4 FinancialMarketsCrises Slides
4 FinancialMarketsCrises Slides
(07 33109)
Dr Ceri Davies
[email protected]
Introduction
• We have considered how households save – as the
difference between income and consumption in any given
period. We have also considered how firms invest – they
set aside current resources for future use/benefits.
1
Financial Markets & Macroeconomics
2
Overview
• Baseline:
– A Model of Perfectly-Functioning Financial Markets
• With imperfections/frictions:
– Agency Costs and the Financial Accelerator
• Financial Crises:
– The Diamond-Dybvig Model
– Financial contagion
Baseline Model
Assumptions: two-period model; a representative household
has an endowment E of the economy’s single good in period 1
and no endowment in period 2; we abstract from labour
market (or leisure) decisions and focus on financial markets.
𝑈′(•) > 0
𝑉 = 𝑈 𝐶1 + 𝛽𝑈 𝐶2
𝑈 ′′ • < 0
3
Investment Projects
• The are N possible ‘investment projects’ undertaken by firms;
there are S possible ‘states of the world’ in period 2; firms are
price-takers too.
Equilibrium
• It is conceptually straightforward to compute the equilibrium
in such a model with complete markets and no imperfections.
• We can describe the outcome of the model in terms of claims
on period-2 output in the various possible future states of the
world. This is known as an Arrow-Debreu-McKenzie
contingent claim (see next slide).
• Notation: qs denotes the price of a claim on one unit of
period-2 output in state s, stated in units of period-1 output
(i.e. in relative terms, with period 1 output as the numeraire).
• An equilibrium consists of: a set of prices over future states
{qs}, investment decisions {𝐾𝑖 } and consumption choices 𝐶1
and {𝐶2𝑠 }.
4
Aside: State-Contingent Claims
• We use these as a helpful modelling device; we assume
that we can put a price on contracts which pay-out in
different possible future states of the world; we can cover
all cases, ‘complete markets’ (Arrow-Debreu-McKenzie).
𝐶1 + 𝑞𝑠 𝐶2𝑠 = 𝐸
𝑠=1
5
Aside: The Stochastic Discount Factor
• Recall:
′ 𝑠
𝑞𝑠 = 𝜋𝑠 𝛽𝑈 (𝐶2 )
𝑈 ′ (𝐶 ) 1
6
3. Markets must clear.
𝑁
For period 1: 𝐶1 + 𝐾𝑖 = 𝐸
𝑖=1
𝐶2𝑠 = 𝐾𝑖 𝑅𝑖𝑠
𝑖=1
for all s
Summary
𝑆
= 1 if 𝐾𝑖 > 0
𝑞𝑠 𝑅𝑖𝑠
≤ 1 if 𝐾𝑖 = 0
Number of equilibrium 𝑠=1
for all 𝑖
conditions
𝑁
Unknowns: 𝑆 x 𝑞𝑠 𝑆 x 𝐶2 𝑁 x 𝐾𝑖 𝐶1
7
Interpretation
• So far, the model is conceptually similar to a standard model
of consumption or investment under uncertainty.
• With imperfections/frictions:
– Agency Costs and the Financial Accelerator
• Financial Crises:
– The Diamond-Dybvig Model
– Financial contagion
8
Introducing Market Imperfections
• We have so far assumed that all economic agents are equally-
well informed; financial markets function efficiently with
symmetric (‘perfect’) information; potential investment
projects go ahead if their value exceeds the cost of capital.
9
A Model with Asymmetric Information
• This theoretical framework belongs to the class of costly
state verification models (Townsend, 1979).
• An entrepreneur has the opportunity to undertake an
investment project; the project requires 1 unit of resources.
• The entrepreneur has wealth W<1; (s)he therefore requires
outside financing of (1–W) for the project to proceed.
• The project has an expected output of 𝛾 (>0) ex ante;
however, actual project output is distributed uniformly
along the interval [0,2𝛾].
• Outside investors must bear some risk since the
entrepreneur will put all personal wealth into the project.
This implies:
1. The investment project is only ‘socially desirable’ from a
social planner’s perspective if expected output 𝛾 > 1 + 𝑟
2. The entrepreneur will only choose to proceed with the
project if the difference between 𝛾 and expected payments
to outside investors exceeds 1 + 𝑟 𝑊; otherwise buy bonds.
3. Due to competitive bidding, in equilibrium investors can
expect a return of 𝑟 on any particular project.
10
Information and Monitoring Costs
• Entrepreneurs are better-informed than outside investors
about investment projects and, therefore, the actual output
that a particular project produces.
(1 − 𝑊)(1 + 𝑟)
11
Equilibrium under Asymmetric Information
• It is costly for outside investors to observe a project’s
output. To simplify matters, assume that there is just one
outside investor per investment project, i.e. the investor
is wealthy enough to fund the project alone.
12
The Optimal Payment Function
13
3. The payment is D whenever output exceeds D. If the
payment is ever less than D when output is greater than
D, it is possible to increase the investor’s expected
receipts and/or reduce expected verification costs for
these levels of output; it would therefore be possible to
construct a more efficient contract for the investor.
X (1)
(2)
(1)
This reasoning leads
us to the optimal
contract structure, as
(4)
shown by the solid line
(3)
(5)
14
The Equilibrium Value for D
15
Summary
• From the results on the previous slide, the investor’s
expected returns minus verification costs, c, are:
Probability Probability
2𝛾−𝐷 𝐷 𝐷
2𝛾
𝐷 + 2𝛾 2
−𝑐 if 𝐷 ≤ 2𝛾
𝑅(𝐷) = 0
𝛾−𝑐 if 𝐷 > 2𝛾
Pay-off net
of cost
16
Suppose the investor has some ‘target’ return
(V1, V2 or V3) in mind:
Two equilibrium
values for D
Equilibrium Investment
• Both parties must be happy to proceed with the project;
this incentive compatibility constraint is needed because
investor and entrepreneur both have the opportunity to
invest in the ‘safe asset’.
17
Interpretation and Application
• Our specific results hold for the particular model presented;
however, the concepts covered have broader applicability.
• Suppose that agency costs (e.g. monitoring costs) are lower for
wealthier entrepreneurs who can pledge more ‘skin in the
game’. When wealth falls generally – e.g. a recession – agency
costs rise, investment projects become more costly and some
projects are no longer viable; investment declines and wealth
falls again… this triggers a vicious circle.
18
Credit Spreads
• The assumptions of the model give rise to an inverse
relationship between credit spreads – which is the cost of
external borrowing over the risk-free rate – and the net worth
of entrepreneurs, or firms or households more generally.
19
Modelling a ‘Financial Crisis’
with/without F.A. Effects
Key Implication
• The financial system is important to investment; for
example, an increase in c – verification costs – will reduce
investment in our model.
20
A Model with F.A. Effects
Calibrated to the UK Economy
A negative
shock to
output is
amplified
with F.A.
effects
Financial Crises
21
The Diamond-Dybvig Model
• This model considers the possibility of a bank run.
Depositors wish to be able to withdraw their savings
whenever they want, e.g. an instant-access account.
Friday 14
September
2007
The first run
on a British
Bank in 150
Years
22
The Model
• There are three time periods: 0, 1, and 2.
Individuals
• To begin with, all individuals are the same. However, in
period 1 a fraction 𝜃 of individuals learn that they only like
period 1 consumption (C1) while others discover that they
value period 2 consumption (C2) as well; patient vs.
impatient? We assume that one’s type cannot be observed
by other individuals (an information friction):
23
Autarchy
• Rule out any sort of trade, insurance or risk sharing among
individuals; this is just a starting point.
• Period 0 consumption isn’t valued by anybody so all agents
invest their endowment in period 0.
• Given the assumptions imposed: Type a’s liquidate their
investment projects early to enjoy period 1 consumption
(=1) only. Type b’s hang onto their investment and enjoy
period 2 consumption (=R) only; note ρ and ρR>1.
• Overall, expected utility is:
24
• We can state that the social planner’s resource constraint is
(for 𝑐2𝑎 = 𝑐1𝑏 = 0):
𝐸 𝑈 = 𝜃ln𝑐1𝑎 + (1 − 𝜃)𝜌ln𝑐2𝑏
∗ 1 ∗ 𝜌𝑅
𝑐1𝑎 = >1 𝑐2𝑏 = <𝑅
𝜃+ 1−𝜃 𝜌 𝜃+ 1−𝜃 𝜌
Introduce a Bank
• Diamond and Dybvig show that we do not need a social planner
to achieve the efficient outcome; instead, we could allow one
individual in the economy to set up a bank.
• The bank takes deposits, makes investments and allows
customers to withdraw their funds whenever they wish, so long
as the bank has funds available; those who don’t withdraw in
period 1 share the investment proceeds in period 2.
• There is an equilibrium in the model in which Type a’s can
∗ ∗
achieve 𝑐1𝑎 and Type b’s can achieve 𝑐2𝑏 , i.e. the socially
optimal outcome is a Nash equilibrium in the model.
• Therefore, the bank provides liquidity to the economy; it makes
long-term investments and satisfies individuals’ consumption
timing preferences; Type b’s wait until period 2, Type a’s don’t.
25
An Alternative Equilibrium
• However, Diamond and Dybvig show that there is another
Nash equilibrium in the model. It happens if Type b’s
believe that all agents – not just Type a’s – will try to
withdraw their deposits in period 1.
Intuition
26
Financial Contagion
If one bank (or financial institution) gets into financial difficulty,
this is likely to cause worries for clients at other banks. The
initial concern – whether warranted or not – can quickly
spread. Why?
Summary/Conclusions
• We have introduced financial markets into our macroeconomic
modelling framework, beginning with a baseline case under
complete markets and perfect information.
27