PAI723 Lect8
PAI723 Lect8
• Since economics is about allocating scarce resources -- that is, asking what
choices people make when faced with limited resources -- looking at utility for a
single good is not enough. We want to compare utility for different combinations
of two or more goods.
• Our goal is to be able to graph the utility received from a combination of two
goods with a two-dimensional diagram. We do this using indifference curves.
• An indifference curve represents all combinations of goods that produce the
same level of satisfaction to a person.
o Along an indifference curve, utility is constant.
o Remember that each curve is analogous to a line on a contour map,
where each line shows a different elevation.
A. Drawing Indifference Curves
A
B
5. In general, indifference curves are convex -- that is they are bowed toward
the origin.
This is because people prefer variety.
5 of x and 5 of y is better than 8 x and 2 y.
Curvature is less when the goods are close substitutes, because
then variety isn't as important.
Consider the examples of left & right shoes (perfect
complements) and black & blue pens (perfect substitutes).
B. Marginal Rate of Substitution
• Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS) is the rate at which a person will give up
good y in order to get more of good x and still have the same utility.
o It is equal to the negative of the slope of the indifference curve
In the example below, as we move from point A to point B, we give
up 2 units of Y to gain one unit of X.
Thus, the slope of the indifference curve in this region is -2, and the
MRS = 2.
o As we move along the indifference curve, the curve gets flatter, and the
MRS is lower.
Moving from C to D, we are only willing to give up 0.5 units of Y to
get one unit of X.
Thus, the slope of the indifference curve in this region is -0.5, and
the MRS = 0.5.
o MRS = MUX/MUY
Thus, MRS tells us the ratio of the marginal utilities.
Note that, as we move along the indifference curve, the MRS
gets lower.
From A to B, where the MRS = 2, X is more valuable than Y,
since we have more Y than X.
Here, as a result, the marginal utility of X is twice
that of Y.
From C to D, where the MRS = 0.5, Y is more valuable than
X.
The marginal utility of X is just half that of Y.
This result follows from diminishing returns.
When we have more of X, we place
less importance on getting even
more.
o I = PxX + PyY
o The intercepts represent the amount of the good you can get if you spend
all your income on that good (I/Px and I/Py).
Changes in income lead to parallel shifts of the budget constraint.
o The slope (-Px/Py) represents the relative prices. It tells how much of Y
you need to give up to afford another unit of X.
Changes in prices cause the line to rotate.
In the example below, Px1 is lower than Px0. Thus, we can afford
more, so the budget constraint rotates outward.
• Note in general that focusing on how bundles on the origin change (e.g. if you
spend all of your money on only one good) can help determine how to change
the budget constraint as income or prices change.
IV. Which Bundle to Choose? Maximizing Utility
A
C
B D
A
C
X* X
B D
E
Y*
A
C
X* X