9294
9294
9294
https://ebookultra.com
https://ebookultra.com/download/basic-spanish-2nd-edition-ana-c-
jarvis/
ebookultra.com
https://ebookultra.com/download/john-milton-life-work-and-thought-1st-
edition-gordon-campbell/
ebookultra.com
https://ebookultra.com/download/international-handbook-of-workplace-
trauma-support-1st-edition-rick-hughes/
ebookultra.com
John Campbell s Physiology Notes For Nurses 1st Edition
John Campbell
https://ebookultra.com/download/john-campbell-s-physiology-notes-for-
nurses-1st-edition-john-campbell/
ebookultra.com
https://ebookultra.com/download/life-after-trauma-2nd-ed-a-workbook-
for-healing-2nd-edition-dena-rosenbloom/
ebookultra.com
https://ebookultra.com/download/assessing-psychological-trauma-and-
ptsd-2nd-edition-john-p-wilson/
ebookultra.com
https://ebookultra.com/download/basic-principles-in-biology-for-
hkdsee-book-3-2nd-edition-y-k-to/
ebookultra.com
BTLS Basic Trauma Life Support Para Paramedicos y
Otros Proveedores Avanzados Spanish 2nd Edition
Eduardo Romero Hicks John Emory Campbell Digital
Instant Download
Author(s): Eduardo Romero Hicks John Emory Campbell
ISBN(s): 9780964741829, 0964741822
Edition: 2nd
File Details: PDF, 43.54 MB
Year: 2004
Language: english
Exploring the Variety of Random
Documents with Different Content
“liked him so well as to pack up her alls, leave her husband, and run
away with him to Italy.”
The moral obliquity of the incident lends colour to the unsparing
attacks of his enemies, and certainly cannot be extenuated even
according to the loose standards of his day. The gravity of the
offence he could not be ignorant of, notwithstanding his youth. His
finer susceptibilities, however, had been impaired by the contagion
of vice, which led him to embark upon risks, especially of gallantry,
from mere impulsiveness, and regardless of consequence. What little
credit can be extended to Law in connection with this affair, he
derives from having remained faithful to her to the last, while the
death of her husband, shortly after, relieved him of possible
embarrassment during his subsequent visits and residence in Paris.
Unsuccessful in his appeal to the Court at St. Germains to secure
official employment, he resumed his old career of gambling, and
made the principal cities of the Continent the field of his operations
for the next three or four years. His movements at this time are
somewhat difficult to trace. No authentic record of his peregrinations
have come down to us. It is tolerably clear, however, that he resided
for short periods at Genoa, Rome, Venice and Amsterdam, and may
also have visited Florence and Naples. Gambling in his case was no
mere means of satisfying an uncontrollable passion. He did not
conduct it promiscuously. He based his speculations upon a system
which he had developed for his own guidance after the most careful
study of the laws of chance. Although success did not invariably
attend his play, the balance of probability was so frequently in his
favour that he was not only able to maintain his position as a
gentleman of worth, but to amass a considerable fortune in an
incredibly short period of time. No doubt the cool, calculating
Scotsman, apart from any merit his system of play may have
possessed, was more likely to rise from the tables with success than
those with whom he would choose to gamble. Not only would his
confidence and boldness irritate and excite his opponents, but the
reputation his skill had acquired for him would be in itself a
disturbing element to their minds, and render them unequal to his
superior play.
Notwithstanding his propensities in this direction, Law also
devoted his abilities and his keen powers of observation to another
and more creditable study. The subject of banking, the mysteries of
credit, and all the intricacies of financial problems appealed to his
strongly mathematical mind, and of the advantages afforded him,
whilst on the Continent, for an intimate acquaintance with the
various systems of his time he was not slow to avail himself. At this
period there were several banking companies in Europe, and of
these the banks of Venice, Genoa, and Amsterdam were the chief.
The first two owe their origin to the financial difficulties of the
Venetian and Genoese Republics, and had been in existence since
1157 and 1407 respectively. The Bank of Amsterdam, on the other
hand, was of more modern growth, having been established in 1609
in order to minimise the confusion continually arising from the
unsteady value of the currency by placing the coinage upon a fixed
and more permanent basis. Law, accordingly, utilised his stay in
these three cities to gaining an insight into their methods of
business. At Venice, we are told, he constantly went to the Rialto at
Change time, and no merchant upon commission was more
punctual. He observed the course of exchange all the world over;
the manner of discounting bills at the bank; the vast usefulness of
paper credit; how gladly people parted with their money for paper,
and how the profits accrued from this paper to the proprietors. At
Amsterdam, where he was employed as secretary to the British
Resident in Holland, “he made himself acquainted on the spot with
the famous bank of that city; with its capital, its produce, its
resources; with the demands individuals had upon it; with its
variations, its interests; with the mode of lowering or raising its
stock, in order to withdraw the capital, that it might be distributed
and circulated; with the order that bank observed in its accounts and
in its offices; and even with its expenditures and its form of
administration.”
The varied information which Law in this way acquired during his
residence on the Continent, and especially in the great banking
centres, he did not store as a mere mass of bare interesting facts.
Whether the investigations he assiduously pursued were the
outcome of a design to develop a new system of banking, or
proceeded merely from the attraction of the subject, is matter of
doubt. But it is clear that he abstracted certain principles of finance
from the data he had gathered, and that these principles were
heterodox according to the opinions of his contemporaries. Our
judgment upon Law must be largely determined by our impression
as to whether these principles were logically deduced explanations
of the financial phenomena he observed, or whether they were the
fanciful ideas of his own imagination for the justification of which he
sifted his phenomena. It is extremely difficult to arrive at any
definite conclusion. His own published writings give no guiding clue,
and the records of his time confuse, rather than enlighten, by their
contradictory and varied explanations of his schemes. It is probable
that the principles upon which they were founded possessed an
element of both possibilities. His observations on the one hand
would seem to indicate to his mind some underlying law; and on the
other hand his mind, impressed with the beauty and simplicity of
some vast ambitious scheme of finance, would readily discover
support in its favour from the deductions he had made. At no time
did Law attempt to build up a system of financial philosophy, but he
must be given due praise for laying down propositions bearing upon
the subject of credit and of the use of paper money which have
stood the test of time and received recognition from political
economists of our own day. He must also be raised to a higher level
than a mere financial schemer. His proposals were more than
plausible. They had an element of practicability, in which he
demonstrated his own belief by his readiness to put them to test
under private direction before they were launched with sovereign
authority and under public control. Convinced so thoroughly as he
was with the soundness of his theories, and with the possibilities
they opened up, if adopted, of infusing new life and new energy into
the commercial world of his day, he regarded himself as a man with
an important mission.
His own country seemed to offer a suitable field for his financial
ability, and we find him back in Edinburgh in the closing year of the
seventeenth century, the legislative independence of Scotland
affording him all necessary safety against arrest for the murder of
which he had been guilty five years previously.
CHAPTER II
Unsettled condition of Scottish politics in 1700.—Financial and
commercial insecurity of country.—Law’s solution of
difficulties.—Land Bank.—Supported by Court party.—
Rejected by Parliament.—Again resorts to gambling.—
Returns to Continent.—Expelled from Holland.—Visits
Paris.—Discusses finance with Duc d’Orleans.—Expelled
by Lieutenant General of Police.—Submits proposals to
Louis XIV. without success.—Again attempts to secure
adoption of proposals by France.—Financial condition of
France.—Earl of Stair’s friendship with Law.
One of the first, as it also was one of the most important and
pressing, matters to which the Regent’s attention was demanded,
was the financial condition of the country. The adoption of drastic
measures was imperative. The national debt amounted to 3500
millions of livres, and while the revenue produced 145 millions, the
expenditure of the Government absorbed 142 millions, leaving 3
millions with which to liquidate interest upon the national debt, or 1-
10th per cent. A deficit of 150 to 200 millions was thus accumulating
each year, and every resource which ingenuity could conceive having
long ago been exhausted, the situation was daily becoming more
difficult. The Regent, shortly after his accession, called a meeting of
the Council for the purpose of devising a means of relieving the
intolerable strain. National bankruptcy was suggested by a few of its
members, notably the Duc de Saint-Simon. The Regent would give
no ear to such a course, and waved the suggestion aside as alike
dishonourable and disastrous to all possibility of good government.
No one, however, seemed capable of offering any plan of permanent
value. The schemes proposed were merely expedients promising
temporary relief, and no other policy but one of despair being
apparent at the moment, the Regent was eager for their immediate
execution.
A commission or visa was appointed to investigate the nature of
the national debt, and, by classifying the claims, to bring order out
of chaos. By methods, in many instances more rigorous than just,
the national debt was reduced by 1500 millions, and interest was
made uniform at the rate of four per cent. Of the 2000 millions at
which the debt now stood, 1750 millions were funded, and the
balance of 250 millions was converted into a general floating debt
represented by billets d’état. A substantial reduction was thus made
in the amount of interest payable by the Treasury; but, without an
increase of permanent revenue, which, if it were to be accomplished
by the imposition of fresh taxation, neither the Regent nor his
Councillors would face, or without a reduction in expenditure to an
extent which would have rendered the public service inefficient, the
solution of the financial difficulty was as distant as ever. Recourse
was accordingly had to two measures, which served the purpose of
the moment. The first was the old expedient of debasing the
coinage. With the ostensible object of having a new currency with
the new king’s effigy, the old coinage was recalled. The fresh issue,
however, was depreciated in the process to the extent of about 30
per cent., and the Government profited by the transaction sufficient
to liquidate one year’s interest of the National Debt. The second
device for replenishing the Exchequer was the establishment of a
Chamber of Justice, a kind of inquisition for the investigation of the
conduct of the tax-collectors. These men by their unscrupulous
dealings, had come to be regarded as the evil genii of the French
peasantry. Like vampires, they had for years been sucking the very
life-blood of the nation. No redress was open to their victims, and
resistance only had the effect of increasing the burdens laid upon
their shoulders. The institution of the Chamber of Justice was
accordingly received with unbounded joy. Every tax-farmer was
arraigned before this tribunal. The most searching investigation was
made, not only into his own dealings, but also into the dealings of
the hordes of satellites whom he employed to bleed his unfortunate
victims. Where information was withheld, or even where it was
suspected that the information given was tainted with inaccuracy,
encouragement was given to informers by holding out promises of
20 per cent. of any fines that might be levied. Such a system, of
course, was bound to bring evils in its train as great as those it was
intended to remove. A reign of terror set in amongst the farmers-
general. No sympathy was extended to them by their judges. All
confidence in their honesty had long ago been destroyed. They were
already prejudged. No effort on their part could by any possibility
ward off the weight of accusation against them. Prison
accommodation was soon taxed beyond its capacity. Those who
were fortunate enough to escape this Jeddart justice by bribery, by
payment of enormous fines, or by quietly submitting to wholesale
confiscation, left the country as a measure of personal safety. The
records of the period teem with the decisions of the Chamber of
Justice and their consequences. Most of the cases reflect a degree of
moral obliquity on the part of the judges not less than on the part of
the accused. We are told of one instance where a contractor had
been taxed, in proportion to his wealth and guilt, at the sum of
twelve millions livres. A courtier, possessing considerable influence
with the Government, offered to procure a remission of the fine for a
bribe of one hundred thousand crowns. “You are too late, my friend,”
replied the contractor, “I have already made a bargain with your wife
for fifty thousand.” In the course of a few weeks almost the whole of
the fraternity had run the gauntlet of the Chamber of Justice. They
had been stript of their power, their influence and their possessions.
The country had been effectively cleared of their presence, but to
comparatively small advantage. The total fines and confiscations
amounted to one hundred and eighty million livres, of which the
Government received only one half, and its parasites the other. As a
consequence, its career was brought to a close, and with it the
ingenious financial devices of the Council of Ministers.
Law was an amused spectator of the puerile efforts of the
Regent and his advisers to restore financial stability to their country.
He regarded them no less with scorn, and probably rejoiced in the
futility of their efforts, in the hope that each successive step they
took would bring the realisation of his own ambition within
measurable distance. The position he occupied, however, was one of
difficulty, and demanded a display of considerable tact and
judgment. He had educated the Regent up to the point of implicit
confidence in his scheme, but there still remained a dead weight of
opposition in the Council, and without the support of both the
ground was very uncertain.
No time was lost by Law in an attempt to bring his proposals to
a head. He repeatedly interviewed the Regent within the first few
weeks after the death of Louis XIV., and submitted definite schemes
for relieving the situation. He urged that by the adoption of a system
of paper credit, not necessarily for supplanting, but for
supplementing, the coinage in currency, not only would the trade of
the country increase in volume, but the national debt would be
effectively dealt with. He based his argument upon the principle that
the quantity of money in circulation in a country determines its
industrial activity. Recognising that money, whether it be specie or
paper, is not itself the wealth of a country, but only the measure of
its wealth, and that in whatever form it exists it must represent
either the whole or part of that actual wealth, he conceived the idea
of issuing the notes against the landed property of France, and the
ordinary State revenues. He pointed out, as examples in support of
his proposals, the immense benefits which had flowed from the
adoption of a similar system by England, Holland, Venice, and
Genoa. The Regent, convinced before by Law’s arguments, was now
determined to put them into operation. He convened the Council of
Finances, and invited to its deliberations the principal bankers and
merchants of Paris and of the provinces. The sederunt took place on
24th October, 1715, only eight weeks after the King’s death, but the
Regent had personally interviewed beforehand several of the
members to secure their support for Law. To this assembly Law
unfolded the general outline of his proposals. “He was listened to as
long as he liked to talk. Some, who saw that the Regent was almost
decided, acquiesced; but the majority opposed.” The precise ground
of opposition is nowhere recorded, but probably the fear, expressed
at the former Council in July, had not been dissipated, that the
system would lend itself to abuse at the hands of an absolute
monarch, and might bring in its train greater evils than those it was
intended to remedy. The letters patent of 2nd May, 1716, granting
private banking privileges to Law, refers to the decision of this
assembly, but being couched in the language of official ambiguity,
gives no clue to the reasons which actuated the rejection of the
scheme. “Mr. Law having some time since proposed a scheme for
erecting a bank, which should consist of our own money, and be
administered in our own name, and under our authority, the project
was examined in our Council of Finances, when several bankers,
merchants and deputies from our trading cities being convened and
required to give their advice, they were unanimous in the opinion
that nothing could be more advantageous to our kingdom, which,
through its situation and fertility, added to the industry of its
inhabitants, stood in need of nothing more than a solid credit for
acquiring the most extensive and flourishing commerce. They
thought, however, that this present conjunction was not favourable
for the undertaking; and this reason, added to some particular
clauses of the project, determined us to refuse it.”
Law was thus foiled again, but weakness of purpose was far
from being a feature of his character. Irrefragable determination
steeled him against all rebuffs. He saw more than ever that France
was his last and only opportunity. He saw that the plastic minds of
most of the ministers were susceptible to the pressure of the
Regent’s influence if applied with sufficient strength. This was not
difficult of operation. The Regent’s influence was at Law’s command,
and he made unsparing use of it. With prudent calculation, however,
of the future, should his plans fail in their object by some mishap, he
modified his scheme to the extent of petitioning for permission to
establish a private instead of a national bank. In order, too, that the
members of the Council and those who would be called to the
deliberations in connection with his proposal should have some more
definite and complete knowledge of his theories than could be
conveyed in conversation, or in course of an address at the Council
table, Law translated his book on Money and Trade, published in
Edinburgh in 1705, supplementing what he had written there by
separate papers giving his maturer ideas.
Early in 1716 every preparation had been made, and all
contingencies provided against. The Regent called again the
Assembly of the previous October. The scheme was solemnly
discussed. Opposition dwindled to a mere shadow. The scheme was
passed, and remitted to the Regency Council for final ratification.
This last stage in the process is well described by the Duc de Saint-
Simon, whose opposition not even the Regent could overcome.