The impact of professional sports franchises and venues on local economies
The impact of professional sports franchises and venues on local economies
The impact of professional sports franchises and venues on local economies
DENNIS COATES
University of Maryland-Baltimore County
BRAD R. HUMPHREYS
West Virginia University
Abstract. Local governments routinely subsidize sports stadiums and arenas using the justifi-
cation that hosting professional franchises produces economic development and social benefits in
the community. The prevalence of venue subsidies generated an extensive and vibrant research
literature, which spans over 30 years and includes more than 130 studies. We chronicle this body of
research from early studies of tangible economic impacts in metropolitan areas, using basic empiri-
cal methods, through recent analyses that focus on sub-local and non-pecuniary effects and employ
more sophisticated empirical methods. Though findings have become more nuanced, recent analy-
ses continue to confirm the decades-old consensus of very limited economic impacts of professional
sports teams and stadiums. Even with added non-pecuniary social benefits from quality-of-life
externalities and civic pride, welfare improvements from hosting teams tend to fall well short of
covering public outlays. Thus, the large subsidies commonly devoted to constructing professional
sports venues are not justified as worthwhile public investments. We also investigate the paradox
of local governments continuing to subsidize sports facilities despite overwhelming evidence of their
economic impotence. Our analysis informs academic researchers and policymakers to motivate fu-
ture studies and promote sound policy decisions guided by relevant research findings. (JEL: R58,
H71, L83, Z28)
Between 1970 and 2020, state and local governments devoted $33 billion in public funds
to construct major-league sports venues in the United States and Canada, with the median public
contribution covering 73 percent of venue construction costs.1 The prevalence of subsidized sports
stadiums and arenas spawned an active economics literature evaluating their efficacy at stimulating
economic activity. This literature contains near-universal consensus evidence that sports venues
do not generate large positive effects on local economies. Several existing surveys of this literature
have documented the strong consensus of null findings (Baade and Dye 1988b; Siegfried and Zim-
balist 2000; Coates and Humphreys 2003b, 2008; Coates 2007). However, this literature expanded
considerably since the last comprehensive literature survey. We survey the extensive academic lit-
erature on the economic impacts of sports teams and venues on local communities, which includes
more than 130 articles and spans more than 30 years, most published in the past decade. We doc-
ument the presence of a clear consensus in the results reported in this literature. Supplementary
Appendix Table A1 provides a list of included studies and brief summaries of the main findings.2
We also discuss explanations for why these subsidies continue despite the consensus evidence that
they generate little in terms of tangible local economic benefits.
The early empirical literature on economic impacts of sports venues and games primarily
employed multiple regression models using annual data aggregated to the metropolitan area level to
compare economic outcomes across urban areas with teams over time. With the key empirical ques-
tion, the (lack of) tangible economic impacts flowing from professional sports teams and venues,
largely settled, much of the recent economics and urban/regional development literature focused
on investigating the existence of localized economic development effects and quality-of-life amenity
benefits. Matheson (2019) notes that even though sports events are not associated with large tan-
gible economic benefits in metropolitan areas, and may not deserve substantial public funding, the
optimal subsidy for a new sports facility may be greater than zero. Benefits may be concentrated in
neighborhoods or business/entertainment districts that deliver concentrated economic benefits that
1
Real dollars in 2020 terms. 1970 to 2010 stadium funding from Long (2013), and subsequent funding from various
media reports compiled by authors.
2
There exists a complementary literature on mega-events (e.g., Olympic Games, World Cup, Super Bowl, etc.), which
similarly finds these events have limited positive impacts on host communities. We do not include these studies in
this review, as the subsidization of sports venues to host professional sports teams is extensive enough to warrant
a separate treatment. Economic studies of mega-events are sufficiently distinct and abundant to require a separate
survey and have been more recently summarized by (Baade and Matheson 2016; Barrios et al. 2016; Scandizzo and
Pierleoni 2018).
1
In 1970, teams in North America’s four major sports leagues—Major League Baseball
(MLB), the National Basketball Association (NBA), the National Football League (NFL), and
the National Hockey League (NHL)—played games in 80 stadiums and arenas in the US (76) and
Canada (4) (Okner 1974). Between 1970 and 2020, 135 new or replacement stadiums and arenas
hosting teams opened, representing an average of 2.6 new venues per year. Figure 1 shows a modest
increase in new facilities in the 1970s and a robust construction boom occurring in the 1990s and
2000s. Few new facilities opened during the 1980s, and the period following the mid-2000s experi-
enced relatively less new facility construction; however, Humphreys (2019) notes that the average
age at which teams are replacing their existing stadiums (27 years) indicates that another wave of
stadium construction is expected within the next decade, as the facilities built in the 1990s and
early 2000s are deemed obsolete. For example, in 2017 team owners in Atlanta replaced their NFL
and MLB stadiums after only 25 and 20 years of use, respectively.
Stadiums and arenas are often replaced even though they remain viable venues. From the
1960s through the 1980s, NFL and MLB franchises often shared a public multipurpose stadium—
older fans will remember the infield dirt making for treacherous footing for football players in
shared stadiums. Team owners preferred separate single-sport stadiums rather than share space,
scheduling, and revenue with a co-tenant. A further motivation for teams to seek new facilities was
3
6
6
3 2 2
3 5 3 1
4
4 4 1 4442 2 3
321 13 3 133 1 3 1 3
2
2 2 2 1 1 12 2 2 22 2 2 2 1 2
1 11111 1 111 1 1 1 1 1 1 11
0
1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020
Year
to generate added revenue from modern amenities, like luxury boxes and club seating, that cater
to a lucrative customer cohort of affluent individual and business spectators.
An added benefit to NFL teams was that premium seat fee revenue was not initially subject
to league revenue sharing (Vrooman 2012). Fort (1999) notes that the stadium revenues of teams
that have new facilities “often outpace the ‘have nots’ by a multiple of twenty in MLB and the
NBA, and almost forty in the NFL.” A novelty effect from constructing new venues that increase
the spectator demand and correspondingly increase team revenues is well-documented in all sports
leagues (Coates and Humphreys 2005; Bradbury 2019). Poitras and Hadley (2006) estimate that
the private returns from new stadiums are high enough to cover the construction costs, rendering
any spillover benefits to be inframarginal.
Although the rate of new facility construction slowed during the 2010s, the cost of new
sports facilities increased substantially. Long (2013) provides an extensive summary of publicly-
reported stadium costs and public contributions, which we extend through 2020. While median
publicly-reported costs represent 73 percent of total costs (60 percent mean) they routinely omit less
obvious costs, such as land, infrastructure, operations, capital improvements, municipal services,
and foregone property taxes. Long finds that including these relevant public obligations increased
4
100
Public Share of Total Facility Cost (%)
80
60
40
20
Figure 2. Public Share of Sports Venue Construction Costs (1970–2020). Sources: 1970–
2010, Long (2013), pp. 19–29; 2011–2020, compiled from media reports.
Figure 3 shows that public funding has increased as stadiums and arenas have grown more
expensive. Spectator sports are a normal good, and as the economy has grown, so have consumers’
tastes for sports spectatorship. Stadiums have evolved from austere multi-sport facilities with con-
crete bleachers and minimal concessions into extravagant sport-specific venues that offer amenities
and comforts for which spectators are willing to pay—luxuries which professional clubs are more
willing to provide when bearing less than the full cost. Propheter (2017) finds support for Quirk
and Fort (1997)’s gold-plating hypothesis, that stadium opulence is positively correlated with pub-
lic subsidies, with each $1 million in public funding associated with 20 to 50-percent increases in
construction costs. The three stadiums that opened in 2020 exceeded $1 billion in construction
5
1,200
Arenas (Public cost)
Stadiums (Public cost)
1,000 Arenas (Total cost)
Stadiums (Total cost)
(in millions of real 2020 dollars)
Median Construction Cost
800
600
400
200
0
1970s 1980s 1990s 2000s 2010s
Figure 3. Stadium and Arena Construction Costs by Decade (1970–2019). Sources: 1970–
2010, Long (2013), pp. 19–29; 2011–2019, compiled from media reports.
In addition to subsidies provided by local and state governments, new sports facility con-
struction projects financed by sub-national governments may qualify for a federal tax exemption on
bond interest. Funding stadium construction with tax-exempt municipal bonds lowers borrowing
costs for team owners, which can result in significant cost savings on projects where expenditures
are measured in hundreds of millions of dollars. Drukker et al. (2020) estimates that the present
value of the implicit nationwide subsidy to bondholders from 2000 to 2020 was $3.6 billion, and
resulted in $4.3 billion in lost revenue to the federal government. Although the Tax Reform Act of
1986 included provisions designed to end this practice, the new restrictions had the unintended con-
sequence of increasing public funding from sources not tied to the facility’s use.4 Stadium projects
3
SoFi Stadium construction was entirely privately financed, which is a notable exception among recent new stadium
projects. Los Angeles did not host an NFL team from 1995 through 2015, and the two-team relocation to Los
Angeles was part of an NFL effort to return football to one of the US’s largest markets. Construction costs were
shared by the two team owners, and the League provided large loans to finance the construction.
4
The Act categorized municipal bonds as private—thus, not tax exempt—if more than ten percent of the funded
project is to be used by a non-government entity (private use test) or ten percent of the debt service was secured
by property used by a private business (private payment test). The latter test could be met by local governments
funding sports venues from tax revenue derived from non-stadium tax revenue, which incentivized local governments
to fund sports venues by diverting public revenue from other unrelated sources.
6
Agree 28 Agree 63
Neutral 10 Uncertain 17
Disagree 4 Disagree 3
0 20 40 60 0 20 40 60
Respondents (%) Respondents (%)
(a) Question: Local and state governments in the U.S. (b) Question: Providing state and local subsidies to build
should eliminate subsidies to professional sports fran- stadiums for professional sports teams is likely to cost the
chises. relevant taxpayers more than any local economic benefits
that are generated.
Figure 4. Economists’ Opinions on Sports Subsidies. (a) 2005 survey of American Economic
Association, 210 Ph.D. economist members, 81 respondents (Whaples 2006). (b) 2017 survey
of Chicago Booth’s Initiative on Global Markets panel of economic experts, 42 members, 30
respondents (IGM Economic Experts Panel 2017).
5
Michael Greenstone stated, “Sports teams generate value that they cannot capture thru tixs/tv—Chicagoans bene-
fited from Cubs winning [World Series]. Subsidies are compensation.”
7
Economic studies of sports venues as drivers of economic activity began in earnest during
the stadium construction boom of the 1990s, when a growing number of new stadiums raised
concerns over using public funds to subsidize professional teams. Prior to this time, economic impact
estimates had been limited to consulting studies, often commissioned by parties with vested interests
in stadium projects, using estimation methods of limited credibility. Improved data availability
allowed economists to systematically search for evidence of economic effects using more credible
statistical methods. Early econometric studies largely used multiple-regression analysis to estimate
relationships between the presence of teams/stadiums and economic well-being in metropolitan
areas (MSA), which includes the host city proper and its connected surrounding communities.6
Much of the early literature on the economic impact of sports facilities is either summarized
or included in Noll and Zimbalist (1997), published by the Brookings Institution as a guide for
policymakers. The volume includes 15 chapters of analyses using various empirical strategies to
asses the economic effects from sports venues. The introduction summarizes the “unattractive
economics of stadiums” from the studies’ findings succinctly: “In every case, the authors find that
the local economic impact of sports teams and facilities is far smaller than proponents allege; in
some cases it is negative. These findings are valid regardless of whether the benefits are measured
for the local neighborhood, for the city, or for the entire metropolitan area in which the facility is
located” (p. vii–viii).
Findings in papers published in academic journals from that era are similarly dour. In
response to what the authors referred to as “stadium mania...sweeping the United States,” with
local politicians proposing sports as a channel for economic development, Baade and Dye (1988a,
1990) provide the first empirical analyses of sports stadiums on local economies by examining
impacts on a few selected US metropolitan areas extending from the mid-1960s to the early-1980s.
Baade (1996) extends this empirical strategy to estimate the relationship between the presence of
sports teams and new stadiums and cities’ income per capita and share of state employment in the
amusement and recreation sector using data from the late-1950s through the 1980s from an a larger
sample of metropolitan areas. The estimates do not identify positive impacts on host economies, and
6
Some early contributions focused on the policy landscape of the era and offer case studies in books. Baim (1994)
features several essays that were published as policy reports during the 1980s, and includes detailed financial in-
formation on several public stadium projects. Johnson (1995) provides a collection of case studies of minor league
baseball stadium development projects.
8
3.1. Summary of evidence from metropolitan area data. Studies analyzing the economic
impact of professional sports on metropolitan areas report little evidence of strong economic impacts
in urban areas home to major-league teams. While not surprising in light of the clear importance
of displacement effects, the empirical evidence clearly contradicts common claims of large tangible
benefits from hosting sports activities made by subsidy proponents.
While large metropolitan area wide economic effects from sports venues do not appear to
exist, areas in close proximity to stadiums and arenas may experience hosting spillovers that are not
apparent in aggregate city and region level data. Even if localized impacts occur, the assumption
that sports commerce has positive spillovers on surrounding businesses is naı̈ve, because stadiums
can either foster or hinder different types of economic development, depending on the specific
characteristics of the host community. While policy debates typically focus on positive externalities,
researchers also identifies negative spillovers. Even if localized net effects are positive (or negative)
the distribution of the impacts on different sectors is important, because stadium subsidies typically
come from broader municipal and state tax jurisdictions.
12
4.1. Local business location and activity. Harger et al. (2016) examines the impact of new
stadiums on nearby business establishments in 10 US cities in the 2000s. Difference-in-difference
estimates do not identify any strong effects on the number of new businesses or employment in
general; however, the authors estimate small positive effects on employment at eating and drink-
ing establishments within one mile of the stadiums. These localized findings are consistent with
13
4.2. Local sales. Economists also use local sales and sales tax collections data to estimate eco-
nomic effects of hosting teams and opening new facilities. If sports events generate net-new revenue,
then this should be evident in changes in local purchases, as external consumers transfer their spend-
ing to the host jurisdiction. It is somewhat surprising that economists have not analyzed sales or
sales tax revenues more often to estimate the economic effects of sports events, because most local
jurisdictions raise revenue through sales taxes and collect detailed data on sales and sales taxes.
Existing studies in this literature tend to fall into one three groups.
The first group of studies analyzes impacts of hosting specific sports events plausibly asso-
ciated with a game day influx of visitor spending generated by sports events. Though they do not
all focus on the impact of the presence of professional sports teams, the findings are informative
in terms of the impact of hosting sports on local sales since the other sporting events analyzed
also attract large numbers of fans on game day. Coates (2006) identifies positive impacts on local
14
4.3. Hotels occupancy and room rates. New sports venues are often touted as important
catalysts for tourism, generating new spending by visiting patrons who would otherwise not consume
local goods and services. Data from individual hotels offers a setting in which to identify spending
by visitors who travel to a city to attend games.
Lavoie and Rodrı́guez (2005) uses the Box-Jenkins method to identify impacts of several
league work stoppages on hotel occupancy aggregated to the city level in eight Canadian cities
during the 1990s, when the cities also experienced team departures and arrivals. The results do
not support the existence of strong impacts of sports on hotel occupancy, though three cities did
experience declines in hotel stays during the 1994-1995 lockout.
16
17
4.4. Summary of localized development effects. Though studies identify some localized pos-
itive effects near sports facilities, such findings are not ubiquitous in the literature. In general,
when positive effects exist, they occur very close to venues, within one or two miles, and in sectors
closely related to sports consumption (e.g., food and beverage). This pattern in the results strongly
supports the predictions made by the model developed by Humphreys and Zhou (2015b). The ef-
fects likely differ across types of sports facilities and events because of pre-existing characteristics
that may or may not complement sports-focused economic development. A key lesson from this
literature is that even at the most spatially disaggregated levels, positive economic development
effects are not guaranteed, and positive spillovers appear to manifest only in favorable commercial
environments. The findings also highlight the potential for negative externalities that may deter
business formation, not a prominent argument in public policy debates over stadium subsidies. We
further discuss this point in Section 6. Overall, the evidence indicates limited localized economic
development halos from stadiums and arenas.
Even if sports teams and venues do not generate tangible local economic benefits, public
subsidies could be justified if local residents receive sufficient intangible social benefits from their
18
5.1. Contingent Valuation Method. Noting that governments often justify funding new sta-
dium projects because sports teams generate large positive externalities, Johnson and Whitehead
(2000), in a seminal study, use the contingent valuation method (CVM), a stated preference ap-
proach, to measure how much residents value the presence of local sports teams in the context of two
proposed new sports facilities. Environmental economists developed CVM to quantify individuals’
nonuse value of environmental assets. In this literature, nonuse value refers to intangible benefits
generated by the presence of environmental assets that individuals may or may not consume or
directly experience. Environmental assets valued using CVM include wilderness areas, national
parks, endangered species, and others. CVM employs survey questions designed to elicit individual
preferences objectively for non-priced goods in hypothetical settings. In the case of sports facilities,
CVM studies focus on a different hypothetical: proposed new sports facilities.
Johnson and Whitehead (2000) use surveys of households in Lexington, Kentucky to esti-
mate a nonuse value of a minor-league baseball team and a college basketball team. In this setting,
estimated nonuse value represents a small portion of residents’ willingness to pay for host sports
facilities (10 and 30 percent, respectively), which was not sufficient to justify the estimated public
cost of constructing the venues.Similarly, Johnson et al. (2001) use CVM to estimate the nonuse
value of Pittsburgh hosting the NHL’s Penguins, finding the nonuse value to be 73 percent of the
total willingness to pay for a new stadium for the team. The estimated nonuse value ($17.2–$48.3
19
7
Swindell et al. (2008) emphasizes the importance of the estimated positive nonuse value ($60-85 million), but that
estimate falls well below the public subsidy ($650 million) provided to build the new sports facility analyzed, Lucas
Oil Stadium in 2008.
20
5.2. Property values. Carlino and Coulson (2004) observe that any external benefits and costs
generated by professional sports teams in cities ought to be capitalized into residential property val-
ues: “If people like having a professional sports franchise in their community, they are presumably
willing to pay for it, if not directly through the purchase of season tickets, then indirectly through
an increased willingness to pay for housing in the area” (p. 27). This hypothesis derives from
Tiebout (1956) and Oates (1969), who argue that spillover benefits and costs of publicly-provided
services should be reflected in local property values. Unlike survey-based evidence from CVM stud-
ies, property values reflect revealed preferences. Also, the model developed by Humphreys and
Zhou (2015b) predicts that sports facilities will affect nearby residential property values.
Carlino and Coulson (2004) estimate an hedonic housing pricing model accounting for home
and city characteristics in several large US metropolitan areas including indicator variables that
identify the presence of NFL and MLB teams. The estimates indicate an eight-percent increase
in rental prices in cities home to NFL teams, with stronger central city impacts. MLB teams are
associated with increased rents in suburban areas. However, Carlino and Coulson (2004) report
wages are two percent lower in NFL cities, which the authors interpret as a compensating differential
that residents are willing to pay to cover the costs of hosting an NFL team. The authors conclude
that their results “are substantial evidence that the quality-of-life benefits associated with hosting
an NFL team may justify the seemingly large public expenditures” (p.48).
21
22
23
8
Wembley Stadium (£900 million) was largely privately funded (£600 million), with public contributions from the Na-
tional Lottery (£120 million), Department of Culture, Media, and Sport (£20 million) and the London Development
Agency (£21 million), while Emirates Stadium (£390 million) was privately funded (Conn 2018).
25
5.3. Voter preferences. Evidence of important intangible benefits may also be discovered through
the democratic process, as stadium subsidy projects often must be approved by voter referenda.
Voting permits residents to reveal preferences for stadium benefits and costs that are not captured
in markets for sports consumption. In addition, patterns in the spatial distribution of votes provides
information as to how the community perceives and values any proximity-related intangible benefits.
Of course, referendum voting has a well-known problem: the setting of reversion levels in
votes that generally leads to passage of the referendum. Fort (1999) highlights the importance of this
in the case of referenda on stadium subsidies. Consequently, while some direct-democracy stadium
initiatives fail, most succeed, which may reflect a local willingness-to-pay for sports activities (Brown
and Paul 2002) or strategic setting of the referendum reversion level.
Coates and Humphreys (2006) analyzes voting patterns for stadium initiatives in Green Bay,
Wisconsin (NFL, 2000) and Houston, Texas (NBA, 1999 and 2000), finding a positive association
between voter proximity to the facility in Green Bay and support for a subsidy for renovation of a
stadium but no relationship in Houston. This pattern in the results suggests that residents most
likely to experience venue spillovers were more willing to fund the cost of projects, consistent with
sub-local agglomeration effects being positively associated with proximity to the facility.
26
5.4. Consumer surplus estimates. Finally, two relatively old papers estimate the consumer sur-
plus generated by the presence of teams in cities based on observed game ticket prices. Monopoly
teams cannot fully capture consumer willingness to pay to attend games, and the remaining con-
sumer surplus reflects the willingness to pay to attend games by fans and, under certain conditions,
the value of public goods benefits generated by sports teams. Since teams cannot fully capture
this fan willingness to pay, teams may not be willing to enter markets with substantial consumer
27
5.5. Summary of intangible benefits. Economists have identified intangible benefits from sta-
diums hosting professional sports teams using several empirical methods, a notable accomplishment
28
While most debates about sports-driven economic development focus on direct economic
impacts and potential positive spillovers, research also identifies considerable negative effects in
cities hosting sports events. Estimates of small, limited positive effects appear in the literature and
frequently come up in the public debate on subsidies. Hosting games generates nuisances as well
as potential benefits. The substantial and robust evidence of negative effects almost never appears
in these policy debates. Gameday activities can benefit some nearby businesses and residents,
but may also generate disamenities for others. The influx of consumers on game day also brings
29
6.1. Crime. Crime is the most extensively studied and documented negative externality gener-
ated by hosting games. Sports are associated with aggressive fan behavior, frequently combined
with alcohol consumption that may catalyze criminal conduct. Marie (2016) develops a conceptual
framework identifying three main channels through which sports may impact crime: the concen-
tration of hostile fans, in which fans gather to become targets of or commit crimes; displacement of
police to monitor game day events and maintain order and safety; and incapacitation of potential
criminals who attend or watch games rather than commit crimes. Using crime data from London
boroughs that hosted soccer matches in the mid-1990s, Marie (2016) identifies increases in property
crimes in boroughs hosting matches. Crime in boroughs home to travelling teams falls during away
matches. This combination of effects highlights the role of displacement of police and incapacita-
tion of criminals on crime in communities. In total, the findings indicate hosting games appears to
increase property crime against local residents.
The positive association between crime and sporting events is perhaps the most robust
empirical finding in the economic effects of sports literature.9 Using a variety of empirical methods,
economists clearly identify positive relationships between hosting sports games and crimes in many
settings. We briefly discuss several prominent studies in this literature to summarize consensus
findings. Researchers identified a positive relationship between hosting sports events and crime for
games played by MLB teams (Mares and Blackburn 2019; Pyun 2019), NBA and college basketball
teams (Yu et al. 2016), NFL teams (Kalist and Lee 2016), NHL teams (Block 2021), college football
teams (Rees and Schnepel 2009), English soccer clubs (Marie 2016), and Spanish soccer clubs
(Montolio and Planells-Struse 2016, 2019). Propheter (2020a) finds larger displacement effects in
9
Baumann et al. (2012) is an exception that finds no impact of sports teams on annual MSA crime rates, but there is
little expectation that the presence of teams should affect city-wide crime rates over the course of a year, especially
if sports events reallocate crime within the region.
30
6.2. Health, traffic, and pollution. A less obvious spillover from hosting sports games is pol-
lution from congestion when residents travel to games, which contributes to road traffic and air
pollution. Congested roads inflict time costs and may be a detriment to public health, particularly
for residents with respiratory ailments. Humphreys and Pyun (2018) examines the impact of MLB
game attendance on time spent in traffic, and finds a positive effect. The estimates indicate that
an MSA with average MLB attendance experiences approximately five million additional miles
traveled—which represents just over half-of-one percent of total vehicle-miles traveled—and 28,000
hours per year in delayed traffic. Using air emissions cost of congestion (Mashayekh et al. 2011),
this translates to $7 million per year in social costs from added CO2 emissions.
Locke (2019) analyzes variation in the daily average concentrations and air quality indices
for several common atmospheric pollutants, and identifies a small negative impact of games on air
quality. However, though the estimate is statistically significant, the magnitude of the relationship
is so small that the damage has little practical significance. Humphreys and Ruseski (2019) identify
effects from new stadium construction on infant birth weights. Estimates indicate that between
31
6.3. Summary of negative externalities. Researcher reveals strong evidence of negative spillovers
in cities that host sports events. In particular, hosting games is associated with increased criminal
activity, which may generate considerable costs to area residents and businesses. Other nuisance
externalities from congestion, pollution, and public health have also been identified as potential
harmful byproducts of sports games. These externalities also imply substantial negative external
costs. Policy discussions about the appropriateness of subsidies for new professional sports facil-
ities should include the potential costs and consequences of negative externalities generated by
professional sports, and not focus solely on positive direct and indirect impacts.
7. Anti-consensus arguments
Though most research in this literature does not support the contention that hosting sports
teams generates large economic impacts on local communities, some important exceptions should
must be acknowledged. Skeptics of the consensus in economic research documented above frequently
argue that economic outcomes typically used to quantify the impact of sports do not fully capture
important holistic, difficult to measure benefits. If stadiums provide unique physical capital that
promotes a healthy downtown, for example business and/or entertainment districts, this also may
strengthen the commercial and social reputations of host communities, a potentially important but
difficult to quantify outcome. The main idea behind these criticisms posits that research focused on
common quantifiable economic outcomes (e.g., income, employment, and output) does not capture
theses other benefits. Important, undetected long-run development effects generated by professional
32
33
10Rosentraub’s book was originally published in 2009, and it was significantly revised and published under a new
title in 2014.
35
After decades of study, clear and unambiguous evidence shows that sports stadiums and
arenas do not generate strong economic development benefits on host communities. The contrast
between the strong consensus null or negative findings of sports venues on local economies in peer
reviewed academic research coupled with the continued and growing public subsidization of these
facilities creates a seeming paradox: If sports stadiums are not potent drivers of local economic
activity, then why do federal, state, and local governments continue to subsidize sports venues in
economic development projects?
Politicians clearly appear to be more amenable to subsidizing professional sports than other
businesses, as the public contribution to sports stadiums and arenas is large relative to other
business incentives. Bartik (2019) reports that the average business incentive provided by US state
and local governments is equivalent to subsidizing three percent of a firm’s wages for 20 years (p.
11). By comparison, the $300 million subsidy to fund Truist Park as the home of the Atlanta Braves
in 2017, a typical example among modern sports facility subsidies, represents approximately eleven
37
8.1. Concentrated benefits and dispersed costs. A common political economy explanation
for the prevalence of venue subsidies is the asymmetric bargaining power among interest group con-
stituencies. When subsidy benefits are distributed among a few interested parties, but the tax costs
are dispersed widely across an entire polity, the former has a bargaining advantage that will likely
yield more favorable political outcomes. The beneficiaries of sports subsidies are heavily concen-
trated: team owners and proprietors of few complementary activities (e.g., hospitality, recreation,
client development, etc.) reap much of the benefits from the hundreds of millions of dollars in venue
subsidies. Public funding is spread among a jurisdiction’s taxpayers, with each taxpayer bearing a
small share of the tax burden.
Even though stadium subsidies may lower the welfare of the average resident, the cost is
shared so broadly that individual costs may be small enough (e.g., Baltimore’s Camden Yards
annual tax cost amounted to $15 per local household (Hamilton and Kahn 1997)) that it is not
worthwhile for voters to organize opposition. In this case, the small group of beneficiaries devote
greater resources to promoting stadium subsidies through lobbying and public relations campaigns
than the opposition. In addition, residents who value sports teams tend to have strong preferences
in favor subsidizing local teams, which enhances the organizational power of pro-stadium voter
constituencies (Groothuis et al. 2004). sports facility subsidies may be a foregone conclusion based
on rational political incentives faced by both voters and organized interests.
Though a rational ignorance/submission explanation provides intuitive appeal, it is not suf-
ficient to explain why stadium subsidies persist and grow. Perhaps this explanation was appealing
prior to the 2000s, when the academic consensus was less apparent and research results were not
11Estimated based on reported team payroll from 2017 to 2021, assuming the same average annual increase in payroll
(1.5 percent) over the next 15 years.
38
8.2. Bargaining, outside options, and loss aversion. Humphreys and Zhou (2015a) approach
the sports facility subsidy issue as a bargaining process between team owners and local officials
acting on behalf of taxpayers. While not a formal bargaining process like the collective bargaining
12For example, billionaire Richard Scaife played a significant role in organizing “one of the most effective opposition
campaigns” for a stadium initiative in Pittsburgh (Delaney and Eckstein 2003b, p. 199), and he also donated to
many prominent conservative and libertarian advocacy groups that frequently oppose stadium subsidies around
the US.
39
8.3. High-profile advocacy reports. A common counterargument used against the consensus
findings on the inefficacy of sports stadiums in promoting economic development involves commis-
sion of a private consulting study to generate favorable findings in terms of forecasted economic
benefits. Stadium boosters often hire consultants to conduct economic or fiscal impact analyses
that demonstrate the proposed sports development will generate large returns to the community
through increased economic activity, creating jobs and wealth in the community while growing the
tax base to pay for itself through increased tax collections. These reports are part of what Coates
and Humphreys (2008) describe as a “promotional literature.” These reports are often released
at the same time the stadium project is announced, because economic development justifications
are persuasive in fostering favorable public perceptions of sports facility subsidies (Connolly and
41
42
43
8.4. Local growth coalitions and the media. Research by sociologists Kevin Delaney and
Rick Eckstein highlights the importance of influential local insiders in promoting stadium subsidies.
Using in-depth interviews with local officials in nine cities seeking stadium subsidies during the 1990s
and 2000s, Delaney and Eckstein (2003b) observe that sports teams typically did not lead the public
fight for the subsidies they received.13 This observation is not consistent with the concentrated
benefits and dispersed costs hypothesis, because the chief beneficiary of these subsidies are team
owners. The interviews reveal the importance of “local growth coalitions” in successfully garnering
stadium subsidies. Sociologist Jay Scherer similarly identifies the importance of a “boosterish”
local coalition in overcoming opposition to a subsidy for a new NHL arena in Edmonton, Alberta
in the early 2010s (Scherer 2016).
Delaney and Eckstein find local growth coalitions tend to derive from a pre-existing institu-
tional alliance between the local corporate community and local government, which is largely run by
business leaders (e.g., chambers of commerce and groups of local CEOs), but it may include other
community members, such as politicians, government officials, and members of religious, labor,
and media organizations. Though sports franchises are the chief beneficiaries of these subsidies,
they rarely play a major role in these coalitions. These groups have a strong influence over all
local development policy, which they use to serve their parochial interests. Their detachment from
sports franchises permits them to portray their stadium advocacy as being in the best interests
of the overall community, and thus their support influences voters. In an environment where the
voting public is largely ignorant of the complicated finances of stadium projects, team owners can
rely on, or subtly collaborate with, community leaders to build support for subsidies.
Coalition members likely see sports as a way to foster their own interests, such as client
development and employee recruitment, even if there is not an economic payoff to the wider com-
munity. CEOs use sports as a tool for attracting top executives and qualified workers, for whom
the presence of a local team is a desirable quality or signal of available local amenities. While the
returns are not sufficient to self-fund a stadium project by coalition members, as long as the tax
burden is shared with the general public, the group is willing to support and use their influence
13The nine cities studied are Cincinnati, Cleveland, Denver, Hartford, Minneapolis, Pittsburgh, Philadelphia,
Phoenix, and San Diego.
44
8.4.1. Favorable local media coverage. Aligning with politicians and local growth coalitions, often
through local media outlets, clearly represents a successful strategy for promoting stadium subsidy
initiatives. After reviewing how media coverage impacted several stadium campaigns for public
funding, Delaney and Eckstein (2008) conclude “that the local media’s approach can more proac-
tively shape and frame the public’s perception of a stadium initiative and, all other things being
equal, significantly affect the outcomes of these initiatives for better or for worse” (p. 91).
Delaney and Eckstein (2008) observe that “an uncritical media often becomes the primary
institutional booster of stadium projects in cities with a weak growth coalition” (p.72). Media
members may see sports teams as complementary products: residents are more willing to subscribe
to local newspapers or watch local broadcasts if they are covering a local team. News media can
contribute to public misperceptions of the project by not accurately conveying costs and benefits
to consumers, or some members may become active advocates for promoting stadium projects,
effectively participating in the local growth coalition. In their research they find: “For the most part,
45
8.5. Political pandering. Jensen and Malesky (2018) develop a theoretical framework grounded
in the political science literature for understanding a related paradox plaguing local economic
development policy, equally applicable to stadium subsidies. Just as elected representatives tend to
support subsidizing sports teams and events, politicians often openly promote the use of economic
development incentives to attract businesses despite strong evidence of the ineffectiveness of such
policies and the fact that most do not pass a cost-benefit test. While rent seeking through campaign
donations or other forms of political support—including nefarious exchanges—may play a role,
it does not appear to be a major driver in determining economic development policy. These
agreements and relationships are not hidden behind closed doors; instead, they are promoted openly
and celebrated at press conferences, where politicians claim direct responsibility.
Jensen and Malesky (2018) present an alternate hypothesis: politicians pander to voters
by taking credit for attracting desirable new businesses when voters are largely unaware or uncer-
tain about the true costs and benefits of the development deal. They find that US voters tend
to support politicians who seek to attract businesses, even when they fail to accomplish state
goals. Even though elected representatives are likely aware of the negative cost-benefit calculus,
re-election-maximizing politicians have the incentive to exploit voter rational ignorance on the value
of economic development projects by supporting economically inefficient projects and policies.
Though the pandering theory was constructed to explain the continuing disbursement of
inefficient economic development incentives, its framework is generalizable to stadium subsidies
and complements the Delaney and Eckstein (2003b) local growth coalition model. Sports venues
are large visible projects that support an activity that is viewed favorably by the public, and local
politicians are in positions where they can take credit for the development. By aligning with a
community of local insiders, franchise owners may be able to persuade elected representatives and
46
8.6. Why do local governments continue to subsidize sports venues? Perhaps no line
of inquiry in research on public funding of sports stadiums has proved more unsatisfying than
the search to understand why local governments continue to fund stadium projects in the face of
overwhelming evidence that these subsidies are poor investments. The public funding paradox has
long eluded a clear, satisfying explanation. The question is not new, either. In 1997, Noll and
Zimbalist (1997) asked, “if stadiums are poor investments, why, in the era of limited government
skepticism about the nature of public construction projects, are expensive stadiums still being
subsidized?” (p. viii). The conjecture at the time was that local politics and sports teams bargaining
power offer explanations. Though political and bargaining incentives are no doubt important
contributors, they are not sufficient to explain the prevalence and dissemination of public funding.
The limited progress and study in this area is concerning given the policy relevance discussed in
Section 2. The role of influential local interest groups and leaders, like those identified by Delaney
and Eckstein (2003b) and Jensen and Malesky (2018), are difficult to observe and quantify using
common empirical methods employed by economists; yet, they appear to be an important causal
influence. Research in this area demonstrates the potential of qualitative research methods for
studying stadium subsidies may offer insight that existing attempts to understand the widespread
use of taxpayer funding to construct stadiums.
9. Conclusion
This comprehensive review of the literature on the impact of sports teams and venues on
local communities identifies several key findings. Empirical research progressed from early studies
of metropolitan areas using multiple regression analysis to rigourous event and case study methods
designed to infer causal effects accounting for multiple confounding factors. Even as empirical
methods improved, the findings remained largely consistent across this broad and vibrant literature.
Our review yields three main conclusions.
First, and perhaps most important, nearly all empirical studies find little to no tangible
impacts of sports teams and facilities on local economic activity, and the level of venue subsidies
typically provided far exceeds any observed economic benefits. In total, the deep agreement in re-
search findings demonstrates that sports venues are not an appropriate channel for local economic
47
49
Abadie, Alberto (2021) “Using synthetic controls: feasibility, data requirements, and methodolog-
ical aspects,” Journal of Economic Literature, 59 (2), 391–425.
Agha, Nola (2013) “The economic impact of atadiums and teams: the case of minor league base-
ball,” Journal of Sports Economics, 14 (3), 227–252.
Agha, Nola and Dennis Coates (2015) “A compensating differential approach to valuing the social
benefit of minor league baseball,” Contemporary Economic Policy, 33 (2), 285–299.
Agha, Nola and Daniel Rascher (2021) “Economic development effects of major and minor league
teams and stadiums,” Journal of Sports Economics, 22 (3), 274–294.
Ahlfeldt, Gabriel M and Georgios Kavetsos (2014) “Form or function?: the effect of new sports
stadia on property prices in London,” Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Series A (Statistics
in Society), 177 (1), 169–190.
Ahlfeldt, Gabriel M. and Wolfgang Maennig (2010) “Impact of sports arenas on land values: evi-
dence from Berlin,” The Annals of Regional Science, 44 (2), 205–227.
(2012) “Voting on a NIMBY facility: proximity cost of an “iconic” stadium,” Urban Affairs
Review, 48 (2), 205–237.
Alexander, D.L., W. Kern, and J. Neill (2000) “Valuing the consumption benefits from professional
sports franchises,” Journal of Urban Economics, 48 (2), 321–337.
Alexander, Donald L, William Kern, and Jon Neill (2000) “Valuing the consumption benefits from
professional sports franchises,” Journal of Urban Economics, 48 (2), 321–337.
Arif, Imran, Adam Hoffer, Brad R. Humphreys, and Matthew Style (in press) “New sports facilities
do not drive migration between US cities,” Economics of Governance, forthcoming (1), 1–20.
Austrian, Ziona and Mark S. Rosentraub (2002) “Cities, sports, and economic change: a retrospec-
tive assessment,” Journal of Urban Affairs, 24 (5), 549–563.
Baade, Robert A. (1996) “Professional sports as catalysts for metropolitan economic development,”
Journal of Urban Affairs, 18 (1), 1–17.
Baade, Robert A., Robert W. Baumann, , and Victor A. Matheson (2008) “Selling the game:
estimating the economic impact of professional sports through taxable sales,” Southern Economic
Journal, 74 (3), 794–810.
(2011) “Big men on campus: estimating the economic impact of college sports on local
economies,” Regional Studies, 45 (3), 371–380.
50
52
56
58
59
61
62
Table A1. Economic studies of sports venues and teams (chronological order)
needs.”
Baade (1996) Teams/ Impact of teams/ venues on MSAs (48) 1958-1987 Income per capita (0); City’s share
Venues economic activity. Multiple (30 years) of state employment in recreation/
regression (separate and sports (0).
pooled OLS estimates).
Chema (1996) Teams/ Reply to Baade (1996). Baade (1996) does not properly
Venues account for modern stadiums
incorporated into urban growth
strategies.
Noll and Zimbalist (1997) Survey Collected volume of studies. 15 chapters Various “In every case, the authors find
on various that the local economic impact of
subjects sports teams and facilities is far
smaller than proponents allege; in
some cases it is negative.”
Statistically significant (+/-) or null (0) findings in parentheses.
Table A1. (continued)
Coates and Humphreys (1999) Teams/ Impact of venue/teams on MSAs (37) 1967-1994 Income per capita: level (–),
Venues economic activity. Multiple (28 years) growth (0).
regression (random effects).
Hudson (1999) Teams/ Impact of teams/ venues on MSAs (17) (20 years) Employment (0).
Venues employment. Multiple
regression (fixed effects).
Porter (1999) Survey Survey of contracted Counties 1979-1996 Sales (0).
economic impact reports. (6) (6 Super
Multiple Regression. Bowls)
Alexander et al. (2000) Consumer Non-econometric estimate of All pro 1996 Substantial evidence of CS in
surplus CS using gate revenue data sports sports attendance markets
teams
Johnson and Whitehead (2000) Option CVM mail survey regarding Households 1997 Nonuse value is small portion of
Value college basketball and (230) willingness to pay.
minor-league baseball venues
in Fayette County, Kentucky.
Statistically significant (+/-) or null (0) findings in parentheses.
Table A1. (continued)
sports-focused downtown
development strategies.
Chapin (2002) Teams/ Case study of San Diego’s San Diego’s 1998-2004 “[T]he City of San Diego’s Ballpark
Venues MLB stadium development Petco Park Project serves as a potential model
project as an example of develop- for realizing downtown
“municipal capitalism.” ment redevelopment through investments
Descriptive. in large activity generators like
sports facilities.”
Coates and Humphreys (2002) Teams/ Impact of post-season MSAs (37) 1969-1997 Income per capita: Post-season
67
Lavoie and Rodrı́guez (2005) Hotels Impact of work stoppages Canadian 1990-1999 Hotel occupancy: NHL strike (–).
and team arrivals/departures cities (8) (120
on hotel occupancy in months)
Canada. Box-Jenkins method
(separate cities).
Long (2005) Venue Estimates true public cost of Stadiums & 1912-2001 After accounting for routinely
Funding sports venues by including arenas (99) unreported costs—land,
costs normally omitted from infrastructure, operations, capital
public subsidy calculations. improvements, municipal services,
and foregone property
taxes—public subsidies are 40%
higher than reported subsidies.
Santo (2005) Teams/ Impact of teams/ venues on MSAs (19) 1984-2001 Aggregate income: Baseball
Venues economic activity. Multiple (18 years) stadium (+), Baseball team (–).
regression (separate and Regional share of income: Baseball
pooled OLS estimates). stadium(+).
Statistically significant (+/-) or null (0) findings in parentheses.
Table A1. (continued)
difference-in-differences
estimation strategy.
Carlino and Coulson (2006) Property Reply to Coates et al. (2006). CMSAs 1993 and Not persuaded by Coates et al.
Values (53) 1999 (2 (2006).
years)
Coates (2006) Local Sales Impact of hosting Super Houston 1991-2006 Both events: Monthly sales tax
Bowl and MLB All-Star (182 revenue (+); Quarterly (total,
Game on local sales. months); retail, and service) sales (0).
1991-2005
70
(60
quarters)
Coates and Humphreys (2006) Voter Impact of proximity to Green Bay Green Bay: Referendum support and stadium
Preferences stadium sites and referendum (89 2000 , proximity (–).
support. Multiple regression precincts), Houston:
(OLS). Houston 1999 &
(894 & 914 2000
precincts)
Coates et al. (2006) Property Comment on Carlino and CMSAs 1993 and Findings not robust to alternate
Values Coulson (2004). (53) 1999 (2) model specifications.
Johnson et al. (2006) Option Examines temporal Households 2002 Willingness to pay is sensitive to
Value embedding and ordering (421 ) payment period length. Limited
effects in CVM survey (see evidence of weak ordering effects.
Johnson et al. (2007)).
Statistically significant (+/-) or null (0) findings in parentheses.
Table A1. (continued)
Santo (2007) Option CVM telephone survey of Adults 2005 Majority of residents not willing to
Value Portland residents regarding (365) pay higher taxes to fund stadium.
public funding for MLB
stadium.
Walker and Mondello (2007) Option Reviews relevant concerns for “CVM represents an important
Value researchers employing CVM component of economic valuation
to estimate nonuse value of . . . [that] can be applicable to
sports activities. recreation, environment, and sport.
. . . Several authors have questioned
its validity, reliability, and survey
techniques. However, with some
refinement and continued
application, CVM could prove a
useful valuation tool in the future.”
Statistically significant (+/-) or null (0) findings in parentheses.
Table A1. (continued)
things.”
Dehring et al. (2008) Voter Impact of stadium property Homes 2004 Referendum support and property
Preferences values effects and home (3,108) values (+); Referendum support
ownership on stadium and home ownership (–).
referendum support in
Arlington, TX. Hedonic price
model.
Delaney and Eckstein (2008) Venue Explores media’s role in Stadiums mid-1990s - “A relatively critical media can
Funding policy debates over stadium projects 2008 seriously impede a stadium project
subsidies. Case studies. (23) in . . . when the local growth coalition
cities (16) is weak . . . [A]n uncritical media
often becomes the primary
institutional booster of stadium
projects in cities with a weak
growth coalition” (p. 72).
Statistically significant (+/-) or null (0) findings in parentheses.
Table A1. (continued)
effects).
Swindell et al. (2008) Option CVM telephone survey of Households 2004 Nonuse value positive ($60-85
Value Indiana residents regarding (865) million), but not sufficient to cover
how much they value hosting subsidy ($650 million).
NFL’s Colts.
Depken and Coates (2011) Local Sales Impact of hosting big college Cities (4) 1984-2008 Games and sales tax revenue (0).
football games in Texas cities (290
(Austin, College Station, months)
Lubbock, Waco). Multiple
74
regression.
Fenn and Crooker (2009) Option CVM mail survey of State & 2002 Nonuse value not sufficient to cover
Value Minnesota and MSA (1,200 subsidy.
Minneapolis-St. Paul MSA households,
regarding NFL’s Minnesota 565
Vikings during a relocation responses)
threat.
Rees and Schnepel (2009) Crime Impact of college football Reported 2000-2005 Assaults (+); Vandalism (+);
games on crime in campus offenses (14,926 Alcohol-related (+).
police jurisdictions. Multiple (26) days; 1,516
regression (negative game days)
binomial).
(Rosentraub 2009, 2014) Teams/ Case studies of sports as Cities (6) Various “As investments, the tax dollars
Venues local development policy. expended for venues have generated
Descriptive. (2 editions) positive net financial returns.”
Statistically significant (+/-) or null (0) findings in parentheses.
Table A1. (continued)
Erie et al. (2010) Teams/ Assesses public-private San Diego’s 1998-2004 “In all, the ballpark project has
Venues partnership relating to San Petco Park been a net drain on the city’s
Diego MLB stadium. develop- . . . finances . . . San Diego’s
Descriptive case study. ment partnership with the Padres has
mostly benefitted . . . Padres’ owner
John Moores [from] public
subsidies and East Village
development rights . . . San Diego
taxpayers, . . . have been left to
absorb the fiscal fallout.”
75
Baade et al. (2011) Local Sales Impact of hosting college MSAs (2) 1979-2007 Basketball (0); Football (+)
basketball and football games (340
on taxable sales in Florida months)
(Gainesville, Tallahassee ).
Multiple regression (separate
OLS estimates per MSA).
Castellanos et al. (2011) Option CVM personal interview Metro-area 2003 Nonuse value sufficient to cover
Value survey of A Coruña, Spain adults replacement stadium but not
residents regarding the (739) support club.
nonuse value of local soccer
club.
Depken and Coates (2011) Local Sales Impact of various sports Texas cities 1990-2008 Mixed findings for most events (0);
teams, events, stadiums on (23) (216 Championship games (+).
sales tax revenue. Multiple months)
regression (fixed effects).
Statistically significant (+/-) or null (0) findings in parentheses.
Table A1. (continued)
Baumann et al. (2012) Crime Impact of major-league MSAs (56) 1981-2006 MSA annual crime rate: Teams
teams and mega-events on (24 years) (0), Olympics (+), Super Bowl (–).
annual crime rate. Multiple
regression (fixed effects).
Cantor and Rosentraub (2012) Teams/ Case study of San Diego’s San Diego’s 1998-2009 “[L]ooking at economic integration,
Venues MLB stadium development Petco Park the stability of home prices, and
project. Descriptive. develop- the attraction of educated people
ment to a city’s center, the Ballpark
District should be considered a
success.”
Feng and Humphreys (2012) Teams/ Impact of proximity to sports Census 1990 & Proximity and property values (+).
Venues venue at census block level. blocks: 2000 (2
Hedonic multiple regression 1990 years)
pricing model of (28,500);
cross-sections. 2000
(30,346)
Statistically significant (+/-) or null (0) findings in parentheses.
Table A1. (continued)
(339)
Propheter (2012) Teams/ Impact of NBA teams/arenas MSA (24) 1979-2009 Regional income (0). Income per
Venues on personal income. Multiple (31 years) capita: All, 1988-1994 (+);
regression (separate and fixed NBA-only, 1985-2009 (+),
and random effects). 2001-2009 (–); Multi-sport (0).
Agha (2013) Teams/ Impact of minor-league MSAs (238) 1985-2006 Income per capita (+).
Venues baseball teams on income per (22 years)
capita. Multiple regression
(fixed effects).
77
Long (2013) Venue Examines the public costs of Major- 1876-2010 Provides extensive summary of
Funding professional sports facilities. league trends in public financing of sports
Descriptive. sports venues, using detailed cost
venues accounting.
Ahlfeldt and Kavetsos (2014) Property Impact of proximity to Residential 1995-2008 Proximity and property values (+).
Values London soccer stadiums. property
Hedonic price model, sales:
difference-in-differences. Wembley
(5,263),
Arsenal
(9,933)
Huang and Humphreys (2014) Property Impact of new stadiums on Census 1992-2010 Proximity and residential
Values residential mortgage tracts (19) mortgages (+), but much of it
applications. (45,000) in likely would have occurred without
Difference-in-differences. MSAs (56) the stadium.
Statistically significant (+/-) or null (0) findings in parentheses.
Table A1. (continued)
Propheter (2014) Local Sales Impact of MLS stadium Municipal 2005-2010 Sales tax revenue: Bridgeview (0),
opening in Bridgeville, IL on govern- (128 Other municipalities (0, mixed).
sale tax revenue of host and ments (168) months)
surrounding municipalities.
Multiple regression (fixed
effects).
Agha and Coates (2015) Teams/ Impact of minor-league teams MSAs (138) 1993-2005 Housing rents in mid-sized
Venues on residential rents. Multiple (13 years) markets: MLB affiliates (+6-8%),
regression (fixed effects). Independent (0).
78
Coates (2015) Teams/ Impact of venue/teams on MSA (366) 1969-2011 Multiple estimates: Income (0, –),
Venues economic activity. Multiple (42 years) Wages (0, –).
regression (fixed and random
effects).
Horn et al. (2015) Voter Impact of proximity to NFL Precincts 1997 Referendum support and stadium
Preferences stadium and referendum (2,500) proximity (–, inverted U-shape).
support in King County, WA.
Multiple regression (LP and
group logit estimates).
Humphreys and Zhou (2015b) Teams/ Theoretical model of how Sports franchises use territorial
Venues teams use relocation threats monopolies to exploit resident
to extract public subsidies. reference-dependent loss averse
preferences to extract public
subsidies.
Statistically significant (+/-) or null (0) findings in parentheses.
Table A1. (continued)
respectively. There is no
generalized positive or negative
outcome, on net.
Harger et al. (2016) Business Impact of new stadiums on Nearby 2002 & Establishments (0). Employment:
Activity local business activity. establish- 2006 (2nd General (0), Eating/drinking (+,
Difference-in-differences. ments: quarter) within 1 mile).
census
tracts
(7,996) in
MSAs (10)
79
Kalist and Lee (2016) Crime Impact of NFL games on NFL cities 2004-2006 Home games and crime (+).
local crime. Multiple (8) (9,496
regression (OLS/Negative days)
binomial).
Marie (2016) Crime Impact of soccer matches on London 1994-1997 Home: Property crime (+), Violent
neighborhood crime in boroughs (1,147 crime (–). Away crime (–).
London. Multiple regression (7) hosing game-time
(negative binomial fixed soccer observa-
effects). teams (9) tions)
Montolio and Planells-Struse (2016) Crime Impact of FC Barcelona Crimes per 2004-2011 Thefts (+); Criminal damage (+);
matches on temporal aspects hour on (29,121 Robberies (+); Gender Violence
of crime. Multiple regression game days hours) (+).
(negative binomial).
Statistically significant (+/-) or null (0) findings in parentheses.
Table A1. (continued)
Depken and Stephenson (2018) Hotels Impact of sports and other Hotel 2005-2014 Hotel stays, rates, & revenue: NFL
events on hotel outcomes in rooms (3,617 (+), NBA (0), Large multi-day
Charlotte. Multiple days) events (+).
regressions (separate
geographic regions).
Feng and Humphreys (2018) Teams/ Impact of proximity to two Single- 2000 Proximity and property values (+).
Venues sports stadiums on family
residential property sales. homes
Hedonic price model. (9,504)
81
Humphreys and Pyun (2018) Health Impact of MLB games on MSAs (88) 1990-2014 Daily average vehicle miles traveled
traffic congestion. Multiple (25 years) (+); Annual hours in traffic delay
regression (IV panel (+).
estimator).
Chikish et al. (2019) Hotels Impact of events on hotel Hotels near 2002-2017 NBA: Room rate (–), Stays (+),
occupancy and rates near Los Staples (> 16,000 Revenue (+). NHL: Room rate (–),
Angeles’s Staples Center. Center (139 days) Stays (–), Revenue (–). Mixed
Multiple regression (Regions hotels in 3 displacement effects from all events.
combined in single estimate). regions)
Humphreys (2019) Survey Point/counterpoint article on “[N]eighborhood revitalization, an
the case for subsidizing urban place-based policy, cannot
sports stadiums. justify [stadium] subsidies if spatial
equilibrium models of the urban
economy represent a reasonable
description of urban outcomes.”
Statistically significant (+/-) or null (0) findings in parentheses.
Table A1. (continued)
(difference-in-differences, (62)
matching).
Islam (2019) Teams/ Impact of receiving NFL MSAs (28) 1975-2008 Employment growth (0).
Venues franchise on employment (34 years)
growth in Charlotte,
Jacksonville, and Nashville.
Synthetic control method.
Johnson and Hall (2019) Voter Impact of voter San Deigo 2016 Referendum support and stadium
Preferences characteristics and zip codes proximity (0).
82
(16); compar-
matched isons)
control
tracts (272)
Cardazzi et al. (2020) Health Impact of acquiring new Cities (122) 1962-2016 New team: Influenza mortality (+).
professional sports teams on (weekly)
influenza mortality.
Difference-in-differences.
Connolly and Touchton (2020) Venue Examines the effectiveness of US adults Not “public perceptions of municipal
84
Funding alternate justifications for (700) reported funding for sports stadiums are
subsidizing a minor league more favorable when the public is
baseball stadium. Survey. told that doing so will improve
economic conditions in the city.”
Depken and Fore (2020) Business Impact of events on Restaurant 2007-2013 Restaurant sales: NFL games (+);
Activity restaurant activity near near (2,350 NBA games (+); Other events
sports venues in Charlotte. sports/ days) (mixed).
Case study. tourism
venues (1)
Drukker et al. (2020) Venue Estimates federal subsidies to Stadiums 2000-2020 Present value of subsidy : $3.6
Funding sports stadiums through (57) (21 years) billion. Lost revenue to federal
municipal bond tax government: $4.3 billion.
exemption.
Joshi et al. (2020) Property Estimate of MLS team Home sales: 2003-2016 Property values (–), distance
Values promotion in Seattle on King decaying effect within one mile.
property values. Repeat sales County
regression. (78,840)
Statistically significant (+/-) or null (0) findings in parentheses.
Table A1. (continued)
Propheter (2020a) Crime Impact of NBA stadium on Response 2016 Police response times: Downtown
police response times in time to (+), Suburbs (0).
urban and suburban settings daily police
following relocation within incidents
Sacramento. Doughnut-hole near
specification, triple Golden 1
difference-in-differences. Center
(42,580)
and Arco
Arena
85
(15,150)
Agha and Rascher (2021) Teams/ Impact of major- and MSAs and 2004-2012 Establishments (0); Employment
Venues minor-league teams and new MiSAs (9) (0)
stadiums on establishments (871)
and employment.
Difference-in-differences.
Multiple regression (Fixed,
random, & between effects).
Block (2021) Crime Impact of hosting NHL Nightly 2015-2019 Property (+); Assaults (+);
games on crime in Boston, crime (4 seasons) Alcohol-related (0).
Chicago, Los Angeles, and (1,310
Philadelphia. Multiple game
regression (Poisson). nights)
Statistically significant (+/-) or null (0) findings in parentheses.
Table A1. (continued)
an “municipal capitalism”
framework.
Keeler et al. (2021) Property Impact of proximity to Los Nearby 1995-2004 Proximity and sale price (+),
Values Angeles NBA/NHL arena on home sales (10 years) announcement and opening effects.
house prices near Staples (15,957)
Center. Hedonic spatial
difference-in-differences.
Propheter (2021) Property Impact of proximity to sports Parcels 2006-2019 Proximity and recovery: Dodger
Values venue on recession recovery near: (14 years) Stadium (+), Others (0).
86