominant for all price vector,
there is a unique equilibrium. However, as I mentioned before, it is too
much to ask.
4.3 Stability
1. Again, the interest is limited. Late 50s, many researchers were trying to
show that there is a stable equilibrium in general. Unfortunately, Scarf
(1960 IER) presented a three-person-three-good counter example, so
there was no hope in a strict sense. But Scarf’s example is quite arti…-
cial, and three people have very di¤erent preferences and endowments.
Thus, his example does not mean that there is no stable equilibrium in
a practical sense.
32
2. Here, we consider a special price adjustment mechanism (that is gener-
alizable), and discuss stability of equilibrium. We will impose weak ax-
iom of revealed preference to market demand (this is actually nonsense
to extend rational behavior for individuals to the aggregated market
behavior, but it works well: equilibrium is essentially unique in this
case, too: see Mas-Colell et al.). Let us consider the following ad-
justment rule p_ = z(p). That is, the price of commodity with excess
demand supply) goes up (down). We need to impose the Walras law
p z(p) = 0 for all p. This system has a very convenient property.
Check the Euclidean norm of price vector change over time (I omit
square root, since it is irrelevant).
!
d X X
(p` (t))2 = 2p` (t)p_` (t) = 2p z(p) = 0
dt `2L `2L
33
have
dV (p) X
= 2 (p` p` ) p_` (t)
dt `2L
X
= 2 (p` p` ) z` (p)
`2L
= 2p z(p) < 0
5 Production Economy
1. Unfortunately, in public economics, almost always production economy.
A production economy is a list (I; J; (X i ; ! i ; ( ij )j2J ; ui )i2I ; (Y j )j2J ),
where J is the set of …rms, ij is the pro…t claim that consumer i owns
P
for …rm j ( i2I ij = 1 for all j 2 J), and Y j RL is the production
set available for …rm j.
34
6. Instead of market equilibrium, Mas-Colell’s book uses "quasi-equilibrium"
which replaces a:(ii) with P
xi ) > ui (xi ) implies p x~i p ! i + j2J ij p y j ".
"a:(ii0 ) ui (~
This condition is of course a weaker one than a:(ii), and a quasi-
equilibrium is not necessarily a market equilibrium (example). The rea-
son why this concept is introduced is to avoid the problem of "! i 2 X i
while ! i 2
= int(X i )." This is an important yet a technical issue, so I do
not go into details.
35
P ij
p xi = p ! i + j2J p y j holds for all i 2 I. Thus, we have
X X
p x~i > p xi
i2I i2I
X XX
ij
= p !i + p yj
i2I i2I j2J
X X
= p !i + p yj :
i2I j2J
P P P
By the de…nition of feasibility, we have i2I x~i = i2I ! i + j2J y~j ,
P P P
thus p ~i = p
i2I x
i
i2I ! + p ~j . From the above inequality,
j2J y
we conclude
X X X X
p !i + p y~j > p !i + p yj ;
i2I j2J i2I j2J
P P
or p ~j > p
j2J y
j
j2J y . This contradicts with …rms’pro…t maxi-
mization (at least one …rm is not maximizing pro…t at y j 2 Y j . Hence,
there cannot be a feasible allocation that Pareto-dominates a market
equilibrium allocation.
10. Remarks on the core: the core may be empty if DRS. Moreover, it
can be empty if IRS (Scarf). Often, we assume CRS. If you wish, you
can de…ne the core, and prove that a market equilibrium is in the core
under CRS. You can prove the core equivalence under the CRS and
atomless consumer assumptions.
12. The core under publicly available technology (production set) Y . Let
S I be a (nonempty) subgroup of consumers. A feasible allocation P
i i i i
for
P S is a list (x )i2S such that x 2 X for all i 2 S and i2S x 2
i
i2S ! + Y . As in the exchange economy, a core allocation is a
feasible allocation x such that for all (nonempty) subgroup of consumers
S I, there is no feasible allocation for S, (~ xi )i2S , such that (i) ui (~
xi )
ui (xi ) for all i 2 S, and (ii) ui (~xi ) > ui (xi ) for some i 2 S. The set of
all core allocations is called the core.
36
13. Prove that market equilibrium is in the core under CRS technology.
37
(b) for all j 2 J and all y~j 2 Y j , py j p~y j holds
P i
P i
P j
(c) i2I W = p i2I ! + j2J p y
38
18. Importance of convexity: quasi-concave utility, convex technology, and
convex consumption set. We can dispense convexity by assuming a
continuum of consumers with additional assumptions.
19. In the classical economics, this theorem justi…es market equilibrium op-
timistically: as long as a proper redistribution (by lump sum transfers)
is done, then any Pareto e¢ cient allocation is supportable. However,
it requires tremendous amount of information.
max u1 (x1 )
(x;y)2RLI
+ RLI
39
subject to
ui (xi ) ui for all i = 2; :::; I
P i
P i
P j
i2I x` i2I ! ` + j2J y` for all ` = 1; :::; L
F j (y j ) 0 for all j = 1; :::; J
The Lagrangian function is
L(x; y; ; ; )
!
X X X X X X
= i i i
(u (x ) ui ) + ` ! i` + y`j xi` j
F j (y j );
i2I `2L i2I j2J i2I j2J
1
where = 1 and u1 = 0. If interior solutions, we have for all i; i0 ; `; `0 ; j;
and j 0
0
i ui` ui` i0
M RS`` 0 =
i
= i0 = M RS``0
u `0 u `0
0
j F`j F`j j0
M RT S`` 0 = j = j 0 = M RT S`` 0
F`0 F`0
i ui` F`j j
M RS`` 0 = = j = M RT S``0 :
ui`0 F`0
22. Now, recall consumer’s optimization problem
X
i i
max
i
u (x ) s:t: p` xi` Wi
x
`2L
40
6 G.E. Theory: Scope of Applications and
Market Failures
1. The …rst and second welfare theorems are strong supports for mar-
ket mechanism. As we will see, we can allow for uncertainty, and we
can introduce time dimension (macro economics). We can also allow
location/job choice as well (nonconvex consumption sets with a large
number of consumers). However, we need to keep limitations of the
…rst welfare theorem in our mind.
41
facing expected price vectors (p(t))1 1
t=0 with interest rates (r(t))t=0 ,
L
where p(t) 2 R+ . Then, this consumer is actually facing price
p(t))1
vector (~ t=0 where
Y
t 1
1
p~(t) = p(t):
t0 =0
1 + r(t)
p(t))1
With price vector (~ 1
t=0 , consumer maximizes her utility U ((x(t))t=0 ).
So, besides in…nite dimension problem, everything is the same,
and we can talk about general equilibrium over time (although
I do not touch producer side: there is special structure of pro-
duction technology due to time. In many applications including
macroeconomics, we assume the following utility function:
X
1
t
U ((x(t))1
t=0 ) = u(x(t));
t=0
You can use Roy’s identity to solve the problem. (See later sec-
tion: optimal taxation.) This is exactly the same as consumers’
behavior in the standard macroeconomics.
42
2. Although the statement and the proof of the …rst welfare theorem are
very simple, there are hidden assumptions such as complete market
(there is market for each commodity), property rights are well-de…ned,
there is no distortions such as taxes and monopoly power. There is
another subtle violation for the proof of the …rst welfare theorem due
to incomparable summations of values of consumption vectors among
all market participants (OLG model).
3. First, missing markets. There are many reasons for missing markets.
43
The population growth rate exceeds the market interest rate. Recall
the …rst part of the proof:
"Suppose not. Then, there exists another feasible allocation x~ such
that (i) ui (~
xi ) ui (xi ) for all i 2 I, and (ii) ui (~
xi ) > ui (xi ) for some
i 2 I. By the de…nition of market equilibrium, we have
X X
p x~i > p xi
i2I i2I
since (i) implies p x~i p xi and (ii) implies p x~i > p xi ."
The problem is displayed inequality. With a higher population growth
rate than discounting (interest rates), the summations of both sides
blow up to in…nity (future weights become heavier and heavier). We
cannot compare in…nity with in…nity. This is the intuitive reason that
the …rst welfare theorem fails.
44
In order to describe uncertainty, we introduce state of the world.
Dependent on state of the world, endowments and/or preferences (and
technology in production economy) can change.
2. Let S = f1; :::; Sg be the set of states of the world. Consumer i has
state-dependent endowment
45
can consume ! i`s + xi`s units of commodity ` if state s realizes. Arrow-
Debreu equilibrium assumes the existence of all such state-contingent
markets for all commodities. This market system is called a complete
market system.
6. Let us consider a simple two consumer two state example with one
physical commodity in each state (say money). You can regard this as
a large market with two types of consumers. Consumer i = 1; 2 has
endowments ! 1 = (! 11 ; ! 12 ) and ! 2 = (! 21 ; ! 22 ), Bernoulli utilities ui (xis )
that are common to all states s = 1; 2, and subjective probabilities
( i1 ; i2 ). Note that expected utility of consumer i is written as
U i (xi1 ; xi2 ) = i i i
1 u (x1 ) + i i i
2 u (x2 );
i @U i =@xi1 i
1
M RS21 = = :
@U i =@xi2 xi1 =xi2
i
2
46
(a) ! 1 = (1; 0), ! 2 = (0; 1), and 1 = 2 . The contract curve (the
Pareto set) is a straight 45 degree line.
(b) ! 1 = (1; 0), ! 2 = (0; 1), and 1 1
1= 2 < 2 2
1= 2. Then, Pareto set is
above the 45 degree line.
(c) ! 1 = (2; 0), ! 2 = (0; 1), and 1
= 2
. The Pareto set is between
the two 45 degree line.
7. So, the market equilibrium is again e¢ cient, but here there is a big as-
sumption: all L S markets exist. If S is a large number, it is a quite
demanding assumption. Do we really need so many markets to obtain
nice results? Arrow observed that if there is a contingent commodity,
then it may be su¢ cient to replicate the Arrow-Debreu equilibrium
when sequential trade is possible. The idea is as follows. There is a
commodity that is traded as state-contingent commodity in period 0
(before state realizes), and in each state of period 1, other commod-
ity markets open after the state-contingent commodity’s transfer has
been made. As long as consumers have rational expectations (state-
dependent perfect foresightedness), such an equilibrium replicates the
Arrow-Debreu equilibrium with only. This equilibrium concept is called
Radner’s rational expectation equilibrium.
Note that zsi can take either sign. Actually, zsi < ! i1s can occur (i sells
commodity 1 in state s more than her endowment amount in state s).
This case is called short selling — if state s occurs, consumer i needs
to purchase commodity 1 to pay back after using up all commodity 1
47
endowment.
A Radner (rational expectation) equilibrium is a list of contin-
gent commodity price vector q = (q1 ; :::; qS ) 2 RS , spot price vector
(p1 ; :::; pS ) 2 RLS , trading plan z i = (z1i ; :::; zSi ) 2 RS , and spot mar-
ket consumption plan xi = (xi1 ; :::; xiS ) 2 RLS + , such
i i
Pthat i(i) (z ; x )
solves
P the above
P maximization problem, and (ii) i2I z = 0 and
i i
i2I xs = i2I ! s for all s 2 S.
It is not hard to see that the set of Arrow-Debreu equilibrium alloca-
tions is equivalent to the one of Radner equilibrium allocations.
11. Suppose that there are K di¤erent assets. Each unit of asset k =
1; :::; K is a vector rk = (r1k ; :::; rsk ; :::; rSk ). A vector of (net) trades
of assets (portfolio) and a price vector at t = 0 are z i = (z1i ; :::; zK i
)2
K K
R and q = (q1 ; :::; qK ) 2 R , respectively. Consumer i’s optimization
48
problem is
P i
i (i) k2K qk zk 0 P
max U (xi1 ; :::; xiS ) s:t:
(xi1 ;:::;xiS )2RLS
+
(ii) ps xs ps ! is + k2K p1s zki rsk for all s
i
(z1i ;:::;zS
i )2RS
49
whatever z i = (z1i ; z2i ) is chosen, consumer i must consume ! i1 if state 1
realizes. This cannot be an Arrow-Debreu equilibrium in general. The
problem is that the space of possible trades is just ! i + f0g R2 , and
consumer i’s budget set is B i (q1 ; q2 ) = f(xi1 ; xi2 ; xi3 ) 2 R3+ : xi1 = ! i1 and
q2 xi2 + q3 xi3 q2 ! i2 + q3 ! i3 g. Thus, although the consumption space is
three dimensional, the trading space is two dimensional, and the budget
line is only one dimensional line. What do we learn from this exam-
ple? In order to replicate the Arrow-Debreu equilibrium, we need full
dimensions (S-dimensions) need to be spanned by asset return vectors
(complete asset market). If this to happen, the Radner equilib-
rium is again equivalent to the Arrow-Debreu equilibrium. Otherwise,
Radner equilibrium is not necessarily e¢ cient (incomplete market).
13. Note that asset return vectors themselves are not important. The im-
portant thing is the space spanned by asset return vectors. This fact
has an implication to option plans. For example, consider the case
where only one asset is available r1 = (4; 3; 2; 1). With unique as-
set, consumers cannot buy or sell this asset (cannot be traded with
only one asset). However, consider strike options with strike prices
3:5, 2:5, and 1:5. Then, these options create assets r2 = (0:5; 0; 0; 0),
r3 = (1:5; 0:5; 0; 0), and r4 = (2:5; 1:5; 0:5; 0). These four asset return
vectors span the entire space. This shows that option plans can im-
prove e¢ ciency of the market by creating complete market. Also note
that trading volume can be unbounded in asset market. if there are
limitations, the entire space may not be spanned.
2. Let us start with the following situation: There are J …rms, and each
…rm j produces commodity j directly from L factors. Prices of com-
modities are described by p = (p1 ; :::; pJ ), and factor prices are de-
scribed by w = (w1 ; :::; wL ). production technology is described by a
50
concave production function
q j = f j (z j )
Each …rm’s optimization problem is
max
j
pj f j (z j ) w zj ;
z
The Lagrangian is
!
X X
L= pj f j (z j ) w^ z`j z` ;
j2J j2J
where w^ = (w
^1 ; :::; w^L ) is Lagrangian multiplier vector that is the same
as shadow price vector of factors. The f.o.c.s are: for all ` = 1; :::; L,
@f j (z j )
pj = w^` ;
@z`j
51
and X
z` = z`j :
j2J
max
j
pj f j (z j ) w z j = max
j
pj q j C j (w; q j ) ;
z q
where C j (w; q j ) is …rm j’s cost function. Firm j’s pro…t maximization
condition is
@C j (w; q j )
pj = :
@q j
Now, general equilibrium touch. Assume that there is an aggregate
factor endowment vector z = (z1 ; :::; zL ). In the equilibrium, the sum
of factor demand and factor endowment are equated.
X X @C j (w; q j )
z` = z`j =
j2J j2J
@w`
C j (w; q j ) = q j cj (w);
where (aj1 (w); aj2 (w)) is …rm j’s cost-minimizing input combination to
produce one unit of output. As you remember we can draw an iso-
quant curve in the space of (z1j ; z2j ), but we can draw a dual of that:
52
iso-cost curve in the space of (w1 ; w2 ). Firm j’s iso-cost curve is de…ned
in the following manner:
Note that the set (w1 ; w2 ) 2 R2+ : cj (w) c is convex, since cost
function is concave in w. By Shephard’s lemma, vector (aj1 (w); aj2 (w)) is
orthogonal to iso-cost curve at each point on the iso-cost curve. Clearly,
as w1 =w2 increases, aj1 (w)=aj2 (w) decreases.
where (a11 ; a12 ) and (a21 ; a22 ) are found from iso-quant curve for unit pro-
duction. (Note that in exchange economy, if utility functions are ho-
mothetic, the Pareto set and utility possibility frontier can be derived
in the same way.)
p1 = c1 (w1 ; w2 )
p2 = c2 (w1 ; w2 )
53
Thus, equilibrium factor prices are determined as the intersection point
of iso-cost curves in (w1 ; w2 )-space. Once w = (w1 ; w2 ) is determined,
we can see how much each factor is used in production of each com-
modity by evaluating (a11 (w ); a12 (w )) and (a21 (w ); a22 (w )) (these are
orthogonal to iso-cost curves) at the intersection point, and write them
in the (factor market) Edgeworth box. The intersection of two rays in
the box is the factor market equilibrium point:
(z11 ; z21 ) = q 1 (a11 (w ); a12 (w ))
(z12 ; z22 ) = q 2 (a21 (w ); a22 (w ))
From here, we can see q = (q 1 ; q 2 ). Since q maximizes the value
of the country under p = (p1 ; p2 ), p is orthogonal to the production
possibility frontier at q .
9. Note that given constant-returns-to-scale technology and interior solu-
tion, factor price w = (w1 ; w2 ) is solely determined by p = (p1 ; p2 ) as
the intersection point of two iso-cost curves. Thus, total endowment of
factors in a country z = (z1 ; z2 ) does not play any role in determining
the factor prices. This has an important implication in the theory of in-
ternational trade. As long as technology exhibits CRS and equilibrium
is interior solution (no specialization occurs), countries with the same
technologies have the same factor prices no matter what factor endow-
ment vectors they have. This is called a factor-price equalization
theorem.
54
a partial derivative with respect to price of good i. Good 0 denotes
leisure consumption.
3. First consumer theory you learned in Marvin’s class. Suppose that
consumer price vector is q = (q 0 ; q 1 ; q 2 ) while producer price is p =
(p0 ; p1 ; p2 ). These price vector can be di¤erent by commodity tax or
monopoly pricing. Then, production possibility frontier and indi¤er-
ence curve has intersections. You can measure economic distortions by
using the idea of compensating and/or equivalent variations. The cost
of distortions measured by producer price p is called excess burdens
(waste of resources).
4. Consider a one-consumer economy with leisure and two commodities
(1 and 2), in which all commodities are produced by using labor only
at …xed coe¢ cients p1 > 0 and p2 > 0, respectively. Taking leisure as
the numeraire, the commodity prices are …xed at p = (1; p1 ; p2 ), and
the production set is a hyperplane p y = 0. Now, we consider the
situation where the government needs to raise a certain …xed amount
of revenue T > 0 (measured by labor). No more lump sum transfers,
and the tax revenues are used for useful purposes.
X
2
t` p` x` = T:
`=0
5. One big question is if we can impose a uniform tax on all goods t > 0. If
it can be done, a uniform taxation is not distortionary, since consumer’s
budget constraint is
X
2 X
2
` `
qx = (1 + t)p` x` = ! 0 ;
`=0 `=0
55
6. However, note that ! 0 is leisure endowment. In order to impose tax
on all commodities, the government need to check how much has been
"consumed" (not bought). In particular, leisure consumption taxation
is hard to implement. Do you wonder if labor income tax works as
leisure consumption taxation? Not at all. What is the price of leisure?
It is an opportunity cost of leisure consumption — wage rate. If labor
income tax is charged, then an after tax wage rate is lower than the
market wage rate. This is a subsidy for leisure consumption. If uniform
commodity tax is charged, consumer should face higher wage rate q 0 =
(1 + t)p0 . Moreover, tax base is also di¤erent, which can be seen as
follows: Let x and x be gross and net consumption vectors. Labor
supply is (! 0 x0 ), and leisure consumption is x0 , where commodity
0 is leisure here, and x0 is the gross leisure consumption. Commodity
taxes are paid for market transaction normally. So, net consumption
x` ! ` should be the tax base. Let x` x` ! ` for all ` = 0; 1; 2.
Utility function u(x) is also translated to u(x) = u(x + !). From this
budget constraint, it is now clear that even if uniform commodity tax
is imposed, the tax revenue will be simply zero.
X
2 X
2
t ` ` t X ` `
2
` `
tp x = qx = q x = 0:
`=0 `=0
1+t 1 + t `=0
That is, given that the government needs to raise revenue T , it has to
introduce tax distortions to the economy.
8. Now, we start the analysis by Corlett and Hague (1953). Corlett and
Hague (1953) considered the following problem. Suppose that there
is uniform commodity tax when leisure is untaxed (this is equivalent
56
to wage income tax system since relative price only matters). The
question they ask is — Is it better to introduce additional distortion?
Should some commodity bear higher tax rate than other commodities?
The smallest number of goods needed is 3 including leisure.
9. From 4, we know that consumers’ utility maximization is described
by the dual problem (expenditure minimization), and the consumers’
budget is zero in net term. Thus, expenditure to obtain utility u is zero
in equilibrium:
E(q; u) = 0:
The government’s budget constraint is
X
2
t` q ` x` (q; u) = T:
`=0
10. Now, we consider a tax reform. We change t1 , but doing so alone will
not satisfy the resource constraint. Thus, we need to adjust the other
commodity 2’s tax rate. Totally di¤erentiating the system of equations,
we have
Eu x2 p2 du x1 p1
= dt1 ;
p xu p x2 p2 dt2 p x1 p1
@x `
where xk = (x0k ; x1k ; x2k ) and x`k = @q k for all `; k = 0; 1; 2. The wel-
x1 p1 x2 p2 Eu x2 p2
N= and D = :
p x1 p1 p x2 p2 p xu p x2 p2
57
11. What is the sign of D? Consider the e¤ect of changing t2 adjusting tax
revenue T . This can be seen from the following comparative statics:
Eu 0 du x2 p2
= dt2
p xu 1 dT p x2 p2
Thus, we have
dT D
= :
dt 2 Eu
This implies that D < 0 is more likely (non-La¤er situation). Note
that La¤er situation occurs at the …rst intersection (the one closer to
the origin) of the o¤er curve and the production possibility frontier.
du
12. How about N ? Given that D is negative, N < 0 () dt1
> 0.
p x1 p1 p x2 p2
N = x1 p1 x2 p2 :
x1 p1 x2 p2
p x1 p1
The term x1 p1
describes how much additional resource is needed ( @p x(q(t);u)
@t1
)
1 1 1
in order to raise one additional unit of tax revenue ( @(t @tp1x ) ). Thus,
du p x2 p2 p x1 p1
> 0 () N < 0 () >
dt1 x2 p2 x1 p1
p x2 p x1
() 2
> ;
x x1
that is, if raising tax of commodity 1 is less wasteful than raising tax
on commodity 2, this tax reform is welfare-improving.
13. We can manipulate the formula a bit.
P2 ` `
p xk `=0 p xk
=
xk k
P2 x ` k
`=0 p x`
=
xk
X q ` xk
2
1
`
=
`=0
1 + t` xk
X
2
1 k
= `;
`=0
1 + t`
58
where xk` = x`k (symmetry of substitution matrix of Hicksian demand),
k q ` xk`
` = xk is compensated demand cross elasticity. Note that we have
X
2 X
2
q ` xk 1 X ` k
2
k `
` = = k q x` = 0:
`=0 `=0
xk x `=0
p xk k
Using the above, we can rewrite xk
by eliminating own price e¤ect k:
p xk X2
1 k
k
= `
x `=0
1 + t`
X
2
1 1 X
2
k k
= ` `
`=0
1 + t` 1 + tk `=0
X
2
1 1 k
= `
`=0
1 + t` 1 + tk
X2
tk t` k
= `
`=0
1 + tk 1 + t`
X2
k ` k
= `;
`=0
` ` t 1 1
where = 1+t ` . The third line to the fourth line: note 1+t` 1+tk
=
tk t` tk t`
(1+t` )(1+tk )
= 1+tk 1+t `:
p x2 p x1 X2 X
2
2 ` 2 1 ` 1
= ` `
x2 x1 `=0 `=0
X
2 X
2
` 2 ` 1
= ` `
`=0 `=0
2 1
= 0 0
2 1
= 0 0 :
59
We have the famous Corlett-Hague result (actually, t0 = 0 is not at all
necessary: just for presentation).
15. Theorem (Corlett-Hague 1953). Suppose that t1 = t2 and t0 = 0, and
dT
dt2
> 0. Then, raising t1 by adjusting t2 to keep the revenue intact
is welfare-improving if and only if 20 > 10 (commodity 1 is relatively
more complementary with leisure than commodity 2).
16. How do we interpret the above theorem? Note that leisure consumption
is not taxable (labor subsidy does not generate revenue). Thus, leisure
consumption is distorted under uniform commodity taxation t1 = t2 .
Raising tax on commodities relatively more complementary with leisure
works as an indirect tax on leisure. (Note: commodity 1 does not have
to be a complement of leisure. Just demands that commodity 1 is rel-
atively more complementary with leisure than commodity 2.) This is
the principle in the theory of second-best. If there is an unremovable
distortion, then it is not necessarily bene…cial to remove other distor-
tions. Some of other distortions may improve e¢ ciency of economy.
17. Now, optimal commodity taxation. This derivation is due to Mirrlees
(1976 J.Pub.E.).
max u subject to E(q; u) = 0, and
u;q
p x(q; u) + T = 0:
Note that constraints are in inequalities:
E(q; u) 0;
p x(q; u) + T 0:
It is because a higher expenditure is more distortionary (bad for utility),
and more resource is good for utility. The Lagrangian of the above is:
L = u + E(q; u) (p x(q; u) + T ) :
The …rst order conditions are
1 + Eu p xu = 0;
and
x` p x` = x` + x` = 0 for all ` = 0; 1; :::; L.
60
0 1
x00 x0L
B C
Letting = = and letting S = @ ... x`k ... A be the Slutsky
xL0 xLL
matrix, we obtain the optimal commodity tax rule.
S = x;
or
X
L
k `
xk = x` ; (*)
k=0
`
where ` = q ` p` (= t` q ` ) is speci…c tax rate for commodity ` (t` = q`
is called ad valorem tax rate). The formula (*) is so-called the Ramsey
rule.
18. The standard interpretation is based on "small" taxes. Suppose that
T is very small (thus, k s are very small). Consider a tax reform
schedule (s) = s , where s 2 [0; 1]: i.e., (0) and (1) are before-
and after-tax vectors, respectively. Assuming that the Slutsky matrix
S does not change when tax rates change, the change in x` , x` , can
be approximated by the formula
X
L
` k `
x = xk = x` :
k=0
1 1 @x1
x1 + 2 = x1 ;
@q2
2 2
1 x1 + 2 x2 = x2 :
` t` `
Rewriting the above in elasticities and = 1+t`
= p` + ` , we have
1 1 2 1
1 + 2 = ;
61
1 2 2 2
1 + 2 = :
Thus,
1 1 1
1 2
2 2 2 = :
1 2
P
The last transformation used `0 + `1 + `2 = 0 (follows from Lk=0 q k x`k =
0). This implies that 1 R 2 holds if and only if 20 R 10 . That is, as in
Corlett-Hague, commodity 1 should face a higher tax rate if and only
if commodity 1 is more complementary with leisure.
20. Now, suppose that any commodity demand P is independent of any other
commodity prices. Note that we have Lk=0 qk x`k = 0. Thus, if x`k = 0
for all k = 1; :::; L with k 6= `, we need to have q 0 x`0 + q ` x`` = 0 for all
` = 1; :::; L. Supposing 0 = 0, we have
0 10 1 0 1
x00 x01 x0L 0 x0
B x1 x1 0 C B 1 C B x1 C
B 0 1 CB C B C
B .. .. . . .. C B .. C = B .. C :
@ . . . . A@ . A @ . A
L L L
x0 0 xL xL
21. Note that this inverse elasticity rule is not contradictory with the
Corlett-Hague rule,
P although they appear to be totally di¤erent con-
ditions. Recall Lk=0 `k = 0 (zero homogeneity of demand). With the
62
above independence assumption, we have the following in three goods
case (though it works for L + 1 goods case).
1 1
0 + 1 = 0
2 2
0 + 2 = 0
`
Since we have ` < 0 for all ` (Slutsky matrix), we have
1 2 1 2
0 < 0 , 1 < 2 :
Thus, with the independence assumption, these two rules are actually
identical.
22. Finally, let us derive the Ramsey rule using more traditional way (using
indirect utility function). The properties of indirect utility function
v(q; W ) are (W is wealth or income):
63
24. Slutsky equation:
x~`k (q; W ) = x`k (q; u) xk x~`W (q; W )
The proof is as follows. We have the following identity:
x~` (q; E(q; u)) = x` (q; u):
Di¤erentiating both sides with q k , and using Shephard’s lemma, we
have Ek (q; u) = xk (q; u), and we have desired result.
25. The optimal commodity tax problem is
max v(q; 0) subject to p~
x+T 0:
q
The Lagrangean is
L(q; ) = v(q; 0) (p~
x(q; 0) + T ) :
64
1
PL k k
Let =1 vW k=0 x~W . Then, we have
X
L
k k
x` = x` ;
k=0
or
S = x:
This formula is again the Ramsey rule.
65