PS0 Micro Sol
PS0 Micro Sol
10 − p = 2 + p ↔ p = 4
and therefore
xD = xS = 6.
The tax levied on consumption increases any given price by two, so that the
new demand curve will look like x0D = 10 − (p + 2) = 8 − p. Again, equating the
demand and supply functions yields
8−p=2+p ↔ p=3
and therefore
xD = xS = 5.
3
Note that the tax has driven a wedge between the price consumers pay, which
is p + 2 = 5 > 4, and the price suppliers get for their products, which is p = 3 < 4.
Correspondingly, consumers want to buy less and firms want to supply less. Tax
revenue for the government is x × t = 5 × 2 = 10. In terms welfare, consumer
surplus has decreased by areas a + b, producer surplus by areas c + d, and the
government earns tax revenues equal to areas a + c = 10. The triangle b + d is
the dead weight loss of the tax, i.e. the inefficiency that occurs because of the
introduction of the tax.
(4) Consider a monopolist that faces a demand curve x = 100−p, and has cost function
c(x) = 2 + 2x. Find the monopolist’s profit-maximizing choice of x. Discuss the
intuition behind the first order condition. Compute the monopolist’s profits.
A monopolist has market power and can therefore set prices. In her decision
how much to produce, she takes into account the effect a change in her price has
on demand. An optimal choice will be at the point where marginal revenue are
equal to marginal costs. To see this suppose marginal revenue was higher than
marginal costs. In this case, an additional unit of output would yield (marginal
revenue) more than it would cost (marginal cost) and therefore the monopolist
could increase her profits by increasing output. The reverse is true if a quantity
is chosen so that the last unit produced cost more than the marginal revenue
from selling this unit. Therefore, profit maximizing behavior implies the above
relationship.
4
M R = M C ↔ 100 − 2x = 2 ↔ x = 49.
Substituting the optimal output back into the demand function gives us the equi-
librium price
49 = 100 − p ↔ p = 51.
We can now compute the monopolist’s profit as:
π = p × x − c(x) = 51 × 49 − (2 + 2 × 49) = 2399.
A final observation is that we could have arrived at the first order condition above
in a more formal way. The profit function is π = p × x − c(x). Substituting the
demand and cost function and maximizing profits with respect to x results in the
first order condition:
100 − 2x − 2 = 0 ↔ 100 − 2x = 2.