Slides Capital Controls
Slides Capital Controls
Capital Controls
Columbia University
1
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
Introduction
• In Chapter 10, we saw that over the past 120 years sometimes
capital flowed fairly freely across countries and sometimes there were
significant deviations from free capital mobility.
2
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
3
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
it = i∗t .
4
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
Suppose now that the government imposes a tax τt per dollar bor-
rowed internationally. The tax raises the cost of borrowing one dollar
internationally to i∗t + τt . For agents to be indifferent between off-
shore and onshore borrowing, the domestic interest rate must equal
the sum of the foreign interest rate and the capital control tax rate,
it = i∗t + τt.
The resulting onshore-offshore interest rate differential, it −i∗t , equals
the capital control tax rate, τt. The larger the capital control tax
rate is, the larger the interest rate differential will be.
This is, capital control taxes will give rise to interest rate differen-
tials. Next, we present a case study of capital control taxes imposed
in Brazil that gave rise to interest rate differentials.
5
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
• In the wake of the global financial crisis of 2008 interest rates in the United
States and other developed countries fell to near zero. In response to such low
rates, global investors who were looking for higher yields started sending funds to
emerging market economies where interest rates were higher.
• One country that was a recipient of large inflows was Brazil. The Brazilian
authorities were concerned that these capital inflows would destabilize their econ-
omy and enacted capital control taxes on inflows. Specifically, between October
2009 and March 2012 Brazil imposed more than 10 major capital control taxes.
The measures included taxes on portfolio equity inflows, taxes on fixed income
inflows, and unremunerated reserve requirements. After March 2012 those re-
strictions were gradually removed.
• When capital inflow taxes are imposed on a specific asset or class of assets
there is always the concern that market participants can find a way to circumvent
them. One way to see if in this instance the capital control taxes were effective
is to see whether they led to non-zero covered interest rate differentials.
6
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
Figure 11.1on the next slide plots daily data for the covered interest
rate differential for the period January 1, 2010 to December 31,
2012.
If the capital inflow controls were successful, we should see that dol-
cupom
lar interest rates inside Brazil, it , became higher than in London,
i∗t , that is, that the covered interest rate differential increased.
8
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
3.5
2.5
percentage points
1.5
0.5
The figure plots daily real-dollar covered interest rate differentials computed as the spread between the cupom cambial and the U.S. dollar Libor rate for the period
January 1, 2010 to December 31, 2012. Data Source: Marcos Chamon and Márcio Garcia, ‘Capital Controls in Brazil: Effective?’, Journal of International Money and
Finance 61, 2016, 163-187. We thank the authors for sharing the data.
9
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
• the covered interest rate differential was around 50 basis points until the fall
of 2010 a level also observed prior to the imposition of capital controls. This
means that the capital control measures enacted until then, which targeted mainly
portfolio equity investment, were not effective in restricting arbitrage between the
cupom cambial and the Libor rate.
• However, starting in the fall of 2010 as the government intensified capital con-
trols, the differential starts rising and reaches a peak of 4 percentage points by
April 2011, after an inflow tax of 6 percent on borrowing from abroad with ma-
turities of less than 2 years was imposed. The size of the covered interest rate
differentials suggest that the latter capital inflow taxes were indeed effective in
the sense that they prevented interest rate equalization.
• By early 2012 arbitragers seem to have found ways to bypass the capital control
tax as differentials return to normal levels of around 50 basis points.
• By June 2012 the capital control tax of 6 percent of borrowing from abroad
with maturities of less than 2 years was removed.
10
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
11
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
Household preferences
U (C1) + U (C2)
T2 = lump-sum transfer
i1 = interest rate on bonds held from period 1 to period 2 (taken
as given by the household)
12
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
U 0(C1)
0
= 1 + i1 (1)
U (C2)
13
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
i1 = i∗1 + τ1,
where i∗1 is the world interest rate.
14
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
Lump-sum transfers: T2
T2 = τ1(−B1 ) (4)
15
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
Equilibrium
16
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
Equilibrium (continued)
The figure on the next slide depicts the equilibrium effects of im-
posing a capital control tax τ1 > 0.
17
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
← slope = −(1 + i∗ )
Q2 A
C2∗ 0 C
C2∗ B
slope = −(1 + i∗ + τ ) →
Q1 C1∗ 0 C1∗ C1
22
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
23
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
At point B, the economy borrows from the rest of the world in order
to finance a level of consumption, C1∗, that exceeds the period-1
endowment, Q1, Q1 − C1∗ < 0.
24
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
← Q1 + D
← slope = −(1 + i∗ )
Q2 A
C2∗ 0 C
C2∗ B
slope = −(1 + i) →
Q1 C1∗ 0 C1∗ C1
The equilibrium under free capital mobility is at point B, where C1∗ > Q1 . Quantitative capital
controls forbid borrowing more than D, pushing households to consume Q1 + D in period 1, point
C. The domestic interest rate under quantitative capital controls (i1) is given by the slope of the
indifference curve at point C and is higher than the world interest rate i∗1 .
25
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
26
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
27
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
28
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
and
29
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
31
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
Suppose that the interest rate at which the small open economy can
borrow in international capital markets is increasing in the country’s
cross-sectional average of borrowing, denoted −B̄1 . If B̄1 < 0, the
country borrows, if B̄1 > 0 the country saves.
The interest rate faced by the small open economy, denoted i∗1, is
assumed to be debt elastic. Specifically,
i∗1 = I(−B̄1 )
32
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
• but borrows at an interest rate that increases linearly with the level
of debt.
The figure on the next slide plots this debt-elastic interest rate
schedule.
33
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
I(−B̄1 )
i + δ(−B̄1 )
B̄1 0 −B̄1
The figure displays an interest rate schedule, I(−B̄1), which is weakly increasing
in the level of external debt, (−B̄1 ). Both i and δ are positive constants. For
B̄1 > 0, the country is a net external lender, and the interest rate is constant and
equal to i. For B̄1 < 0, the country is a net external borrower, and the interest
rate is an increasing function of the level of debt, −B̄1.
34
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
Households:
Suppose that the country has free capital mobility. Let i∗1 be the in-
terest rate charged by foreign lenders to the country in international
capital markets. Then, in equilibrium
i1 = i∗1 (9)
37
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
38
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
i1 = i∗1 = I(C1).
39
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
U 0(C1)
0
= 1 + i1 (11)
U (C2)
C2 Q2
C1 + = Q1 + (12)
1 + i1 1 + i1
i1 = I(C1) (13)
given the endowments Q1 and Q2.
Note that these are the same equilibrium conditions as those asso-
ciated with the model of Chapter 3 with the only difference that in
that model the interest rate parity condition, equation (13), takes
the form i1 = i∗1, where i∗1 is an exogenous constant.
40
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
without
Government Intervention
41
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
Use the interest rate parity condition (13) to eliminate the inter-
est rate i1 from the intertemporal budget constraint (12) and the
Euler (11) to obtain
42
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
• If the country is a borrower (C1 > Q1), the slope is greater than 1+
i1 in absolute value. Intuitively, if the country borrows an additional
unit for consumption in period 1, in period 2 it must pay not only
1 + i1 but also the increase in the interest rate, I 0 (C1), caused by
the increase in debt.
C2
A
B
Q2
A
Q1 C1e C1
46
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
C2
A
B
A
Q1 opt
C1 C1e C1
49
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
50
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
• Takeaways:
– in the presence of a borrowing externality free capital mobility
ceases to be optimal.
– in the economy without govt intervention, households consume
more and borrow more in period 1 than is socially optimal.
– capital controls now are desirable as a way to eliminate overbor-
rowing and to increase welfare.
51
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
53
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
A two-country model
55
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
Trade balance
h Q ih
T B1 = h
.
21+i
Current account schedule (recall B0h = 0).
h Q ih
CA1 = h
. (23)
21+i
Net foreign asset position
h Q ih
B1 = . (24)
2 1 + ih
57
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
f 3 + if
C1 = Q f
. (25)
4(1 + i )
f
⇒ C1 > Q/2, for interest rate below 100 percent (i.e., for any if < 1).
Trade balance
f Q if − 1
T B1 = f
,
4 (1 + i )
f
Current account schedule (recallB0 = 0)
f Q if − 1
CA1 = f
. (26)
4 (1 + i )
Net foreign asset position
f Q if − 1
B1 = . (27)
4 (1 + if )
58
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
Equilibrium
ih = if . (29)
Let this interest rate be denoted i∗ and let’s refer to it as the world
interest rate. That is, let ih = if = i∗.
59
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
f f
Solving for the equilibrium values of Ct and B1
Exercise 11.9 asks you to show that both countries are better off
under free capital mobility than under financial autarky. An implica-
tion of this result is that it does not pay for either country to impose
capital controls so high that all intertemporal trade stops.
11.6
in a Large Economy
64
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
65
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
Let i0 denote the interest rate such that C1 = Q1 and C2 = Q2. Next find the
optimal (C1 , C2) for other values of i1.
Starting from i1 = i0, consider higher values of i1, by the substitution effect C1 ↓
and C2 ↑.
The figure on the next slide shows how (C1 , C2 ) change with the interest rate.
It follows that the optimal consumption path as the interest rate declines describes
a downward sloping locus in the space (C1 , C2) that crosses the endowment point.
This locus is the offer curve.
The figure on the slide after the next plots the offer curve.
∗
If the income effect associated with a decline in interest rates dominates the substitution effect, it is possible that C2 ↑. In what follows we assume that the substitution
effect always dominates.
66
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
I2 I1 I0
Qj2 A0
A1
slope = −(1 + i 0 )
A2
slope = −(1 + i 1 )
slope = −(1 + i 2 )
I0 I1 I2
C1j
Qj1
The figure displays the optimal consumption choice for three different values of the interest rate, i0 , i1 , and i2 , satisfying i0 > i1 > i2 . Each interest rate is associated
with a different intertemporal budget constraint. The higher the interest rate is, the steeper the intertemporal budget constraint will be. The intertemporal budget
constraint I 0 I 0 is induced by the highest of the three interest rates, and the intertemporal budget constraint I 2 I 2 by the lowest. The associated optimal consumption
path induced by the interest rate associated with budget constraint I 0 I 0 is the endowment point, A0 . The intertemporal budget constraints I 1 I 1 and I 2 I 2 produce
optimal consumption choices given by points A1 and A2 , respectively. The offer curve (not shown) connects points A0 , A1 , A2 .
67
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
j
C2
J
A0
j
Q2
A1
A2
J
j j
Q1 C1
The offer curve is the locus JJ, which connects all optimal consumption allocations at different
interest rates. The offer curve crosses the endowment point A0 . The figure also shows the
indifference curve that crosses the endowment point. At the endowment point this indifference
curve is tangent to the offer curve. All points on the offer curve other than the endowment point
are preferred to the endowment point itself.
68
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
• The length of the horizontal side of the box is the global endowment of goods
in period 1, Qh1 + Qf1.
• The height of the box is the global endowment in period 2, Qh2 + Qf2.
• The southwest corner of the box is the origin of the foreign country and is
indicated by the symbol O f . For the foreign country, consumption and the en-
dowment in period 1 are measured on the horizontal axis from the origin O f to
the right, and consumption and the endowment in period 2 are measured on the
vertical axis from O f upward. Welfare of households in the foreign country rises
as the allocation (C1f , C2f ) moves northeast in the box.
• The northeast corner of the box is the origin of the home country and is indicated
by the symbol O h . For this country, consumption and the endowment in period
1 are measured on the horizontal axis from O h to the left, and consumption and
the endowment in period 2 are measured on the vertical axis from O h downward.
Welfare of households in the home country rises as the allocation (C1h , C2h ) moves
southwest in the box.
• Any point in the box represents an allocation of consumption across time and
countries that can be achieved with the existing global endowments.
69
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
0
Qh2
A
Qf2
Qf1 + Qh1
Of
Qf1
The width of the box is equal to the world endowment of goods in period 1, Qf1 + Qh1. The heights
of the box is equal to the world endowment of goods in period 2, Qf2 + Qh2 . The origin of the
foreign country is O f and the origin of the home country is O h . The endowment point is A0.
70
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
• Next, we add the offer curves to the Edgeworth box. This is shown
in the figure on the next slide.
71
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
Qf2
Qf1 + Qh1
Of
Qf1
The offer curve of the foreign country is the locus F F , and the offer curve of the home country is
the locus HH. Both offer curves must cross the endowment point, A0. For a given country, any
point on the country’s offer curve is preferred to the endowment point. The slope of a straight
line from a point on the offer curve, of country f say, to A0 is equal to −(1 + if ). For points to
the right of A0 the interest rate if is lower than the autarky interest rate and for points on the
offer curve FF to the left of A0 the interest rate supporting that allocation, if , is higher.
72
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
• The equilibrium under free capital mobility is given by point B, where the two
offer curves intersect for a second time.
• The equilibrium world interest rate, i∗, is determined by the slope of the line
that connects points A0 and B. This line is the intertemporal budget constraint
faced by the domestic and foreign households at the equilibrium world interest
rate i∗ . This interest rate is lower than the domestic interest rate in the foreign
country under financial autarky, which is determined by the slope of the foreign
household’s indifference curve at the endowment point A0. By the same logic,
we have that the equilibrium interest rate under free capital mobility, i∗, is higher
than the domestic interest rate in the home country under financial autarky.
• We have therefore established that allowing for free capital mobility eliminates
interest rate differentials.
• Because in equilibrium both countries are on their respective offer curves, they
are both better off than under autarky. Thus free capital mobility is welfare
improving.
73
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
Qf2
B
F
H
← slope= −(1 + i∗ )
Qf1 + Qh1
Of
Qf1
The equilibrium under free capital mobility is point B. The slope of the line that connects points
A0 and point B is −(1 + i∗ ), where i∗ is the equilibrium world interest rate under free capital
mobility.
74
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
• This implies that at no point inside the Edgeworth box can both
countries be better off than at point B. In other words, any other
attainable consumption allocation makes at least one country worse
off relative to the allocation associated with the equilibrium under
free capital mobility.
75
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
77
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
• The capital control tax τ creates a wedge between the world in-
terest rate and the interest rate in the foreign country,
if = i∗ + τ. (32)
78
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
f f
From here we can express C1 and C2 as functions of the world
interest rate i∗
f Q 1 + 2i∗
C1 = (37)
2 1 + i∗
and
f Q
C2 = (2 − i∗). (38)
2
79
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
f f
Now use these two expressions to eliminate C1 and C2 from the
utility function of the foreign household to obtain
Q 1 + 2i∗
!
Q
ln + ln (2 − i∗) .
2 1 + i∗ 2
80
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
82
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
Find τ :
τ = if − i∗ = 0.5 − 0.22 = 0.28
83
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
Because the capital controls raise the domestic interest rate (if ),
the current account deficit of the foreign economy falls from
f
B1 = −0.1250Q under free capital mobility to
f
B1 = −0.0918Q under optimal capital controls.
84
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
85
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
Let’s now use the Edgeworth box to analyze optimal capital controls
in the foreign country, see Figure 11.11 on the next slide.
• In setting capital controls, the objective of the foreign country is to attain a
point on the home country’s offer curve, HH, that maximizes the foreign country’s
utility. The foreign country is constrained to pick a point on the home country’s
offer curve because, by construction, only the allocations on the offer curve can
be obtained as a market outcome, that is, by an appropriate choice of the world
interest rate. Consequently, the allocation associated with the optimal capital
control policy is one at which an indifference curve of the foreign country is
tangent to the offer curve of the home country.
• This allocation is point C in Figure 11.11. The indifference curve attained by
the foreign country under optimal capital controls is U U .
0
• The world interest rate under optimal capital controls (i∗ ), is defined by the
slope of the line that connects points A0 and C. Clearly, this line is flatter than
the one connecting points A0 and B. This means that the imposition of optimal
capital controls causes the world interest rate to fall.
• Also, the optimal capital control policy in the foreign country makes the foreign
country better off at the expense of the home country, whose welfare goes down.
Recall that the equilibrium under free capital mobility is Pareto optimal, so the
improvement in the foreign country’s welfare must be welfare decreasing for the
home country.
• These results echo those obtained algebraically in Section 11.7.
86
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
Qf2 U
B
F 0
slope = −(1 + i∗ )
H slope = −(1 + i∗ )
Qf1 + Qh1
Of
Qf1
The offer curve of the home country is HH and that of the foreign country is F F . The endowment
is at point A0. The equilibrium under free capital mobility is at point B, and the equilibrium under
optimal capital controls in the foreign country is at0 point C. The interest rate under free capital
mobility is i∗ and under optimal capital controls i∗ < i∗ . The indifference curve attained by the
foreign country under optimal capital controls is U U . The fact that this indifference curve is not
tangent to the intertemporal budget constraint that crosses point C implies that the equilibrium
with capital controls is Pareto inefficient.
87
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
• Since the budget constraint and the offer curve (the locus HH)
intersect at C, the slopes of the home and foreign indifference curves
at point C are not the same.
11.9 Retaliation
89
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
Equilibrium Requirements
91
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
if = i∗ + τ f ,
Setting j = f in (39) and (40) and solving for C1f and C2f , yields
f
f Q2
f f ∗ f
Q1 + 1+i∗
C1 = K (i , τ ) ≡
1+i∗+τ f
1 + 1+i∗
and
f Qf2
f f ∗ f ∗ f
Q1 + 1+i∗
C2 = L (i , τ ) ≡ (1 + i + τ )
1+i∗ +τ f
1 + 1+i∗
92
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
ih = i∗ − τ h .
Setting j = h in (39) and (40) and solving for C1h and C2h, yields
h Qh2
h h ∗ h
Q1 + 1+i ∗
C1 = K (i , τ ) ≡
1+i∗ −τ h
1 + 1+i∗
and
h Qh
2
h h ∗ h ∗ h
Q1 + 1+i ∗
C2 = L (i , τ ) ≡ (1 + i − τ ) ,
1+i∗−τ h
1 + 1+i∗
i∗ = I(τ f , τ h).
Using this relation to eliminate i∗ from consumption in both periods
in the home and foreign countries we can write
f
C1 = K̃ f (τ f , τ h) ≡ K f (I(τ f , τ h), τ f ),
f
C2 = L̃f (τ f , τ h) ≡ Lf (I(τ f , τ h), τ f ),
94
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
taking as given τ f .
τ h = Rh(τ f ),
which is the reaction function of the home country.
96
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
Figure 11.12: on the next slide displays the reaction functions of the
home and foreign countries in the space (τ h, τ f ) for the algebraic
example studied in Section 11.5.
• The Nash equilibrium is at point A, where the two reaction functions intersect.
• Point B in the figure corresponds to the case in which the foreign country
behaves strategically and the home is passive, which is the case we studied in
Section . Comparing points A and B, we see that retaliation by the home country
makes the foreign country lower its capital control tax rate (28 versus 18 percent).
• Point C in the figure corresponds to the case in which the home country behaves
strategically and the foreign country is passive.
97
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
0.4
0.35
0.3
B
τf
0.25
0.2
A
0.15
0.1
0.05
C
0
0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5
τh
The function Rf (τ h) is the reaction function of the foreign country. It expresses the optimal
capital control tax rate of the foreign country as a function of the tax rate of the home country.
Similarly, Rh(τ f ) is the reaction function of the home country, representing the optimal tax rate
in the home country as a function of the foreign country’s tax rate. The intersection of the
two reaction functions gives the Nash equilibrium capital control tax rates in the two countries.
Replication file: tauf_tauh_num.m in two_country.zip.
98
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
Comments:
• Not surprisingly, intertemporal trade, as measured by the absolute size of the current account,
is the largest under free capital mobility and the smallest under optimal capital controls with Nash
retaliation.
• Also not surprisingly, a country’s welfare is the highest when it imposes optimal capital controls
and the other country is passive.
• It is somewhat surprising, however, that the home country is better off under optimal capital
controls with retaliation than under free capital mobility. Thus, it is optimal for the home country
to impose capital controls regardless of whether this triggers a capital control war or not. This is
not the case for the foreign country, which prefers free capital mobility to a capital control war.
• An interesting question is whether it pays for the foreign country to compensate the home
country for abiding to free capital mobility.
• Finally, if one country imposes optimal capital controls unilaterally, it is in the interest of the other
country to retaliate. To see this, note that in both countries welfare is higher under retaliation
than in the absence thereof.
99
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
Summing Up
• If under free capital mobility, a small country borrows from the rest
of the world, then the imposition of capital controls drives domestic
interest rates up, depresses current consumption, and improves the
current account.
Summing Up (continued)
101
Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford “International Macroeconomics” Slides for Chapter 11: Capital Controls
Summing Up (concluded)