CH 14 Part 2
CH 14 Part 2
Expert advice
Financial intermediaries can advise their customers on financial
matters: on the best way of investing their funds and on
alternative ways of obtaining finance.
Risk transformation
You may be unwilling to lend money directly to another
person in case they do not pay up. You are unwilling to take
the risk. Financial intermediaries, however, by lending to
large numbers of people, are willing to risk the odd case of
default. They can absorb the loss because of the interest
they earn on all the other loans. This spreading of risks is
known as risk transformation. What is more, financial
intermediaries may have the expertise to be able to assess
just how risky a loan is.
Transmission of funds
In addition to channelling funds from depositors to borrowers,
certain financial institutions have another important
function. This is to provide a means of transmitting
payments. Thus by the use of debit cards, credit cards, the
Internet and telephone banking, cheques, direct debits,
etc., money can be transferred from one person or institution
to another without having to rely on cash.
The banking system
Types of bank
Banking can be divided into two main types: retail banking and wholesale
banking.
Most banks today conduct both types of business and are
thus known as ‘universal banks’.
Retail banking. Retail banking is the business conducted by
the familiar high street banks, such as Barclays, Lloyds,
HSBC, Royal Bank of Scotland,
. They operate bank accounts for individuals
and businesses, attracting deposits and granting
loans at published rates of interest.
Wholesale banking. The other major type of banking is
wholesale banking. This involves receiving large deposits
from and making large loans to companies or other banks
and financial institutions; these are known as wholesale
deposits and loans.
In the past, there were many independent wholesale
banks, known as investment banks. These included famous
names such as Morgan Stanley and
Goldman Sachs. With the worldwide financial crisis of the
late 2000s, however, most of the independent investment
banks merged with universal banks which conduct both
retail and wholesale activities.
The rise of large universal banks has caused concern, however.
In the UK in 2010, the Coalition government set up the
Independent Commission on Banking (ICB). It was charged
with investigating the structure of the banking system. It
proposed functional separation: the ring-fencing of retail and
wholesale banking. It argued that the core activities of retail
banks needed isolating from the potential contagion from
risky wholesale banking activities.
Building societies
These UK institutions specialise in granting loans (mortgages)
for house purchase. They compete for the savings of
the general public through a network of high street
branches. Unlike banks, they are not public limited companies,
their ‘shares’ being the deposits made by their investors.
In recent years, many of the building societies have
converted to banks .
In the past, there was a clear distinction between banks
and building societies. Today, however, they have become
much more similar, with building societies now offering current
account facilities and cash machines, and retail banks
granting mortgages.
Assets
A bank’s financial assets are its claims on others. There are
three main categories of assets.
Bank corporation tax surcharge. The 2015 Budget also saw the
announcement of a new 8 per cent corporation tax surcharge
on banks. This marked a shift in the tax base from
banks’ balance sheets to their profits. The 8 per cent surcharge
was introduced in January 2016 for all banks with
annual profits over £25 million. With the main corporation
tax rate at 18 per cent when introduced, the surcharge on
banks meant that their effective corporation tax rate was 26
per cent.
Profitability
Profits are made by lending money out at a higher rate of
interest than that paid to depositors. The average interest
rate received by banks on their assets is greater than that
paid by them on their liabilities.
Liquidity
The liquidity of an asset is the ease with which it can be
converted into cash without loss. Cash itself, by definition,
is perfectly liquid.
Some assets, such as money lent at call to other financial
institutions, are highly liquid. Although not actually cash,
these assets can be converted into cash virtually on demand
with no financial penalty. Other short-term inter-bank lending
is also very liquid
The only issue here is one of confidence that the
money will actually be repaid. This was a worry in the financial
crisis of 2008/9 when many banks stopped lending to
each other on the inter-bank market for fear that the borrowing
bank might become insolvent.
Other assets, such as gilts, can be converted into cash
straight away by selling them on the Stock Exchange, but
with the possibility of some financial loss, given that their
market price fluctuates. Such assets, therefore, are not as
liquid as money at call.
Other assets are much less liquid. Personal loans to the general
public or mortgages for house purchase can be redeemed
by the bank only as each instalment is paid. Other advances
for fixed periods are repaid only at the end of that period.
Banks must always be able to meet the demands of their customers
for withdrawals of money. To do this, they must hold
sufficient cash or other assets that can be readily turned into
cash. In other words, banks must maintain sufficient liquidity.
The balance between profitability and liquidity
Profitability is the major aim of banks and most other financial
institutions. However, the aims of profitability and
liquidity tend to conflict. In general, the more liquid an
asset, the less profitable it is, and vice versa. Personal and
business loans to customers are profitable to banks, but
highly illiquid. Cash is totally liquid, but earns no profit.
Thus financial institutions like to hold a range of assets with
varying degrees of liquidity and profitability.
For reasons of profitability, the banks will want to ‘borrow
short’ (at low rates of interest, as are generally paid on current
accounts) and ‘lend long’ (at higher rates of interest, as
are normal on personal loans). The difference in the average
maturity of loans and deposits is known as the maturity gap.
In general terms, the larger the maturity gap between loans
and deposits, the greater the profitability. For reasons of
liquidity, however, banks will want a relatively small gap: if
there is a sudden withdrawal of deposits, banks will need to
be able to call in enough loans.
The ratio of an institution’s liquid assets to total assets is
known as its liquidity ratio. For example, if a bank had £100
million of assets, of which £10 million were liquid and £90
million were illiquid, the bank would have a 10 per cent
liquidity ratio. If a financial institution’s liquidity ratio is too
high, it will make too little profit. If the ratio is too low, there
will be the risk that customers’ demands may not be able to
be met: this would cause a crisis of confidence and possible
closure. Institutions thus have to make a judgement as to
what liquidity ratio is best – one that is neither too high nor
too low.
Capital adequacy
In addition to sufficient liquidity, banks must have sufficient
capital (i.e. funds) to allow them to meet all demands
from depositors and to cover losses if borrowers default on
payment. Capital adequacy is a measure of a bank’s capital
relative to its assets, where the assets are weighted according
to the degree of risk. The more risky the assets, the greater
the amount of capital that will be required.
A measure of capital adequacy is given by the capital
Adequacy ratio (CAR). This is given by the following formula:
CAR = (Common Equity Tier 1 capital +
Additional Tier 1 capital + Tier 2 capital)/ Risk@weighted assets
It acts as a bank
To the government. It keeps the two major government
accounts: the ‘Exchequer’ and the ‘National Loans Fund’.
Taxation and government spending pass through the Exchequer.
Government borrowing and lending pass through the
National Loans Fund. The government tends to keep its
deposits in the Bank of England to a minimum. If the deposits begin to
build up (from taxation), the government will probably
spend them on paying back government debt. If, on the other
hand, it runs short of money, it will simply borrow more.